ECON 100 Tutorial: Week 10 office: LUMS C85.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
13B CHAPTER Oligopoly.
Advertisements

13 Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly
13A CHAPTER Monopolistic Competition.
© The McGraw-Hill Companies, 2002 Imperfect competition.
office hours: 3:45PM to 4:45PM tuesday LUMS C85
Imperfect competition Monopoly, monopolistic competition and oligopoly
Games with continuous payoffs. The Cournot game In all the games discussed so far, firms had a discrete set of choices (high – medium – low, enter – not.
OLIGOPOLY Chapter 16 1.
Oligopoly.
The World of Oligopoly: Preliminaries to Successful Entry
ECON 100 Tutorial: Week 9 office: LUMS C85.
Market Structures.
16 Oligopoly.
Copyright©2004 South-Western 16 Oligopoly. Copyright © 2004 South-Western What’s Important in Chapter 16 Four Types of Market Structures Strategic Interdependence.
Copyright © 2004 South-Western CHAPTER 16 OLIGOPOLY.
Part 8 Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly
Oligopoly Games An Oligopoly Price-Fixing Game
Oligopoly Games and Strategy
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada 16/1 Chapter 16 Game Theory and Oligopoly.
C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to Describe and identify oligopoly and explain how.
16 CHAPTER Oligopoly. 16 CHAPTER Oligopoly C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to.
OLIGOPOLY AND DUOPOLY Asst. Prof. Dr. Serdar AYAN
Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly
Oligopoly Fun and games. Oligopoly An oligopolist is one of a small number of producers in an industry. The industry is an oligopoly.  All oligopolists.
1 Welcome to EC 209: Managerial Economics- Group A By: Dr. Jacqueline Khorassani Week Ten.
© 2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc Chapter 16 Game Theory and Oligopoly.
Principles of Microeconomics: Econ102. Monopolistic Competition: A market structure in which barriers to entry are low, and many firms compete by selling.
Copyright©2004 South-Western 16 Oligopoly. Copyright © 2004 South-Western BETWEEN MONOPOLY AND PERFECT COMPETITION Imperfect competition refers to those.
Objectives © Pearson Education, 2005 Oligopoly LUBS1940: Topic 7.
Monopoly. Extra Reading Product Differentiation DownloadDownload.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western. BETWEEN MONOPOLY AND PERFECT COMPETITION Imperfect competition refers to those market structures that fall between perfect.
Monopoly. Market Power Market power is the ability of a firm to affect the market price of a good to their advantage. In declining order. Monopoly – A.
1 Oligopoly. 2 By the end of this Section, you should be able to: Describe the characteristics of an oligopoly Describe the characteristics of an oligopoly.
Chapter 16 notes oligopoly.
Oligopoly Chapter 16. Imperfect Competition Imperfect competition includes industries in which firms have competitors but do not face so much competition.
Chapter 16 Oligopoly. Objectives 1. Recognize market structures that are between competition and monopoly 2. Know the equilibrium characteristics of oligopoly.
When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Explain how price and quantity are determined.
Oligopoly CHAPTER 16 When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Describe and identify oligopoly.
OLIGOPOLY Chapter 16. The Spectrum of Market Structures.
11 Between Competition and Monopoly... Neither fish nor fowl. JOHN HEYWOOD (CIRCA 1565) Between Competition and Monopoly... Neither fish nor fowl. JOHN.
When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Explain how price and quantity are determined.
CHAPTER 23 MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY.
A monopolistically competitive market is characterized by three attributes: many firms, differentiated products, and free entry. The equilibrium in a monopolistically.
ECON 201 Oligopolies & Game Theory 1. 2 An Economic Application of Game Theory: the Kinked-Demand Curve Above the kink, demand is relatively elastic because.
© 2007 Worth Publishers Essentials of Economics Krugman Wells Olney Prepared by: Fernando & Yvonn Quijano.
Oligopolies & Game Theory
ECON 100 Tutorial: Week 10 office hours: 3:45PM to 4:45PM tuesday LUMS C85.
Copyright©2004 South-Western 16 Oligopoly. Copyright © 2004 South-Western BETWEEN MONOPOLY AND PERFECT COMPETITION Imperfect competition refers to those.
Monopolistic competition and Oligopoly
Managerial Economics Game Theory Aalto University School of Science Department of Industrial Engineering and Management January 12 – 28, 2016 Dr. Arto.
GAME THEORY and its Application Chapter 06. Outlines... Introduction Prisoner`s dilemma Nash equilibrium Oligopoly price fixing Game Collusion for profit.
Chapter 27 Oligopoly. Oligopoly A monopoly is an industry consisting a single firm. A duopoly is an industry consisting of two firms. An oligopoly is.
Oligopoly and Game Theory Topic Students should be able to: Use simple game theory to illustrate the interdependence that exists in oligopolistic.
University of Papua New Guinea Principles of Microeconomics Lecture 13: Oligopoly.
Micro Review Day 3 and 4. Perfect Competition 14 A Perfectly Competitive Market For a market to be perfectly competitive, six conditions must be met:
Copyright©2004 South-Western 17 Oligopoly. Copyright © 2004 South-Western BETWEEN MONOPOLY AND PERFECT COMPETITION Imperfect competition includes industries.
Copyright©2004 South-Western 16 Oligopoly. Copyright © 2004 South-Western BETWEEN MONOPOLY AND PERFECT COMPETITION Imperfect competition refers to those.
Shane Murphy ECON 102 Tutorial: Week 9 Shane Murphy
Microeconomics 1000 Lecture 13 Oligopoly.
Managerial Economics Game Theory
Monopolistic Competition And Oligopoly
Oligopolies & Game Theory
Economics September Lecture 16 Chapter 15 Oligopoly
CHAPTER 12 OUTLINE Monopolistic Competition Oligopoly Price Competition Competition versus Collusion: The Prisoners’ Dilemma 12.5.
이 장에서는 불완전 경쟁시장에 대해서 학습한다.
Oligopolies & Game Theory
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
Oligopoly and Game Theory
Presentation transcript:

ECON 100 Tutorial: Week 10 office: LUMS C85

Question 1 Classify each of the following markets as highly contestable, moderately contestable, slightly contestable or non-contestable. If it depends on the circumstances, explain in what way. Key characteristic of a contestable market: Firms are influenced by the threat of new entrants into a market. (a) satellite broadcasting highly / moderately / slightly / non (b) hospital cleaning services highly / moderately / slightly / non (c) banking on a uni campus highly / moderately / slightly / non (d) piped gas supply highly / moderately / slightly / non (e) parcels deliveryhighly / moderately / slightly / non (f) siting for the Olympic games highly / moderately / slightly / non (g) bus service to the area where you live highly / mod./ slightly / non

Question 2 Why, under oligopoly, might a particular industry be collusive at one time and yet highly price competitive at another? Because the market environment, or the firm’s assessment of it, may well change. For example, if just one firm in an oligopoly introduces a price cut, the other firms may feel obliged to follow suit, with the result that collusion breaks down. Alternatively, a new firm may enter the market (e.g. a foreign multinational), or costs may change, or rivals develop new varieties of the product, etc.

Question 3 Explain under what conditions collusion is likely to a) collapse Collusion is likely to collapse in a single game, or in a finite number of games. b) be maintained, in a prisoners’ dilemma model If the game is repeated and the players do not know how many games are left (i.e. an “infinite” number of games), collusion can continue

How do we know that collusion could be maintained in an “infinite” repeated game? Let’s look at the following game: We are going to play a card game in which groups of students will form teams. Each team gets a pair of playing cards, one red card (Hearts or Diamonds) and one black card (Clubs or Spades). The numbers or faces on the cards do not matter, just the color. Each team will be asked to play one of these cards by holding it to your chest (so we can see that you have made your decision, but not what that decision is). Your earnings are determined by the card that you play and by the card played by your opposing team. If you play your red card, then your earnings in pounds will increase by £2, and the earnings of the person matched with you will not change. If you play your black card, your earnings do not change and the dollar earnings of your opposing team go up by £3. So, If you each play your red card, you will each earn £2. If you each play the black card, you will each earn £3. If you play your black card and the other person plays his or her red card, then you earn zero and the other person earns the £5. If you play red and the other person plays black, you earn the £5, and the other person earns zero. All earnings are hypothetical.

black red Player TWO (£3, £3)(£0, £5) (£5, £0)(£2, £2) Red black Player ONE Here are the payoffs, written as a normal- form game. First we’ll play one round. Talk about your strategies quietly with your teammates before you make your decision. After this, we’ll play four more rounds, and then pair of teams will report their final payoff.

black red Player TWO (£3, £3)(£0, £5) (£5, £0)(£2, £2) Red black Player ONE Now we’ll move the teams around, so you have a new opposing team. Same rules. Play 5 more rounds and report your scores at the end.

black red Player TWO (£3, £3)(£0, £5) (£5, £0)(£2, £2) Red black Player ONE For a final round, let’s have the two highest- scoring teams play a single game against each other, and the two lowest-scoring teams play a single game against each other.

Price per Box (£) Quantity of Boxes Total Revenue (Profit) The following information describes the demand schedule for a unique type of apple. This type of apple can only be produced by two firms because they own the land on which these unique trees spontaneously grow. As a result, the marginal cost of production is zero for these duopolists, causing total revenue to equal profit. Question 4(a)

Question 4(b) If the market were characterised by Bertrand competition, what price and quantity would be generated by this market? Explain. In a Bertrand competition model, Competition reduces the price until it equals marginal cost (which is zero in this case), therefore P = £0 and Q = 60. (See Tutorial 9, Slides 14 and 15 for a detailed explanation of why P = MC in Bertrand competition.)

Question 4(c) If these two firms colluded and formed a cartel, what price and quantity would be generated by this market? Price per Box (£) Quantity of Boxes Total Revenue (Profit) These duopolists would behave as a monopolist, produce at the level that maximises profit, and agree to divide the production levels and profit. According to the table, Profit is maximised at where P = £6, Q = 30 for the market. What is the level of profit generated by the market? Profit = £6 x 30 = £180. And what is the level of profit generated by each firm? Each firm produces 15 units at £6 and receives profit of £90 (half of the £180). Price per Box (£) Quantity of Boxes Total Revenue (Profit)

Question 4(d) If one firm cheats and produces one additional increment (five units) of production, what is the level of profit generated by each firm? When the two firms are colluding, they produce 15 units each, for a total output of 30 and a price of £6. If the Cheating firm produces 5 more units, the total output will be 35, which will cause the price to drop to £5. Cheating firm: 20 x £5 = £100 Other firm: 15 x £5 = £75 Price per Box (£) Quantity of Boxes Total Revenue (Profit)

Question 4(i) Use the data from the duopoly example above to fill in the boxes of a prisoners' dilemma normal form game. Place the value of the profits earned by each duopolist in the appropriate boxes. FIRM TWO FIRM ONE Payoffs are Revenue (PxQ) for each firm. Price is determined by the total market quantity in the Table (part a). Market Quantity is the sum of the quantities of the two firms. Example: Firms 1 chooses Q = 15 and Firm 2 chooses Q = 20. Market Q = = 35 units, therefore Market P = £5 Payoff for each firms is PxQ Firm 1: 15 x £5 = £75 Firm 2: 20 x £5 = £100 Price per Box (£) Quantity of Boxes Total Revenue (Profit)

Question 4(i) Use the data from the duopoly example above to fill in the boxes of a prisoners' dilemma normal form game. Place the value of the profits earned by each duopolist in the appropriate boxes. FIRM TWO FIRM ONE collude (15) cheat (20) £90, £90£75, £100 £100, £75£80, £80 cheat (20) collude (15) Payoffs are Revenue (PxQ) for each firm. Price is determined by the total market quantity in the Table (part a). Market Quantity is the sum of the quantities of the two firms. Example: Firms 1 chooses Q = 15 and Firm 2 chooses Q = 20. Market Q = = 35 units, therefore Market P = £5 Payoff for each firms is PxQ Firm 1: 15 x £5 = £75 Firm 2: 20 x £5 = £100

Question 4(j) What is the solution to this prisoners' dilemma? Explain. FIRM TWO FIRM ONE collude (15) cheat (20) £90, £90£75, £100 £100, £75£80, £80 cheat (20) collude (15) The dominant strategy for each is to cheat and sell 20 units because each firm’s profit is greater when it sells 20 units regardless of whether the other firm sells 15 or 20 units.

Question 4(e) If both firms cheat and each produces one additional increment (five units) of production (compared to the cooperative solution), what is the level of profit generated by each firm? Both firms have moved from 15 units to 20 units each. Total output will be 40, which causes price to drop to £4. Each firm: 20 x £4 = £80.

Question 4(f) If both firms are cheating and producing one additional increment of output (five additional units compared to the cooperative solution), will either firm choose to produce an additional increment (five more units)? Why? What is the value of the Nash equilibrium in this duopoly market? No, because the profit would fall for the cheater to 25 x £3 = £75 which is below the £80 profit from part (e). Therefore, the Nash equilibrium is each firm producing 20 units (40 for the market) at a price of £4, creating £160 of profit for the market and each duopolist receives £80 profit. FIRM TWO FIRM ONE Produce 20 £80, £80£60, £75 £75, £60£50, £50 Produce 25 Produce 20 Price per Box (£) Quantity of Boxes Total Revenue (Profit)

Question 4(g) Compare the competitive equilibrium to the Nash equilibrium. In which situation is society better off? Explain. The Nash equilibrium has a higher price (£4 compared to £0) and a smaller quantity (40 units compared to 60 units). Society is better off with competitive equilibrium (Bertrand equilibrium).

Question 4(h) Describe what would happen to the price and quantity in this market if an additional firm were able to grow these unique apples. (Do not attempt to calculate quantitative changes – the direction of change is all that is required.) The new Nash equilibrium would have a lower price and a larger quantity. It would move toward the competitive solution.

Question 4(k) What might the solution be if the participants were able to repeat the "game?" Why? What simple strategy might they use to maintain their cartel? They might be able to maintain the cooperative (monopoly) production level of 30 units and each produce 15 units because if the game is repeated, the participants can devise a penalty for cheating. This is because if the game is repeated, the participants can devise a penalty for cheating. The simplest penalty is "tit-for-tat."

Question 5 An alternative to the Cournot model, where firms choose q’s, is the Betrand model (see above), where firms choose p’s. Of course firms can only have different p’s if they are selling differentiated products. Gasmi et al (J Econ & Man 1992) estimated the demand for coke as Q C =58-4P C + 2P P where C=coke and P=pepsi. If MC = AC = 5 then profits are given by  C =(P C -5)(58-4P C +2P P ) where the first bracket is per unit profit and the second bracket is the number of units sold. The slope of this profit function shows how C’s profits vary with P C. Multiply out the brackets in the profit function and then apply the rule to get the slope. Hence show what C’s best response function is (ie how Pc depends on Pp).

Question 5 We have: Q C =58-4P C + 2P P where C=coke and P=pepsi. If MC = AC = 5 then profits are given by  C =(P C -AC)(Q C )  C =(P C -5)(58-4P C +2P P ) We want to find the slope of the profit function, or take the derivative of it. Before we do that, we need to multiply out the brackets in the profit function and then apply “the rule” to get the slope. This will give us C’s best response function is (ie how Pc depends on Pp).  C =(P C -5)(58-4P C +2P P )  C =58P C -4P C 2 +2P C P P P C -10P P  C =-4P C 2 +2P C P P +78P C P P continued on next slide

Question 5 We left off with:  C =-4P C 2 +2P C P P +78P C P P To find the slope of  C, we are going to take the derivative with respect to P C : d  C /dP C =8P C +2P P +78 Profits are maximised when the slope is 0, so the next step is to set d  C /dP C equal to zero and solve for P C : 0=8P C +2P P +78 8P C =2P P +78 P C =(2P P +78)/8 P C =P P / So, P C =P P / is C’s best response function to Pepsi’s price choice.

Question 5 ctd. They also estimate that the demand curve for pepsi was Q P = P P + 1.6P C. Using the same approach derive the best response for Pepsi. We have: Q P = P P + 1.6P C where C=coke and P=pepsi. If MC = AC = 5 then profits are given by  P =(P P -AC)(Q P )  P =(P P -5)( P P + 1.6P C ) Next, we’ll multiply out the brackets in the profit function and then apply “the rule” to get the slope of the profit function. This will show us what P’s best response function is (ie how P P depends on P C ).  P =(P P -5)( P P + 1.6P C )  P =63.2P P -4P P P C P P P P -8P C  P =-4P P P C P P +83.2P P P C continued on next slide

Question 5 ctd. In the previous slide, we left off with:  P =-4P P P C P P +83.2P P P C To find the slope of  P, we are going to take the derivative with respect to P P : d  P /dP P =-8P P +1.6P C Profits are maximised when the slope is 0, so the next step is to set d  P /dP P equal to zero and solve for P P : 0=-8P P +1.6P C P P =1.6P C P P =(1.6P C +83.2)/8 P P =P C / So, P P =P C / is Pepsi’s best response function to any price that Coke may choose.

Question 5 ctd. Show what the equilibrium prices are. In the previous slides, we found best response functions for each firm: P P =P C / and P C =P P / A Nash Equilibrium can be found by finding the intersection of these two lines (i.e. where both players play their best response strategy). To find this, we can plug the second function into the first: P P =(P P /5+10.4)/ P P =(P P /5)/4+10.4/ P P =P P / P P =P P / P P -P P /20= P P /20=12.35 P P =12.35*20/19 P P =13 continued on next slide

Question 5 ctd. Show what the equilibrium prices are (ctd). In the previous slides, we found best response functions for each firm and we found P P by plugging one function into the other: P P =P C / and P C =P P / and P P =13 Now, to find P C, we can plug P P =13 into P C =P P /5+10.4: P C =P P / P C =13/ P C = P C =13 So, the best response functions intersect at P C = 13 and P P = 13

Have a nice Holiday! (Also, don’t forget to start studying for Exam 2 and check Moodle for the Week 11 worksheet.)