1 Finishing Up Property Tax © Allen C. Goodman, 2014.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
C HAPTER Elasticity of Demand and Supply price elasticities of demand and supply, income and cross elasticities of demand, and using elasticity to forecast.
Advertisements

Chapter 12 Economic Policy with Floating Exchange Rates
11 MONEY, INTEREST, REAL GDP, AND THE PRICE LEVEL CHAPTER.
INTRA-INDUSTRY TRADE AND THE SCALE EFFECTS OF ECONOMIC INTEGRATION Elisa Riihimäki Statistics Finland, Business Structures September
1 Alternative measures of well-being Joint work by ECO/ELSA/STD.
© The McGraw-Hill Companies, The classical model of macroeconomics The CLASSICAL model of macroeconomics is the polar opposite of the extreme Keynesian.
Multiple Choice Tutorial Chapter 8 Inflation
FINC4101 Investment Analysis
Government Policies That Alter the Private Market Outcome
Discussion Topics Overview of Water Rates in California Legal Framework of Water Rates Water Consumption Patterns Empirical Data – City of Fresno The.
Governments & marketsslide 1 Price Ceilings, Price Floors, and Excise Taxes.
The Price System The market system, also called the price system, performs two important and closely related functions: Price Rationing Resource Allocation.
Copyright © 2001 by Houghton Mifflin Company. All rights reserved. 1 Economics THIRD EDITION By John B. Taylor Stanford University.
International Economics By Robert J. Carbaugh 9th Edition
3. Goods market equilibrium: the IS curve.
PowerPoint Lectures for Principles of Macroeconomics, 9e
The Loanable Funds Market. Equilibrium Interest Rate Savers and buyers are matched in markets governed by supply and demand There are many markets, but.
© 2002 South-Western Publishing 1 Chapter 6 The Black-Scholes Option Pricing Model.
Money, Interest Rates, and Exchange Rates
Chapter 10 Money, Interest, and Income
INDIVIDUAL AND MARKET DEMAND
Chapter 11 Monetary and Fiscal Policy
The Funding of Public Education in Wisconsin: Is a Crisis Brewing? Andrew Reschovsky Professor of Public Affairs and Applied Economics Robert M. La Follette.
Elasticity of Demand and Supply
Chris Forman Avi Goldfarb Shane Greenstein 1.  Did the diffusion of the internet contribute to convergence or divergence of wages across locations in.
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 15 Interest Rates and the Capital Market.
FISCAL CONSTRAINTS & CHALLENGES PRESENTED TO THE BOARD OF EDUCATION DECEMBER 9, Rye City School District.
School Property Tax Relief in Wisconsin Association for Equity in Funding Milwaukee, January 19, 2012 Andrew Reschovsky Professor of Public Affairs and.
Chapter 70 FY14 Preliminary House 1 Proposal Massachusetts Department of Elementary and Secondary Education 1/23/2013.
Chapter 5 Price Elasticity of Demand and Supply
Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 5 The Standard Trade Model.
Smog Reduction’s Impact on California County Growth Study looks at the relationship between changes in environmental quality and population change. San.
State and Local Public Finance Spring 2014, Professor Yinger Lecture 3 Voting.
© Prentice Hall, Corporate Financial Management 3e Emery Finnerty Stowe Capital Budgeting In Practice.
On The Determination of the Public Debt Robert Barro 1979.
Module 30: Long-run Implications of Fiscal Policy:
LECTURE 3 Introduction to Linear Regression and Correlation Analysis
EC 355 International Economics and Finance
International Financial Management
The Effects of Different Land Uses in Missouri on Local Fiscal Conditions – Cost of Community Services Project Update – 4/12/02.
1 Finishing Up Property Tax © Allen C. Goodman, 2008.
Percentages and Elasticity. percentage: “for each hundred” one per cent: one for each hundred ex: "I spend ten percent of my income on movies and other.
What is the proposed ballot issue? Referred measure 3B: Increased funding for education in School District 51 only Shall taxes on peoples’ property (house,
Principles of Microeconomics 6. Price Controls and Taxes*
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 32 Government Debt and Deficits.
Joint Task Force on Local Effort Assistance September 25, 2002 Bill Freund, Consultant To The Task Force.
Employment, unemployment and economic activity Coventry working age population by disability status Source: Annual Population Survey, Office for National.
Demand Chapter 4 Section 3. Key Terms elasticity of demand: a measure of how consumers respond to price changes inelastic: describes demand that is not.
1 Finishing Up Property Tax © Allen C. Goodman, 2015.
The Annual Analysis of Tax Bill Changes. Prepared by the Bedford Board of Assessors December 30, 2013.
Major revenue and expenditure trends for counties and municipalities. G.R.E.A.T. “T EMPLATE ”
Presentable Market Data. Understanding three views of the current market allows Buyers to maximize their ability to evaluate properties, receiving the.
Demand for Local Public Services: The Median Voter and Other Approaches.
© 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved 4-1 Chapter Outline Consumption and Saving Investment Goods Market Equilibrium Chapter 4 Consumption,
AGGREGATE DEMAND, AGGREGATE SUPPLY, AND INFLATION Chapter 25 1.
State and Local Public Finance Professor Yinger Spring 2016 LECTURE 2 THE DEMAND FOR LOCAL PUBLIC SERVICES.
ChapterDemand 8 8 Guiding Questions  Section 1: Understanding Demand  How does the law of demand affect the quantity demanded? The law of demand states.
State and Local Public Finance Professor Yinger Spring 2016 LECTURE 3 VOTING.
© 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved Consumption, Saving, and Investment Chapter 4.
Town meeting handout Article 3
The Loanable Funds Market
Keynesian and Supply Side Diagrams
State and Local Public Finance Professor Yinger Spring 2017
Perspectives of Property Tax Incidence in California Forty Years after Proposition 13 Robert W. Wassmer Professor, Department of Public Policy and Administration.
State and Local Public Finance Professor Yinger Spring 2017
State and Local Public Finance Professor Yinger Spring 2019
State and Local Public Finance Professor Yinger Spring 2017
State and Local Public Finance Professor Yinger Spring 2019
State and Local Public Finance Professor Yinger Spring 2019
State and Local Public Finance Professor Yinger Spring 2019
Presentation transcript:

1 Finishing Up Property Tax © Allen C. Goodman, 2014

2 An Interesting Article

3 Optimal Amount of Public Good Suppose we start at (X i, G i ). Then we vote tax limits to have less G. Is this desirable or not? Private, X Public, G XiXi GiGi GLGL Depends what we want Suppose we’re at (X i,G i ), but our true preferences are (X 2, G 2 ). Is this desirable or not?

4 Bradbury, Katherine, Christopher Mayer, and Karl Case. “Property Tax Limits and Local Fiscal Behavior: Did Massachusetts Cities and Towns Spend Too Little on Town Services under Proposition 2½ ?” Journal of Public Economics, 80 (2) (2001), Journal of Public Economics This paper examines the impact of a specific property tax limit, Proposition 2½ in Massachusetts, on the fiscal behavior of cities and towns in Massachusetts and the capitalization of that behavior into property values. Proposition 2½ passed in November Proposition 2½ places a cap on the effective property tax rate at 2.5% and limits nominal annual growth in property tax revenues to 2.5%, unless residents pass a referendum allowing a greater increase.

5 Initial Result The initial result of Proposition 2½ in many municipalities was to reduce effective property tax rates to 2.5%; 191 of the 351 cities and towns in the Commonwealth (54%) had effective tax rates in fiscal year 1980 that were higher than 2.5%. Jurisdictions could lower their tax rates in two ways: (1) by reducing their tax levy and (2) by raising the estimated market value of local property. While moving to full-value assessment helped some municipalities cut tax rates, about 45% of the Commonwealth’s cities and towns also had to reduce their levies to bring their tax rate down. Just over one-third of the communities (124 of 351) needed only 1 year of property tax reductions; another 9% needed to cut their levies for 2 (24) or even 3 (9) years to bring their rates down to the 2.5% tax rate ceiling. Remember tax rate t = T/V Remember tax rate t = T/V t  if T  t  V 

6 What the study does The study analyzes the 1990–1994 period, a time when Massachusetts municipalities faced significant fiscal stress because of a 30% cut in real state aid and a demographically driven increase in school enrollments. The findings include the following: (1) Proposition 2½ significantly constrained local spending in some communities, with most of its impact on school spending; (2) The constrained communities realized gains in property values to the degree that they were able to increase school spending despite the limitation; and (3) Changes in non-school spending had little impact on property values.

7 How do they do it? The authors explore whether towns that face larger barriers to raising additional tax revenue spend less on local services and thereby become less attractive to potential home buyers. Differences across communities in pre-Proposition 2½ tax rates and conditions allow a comparison of the fiscal decisions (expenditure patterns) of more and less constrained communities and the capitalization of that behavior into house prices. If movers in any period find one town more attractive than another, they will bid up the price of housing in the more attractive town. To the extent that cutting local public spending makes a community less desirable, increases in local spending will be associated with rising housing prices.

8 Beginning … They begin by estimating the relationship between town spending and constraints imposed by Proposition 2½ between 1990 and 1994, a time when Massachusetts cities and towns faced strong budget pressures because of the coincidence of two factors: a steep  in real state aid and a sizable  in school enrollments. The estimates indicate that cities and towns that faced tighter Proposition 2½ budget constraints  their expenditures relative to communities that faced fewer constraints. Furthermore, these relative reductions were not proportional across all spending categories; the evidence shows that Proposition 2½ had a more profound impact on local school spending than on the rest of the local budget.

9 … and Reductions in spending could represent undesirable service cuts forced by the constraint or exactly the kind of change that backers of Proposition 2½ wanted. The original premise behind Proposition 2½ was that local officials had a tendency to spend ‘too much’ unless checked by the voters. Thus, the second part of the paper correlates changes in house prices with changes in spending. To the degree that the premise behind Proposition 2½ is correct, towns that reduce their spending should see their house prices rise faster than those of other communities. Alternatively, if Proposition 2½ makes it more difficult for communities to achieve residents’ preferred level of spending, house prices should fall in towns that reduce their expenditures. Do they  Do they 

10 The Evidence The evidence indicates that Proposition 2½ did affect local house prices through changes in town spending House prices performed worse in communities that had slower increases in spending, suggesting that Proposition 2½ led communities to spend ‘too little’ on services. Communities also did not appear to optimize their spending mix; increases in school spending have a strong positive effect on house prices, while the coefficient on the nonschool spending variable is not statistically different from zero. If goal is to maximize house prices, what should they be doing?

11 Fig. 1. Massachusetts State Government expenditures on local aid.

12 Fig. 2. Massachusetts K-12 public school enrollments.

13 Fig. 3. Proposition 2½ constraints and overrides.

14 Table 2. Spending regression results. Dependent variable: percent change in school or nonschool spending, fiscal years 1990–1994 In the school spending equation (col. 1), the Proposition 2½ variables are almost all individually statistically different from zero, and in all but one case (‘at levy limit, no overrides’) have the anticipated sign. The magnitude of the coefficients suggests that constraints imposed by Proposition 2½ limited school spending to a great extent in many communities. While the average community increased educational spending by 15%, towns that had previously passed an override increased spending by another 6 percentage points. Communities with leeway to raise revenue without an override (ample ‘excess capacity’) typically did so: other things equal, a town whose levy was 5% below its levy limit raised spending 2 percentage points more than a town 0.1% below.

15 Table 3. House price regression results. Dependent variable: percent change in house prices, fiscal years 1990–1994 In col. (1), coefficient on changes in school spending is + and differs sig. from zero. A town that  its school spending 1 std. dev. (8.6%) more than average saw its house prices  about 2% more than a community with the average  in school spending (ave. community saw a  in house prices of 7.7%). When the larger set of instruments is included, col. (2), the differences between the estimated coefficients for school and nonschool spending are even more pronounced. The coefficient on school spending falls from 0.23 to 0.16, but is still sig. different from 0, while the coefficient on nonschool spending becomes slightly neg. and remains statistically indistinguishable from 0 at conventional confidence levels.

16 Conclusions – Proponents and Skeptics Proposition 2½’s proponents and skeptics disagreed about whether (1) the restraints were needed to rein in runaway taxes and spending that local voters apparently were unable to control on their own, or (2) prevented residents from obtaining services they desired and for which they would have been willing to pay. The research results in this article support the latter view. House price data indicate that potential residents of constrained cities and towns (but not unconstrained communities) were willing to pay a premium for increases in school spending. These findings imply constrained communities were spending too little on schools by the end of the 1980s. Put another way, potential home purchasers considered the attraction of increases in school spending during the 1990–1994 period to outweigh the costs of increased taxes to pay for them. Thus, Proposition 2½ had negative consequences for housing demand, and hence home prices, in the communities in which it was binding through its effect on school spending.