Chapter overview This chapter surveys the most prominent work on consumption: John Maynard Keynes: consumption and current income Irving Fisher and Intertemporal.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Numbers Treasure Hunt Following each question, click on the answer. If correct, the next page will load with a graphic first – these can be used to check.
Advertisements

The Supply of Labor Labor Economics Copyright © 2011 by W.W. Norton & Company, Inc.
1. Bringing together the Real and Financial Sectors
1
Chapter 3 Demand and Behavior in Markets. Copyright © 2001 Addison Wesley LongmanSlide 3- 2 Figure 3.1 Optimal Consumption Bundle.
Copyright © 2002 Pearson Education, Inc. Slide 1.
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 13 International Trade in Goods and Assets.
Copyright © 2003 Pearson Education, Inc. Slide 1 Computer Systems Organization & Architecture Chapters 8-12 John D. Carpinelli.
Chapter 4 Individual and Market Demand
Copyright © 2011, Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved. Chapter 6 Author: Julia Richards and R. Scott Hawley.
Properties Use, share, or modify this drill on mathematic properties. There is too much material for a single class, so you’ll have to select for your.
mankiw's macroeconomics modules
PP Test Review Sections 6-1 to 6-6
LIAL HORNSBY SCHNEIDER
Money: definition Money is the stock of assets that can be readily used to make transactions.
Bellwork Do the following problem on a ½ sheet of paper and turn in.
12.1 © 2005 Prentice Hall, Inc. Economics for Managers by Paul Farnham Chapter 12: Spending by Individuals, Firms, and Governments on Real Goods and Services.
Copyright © 2012, Elsevier Inc. All rights Reserved. 1 Chapter 7 Modeling Structure with Blocks.
DEMAND RELATIONSHIPS AMONG GOODS
UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE
1 10 pt 15 pt 20 pt 25 pt 5 pt 10 pt 15 pt 20 pt 25 pt 5 pt 10 pt 15 pt 20 pt 25 pt 5 pt 10 pt 15 pt 20 pt 25 pt 5 pt 10 pt 15 pt 20 pt 25 pt 5 pt Synthetic.
In this chapter, you will learn…
Motivation The Great Depression caused a rethinking of the Classical Theory of the macroeconomy. It could not explain: Drop in output by 30% from 1929.
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 10 A Monetary Intertemporal Model: Money, Prices, and Monetary Policy.
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 12 Keynesian Business Cycle Theory: Sticky Wages and Prices.
Essential Cell Biology
In this chapter, you will learn…
PSSA Preparation.
A Real Intertemporal Model with Investment
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy
Immunobiology: The Immune System in Health & Disease Sixth Edition
Energy Generation in Mitochondria and Chlorplasts
CHAPTER SIXTEEN Consumption.
MANKIW'S MACROECONOMICS MODULES
© 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved Appendix 4.A A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving.
© The McGraw-Hill Companies, 2005 Advanced Macroeconomics Chapter 16 CONSUMPTION, INCOME AND WEALTH.
In this chapter, you will learn:
In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
Review of the Previous Lecture Traditional View of Government Debt Ricardian View of Government Debt Myopia Borrowing Constraints Other Perspectives –Fiscal.
Review of the Previous Lecture
Macroeconomics fifth edition N. Gregory Mankiw PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich macro © 2002 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved CHAPTER SIXTEEN.
MACROECONOMICS © 2010 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved S E V E N T H E D I T I O N PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich N. Gregory Mankiw C H A P.
CHAPTER 16 Consumption slide 0 Class Slides for EC 204 To Accompany Chapter 16.
Macroeconomics fifth edition N. Gregory Mankiw PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich macro © 2002 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved Topic 13: Consumption.
Appendix 4.A A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving.
Consumption and Saving
In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
© 2011 South-Western, a part of Cengage Learning, all rights reserved C H A P T E R 2011 update The Theory of Consumer Choice M icroeconomics P R I N C.
This chapter presents:
IN THIS CHAPTER, YOU WILL LEARN:
Chapter 16: Consumption.
Keynes’s Conjectures 0 < MPC < 1
Review of the previous lecture 1. Real Business Cycle theory  assumes perfect flexibility of wages and prices  shows how fluctuations arise in response.
Chapter Seventeen1 CHAPTER 17 Consumption ® A PowerPoint  Tutorial To Accompany MACROECONOMICS, 7th. Edition N. Gregory Mankiw Tutorial written by: Mannig.
Source: Romer and Bernstein, 2009 and e21, 2011.
M ACROECONOMICS C H A P T E R © 2007 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved SIXTH EDITION PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich N. G REGORY M ANKIW Consumption.
Lecture 3 Consumption. John M. Keynes: Absolute Income Hypothesis Consumption is a linear function of disposable personal income, C = C + cY C = consumption.
KYIV SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS MACROECONOMICS I September-October 2013 Instructor: Maksym Obrizan Lecture notes II # 2. CHAPTER 16 Consumption Household consumption.
Outlines  Introduction Introduction  Excess sensitivity and Excess sensitivity and econometric approach  The simulation design The simulation design.
© 2011 South-Western, a part of Cengage Learning, all rights reserved C H A P T E R 2011 update The Theory of Consumer Choice M icroeconomics P R I N C.
Chapter overview This chapter surveys the most prominent work on consumption: John Maynard Keynes: consumption and current income Irving Fisher and Intertemporal.
Consumption Topic 13: (chapter 16)
mankiw's macroeconomics modules
16 Consumption This long chapter is a survey of the most prominent work on consumption since Keynes. It is particularly useful to students who expect.
A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving
16 Consumption This long chapter is a survey of the most prominent work on consumption since Keynes. It is particularly useful to students who expect.
Irving Fisher and Intertemporal Choice
16 Consumption This long chapter is a survey of the most prominent work on consumption since Keynes. It is particularly useful to students who expect.
Presentation transcript:

Consumption CHAPTER SIXTEEN This long chapter is a survey of the most prominent work on consumption since Keynes. After reviewing the Keynesian consumption function and its implications, the chapter presents Irving Fisher’s theory of intertemporal choice, the basis for much subsequent work on consumption. The chapter presents the Life-Cycle and Permanent Income Hypotheses, then discusses Hall’s Random Walk Hypothesis. Finally, there is a brief discussion of some very recent work by Laibson and others on psychology and economics, in particular how the pull of instant gratification can cause consumers to deviate from perfect rationality.

Chapter overview This chapter surveys the most prominent work on consumption: John Maynard Keynes: consumption and current income Irving Fisher and Intertemporal Choice Franco Modigliani: the Life-Cycle Hypothesis Milton Friedman: the Permanent Income Hypothesis Robert Hall: the Random-Walk Hypothesis David Laibson: the pull of instant gratification

Keynes’s Conjectures 0 < MPC < 1 APC falls as income rises where APC = average propensity to consume = C/Y Income is the main determinant of consumption. The MPC was defined in chapter 3 and used in various chapters since.

The Keynesian Consumption Function A consumption function with the properties Keynes conjectured: C Y c = MPC = slope of the consumption function c 1

The Keynesian Consumption Function As income rises, the APC falls (consumers save a bigger fraction of their income). C Y Pick a point on the consumption function; that point represents a particular combination of consumption and income. Now draw a ray from the origin to that point. The slope of that ray equals the average propensity to consume at that point. (Why? The slope equals the rise over the run. The rise from zero to that point equals the value of C at that point. The run from zero to that point equals the value of Y at that point. Hence, the rise over the run equals C/Y, or the APC.) At higher values of Y, the APC (or the slope of the ray from the origin) is smaller. This is what Keynes conjectured: at higher values of income, people spend a smaller fraction of their income. slope = APC

Early Empirical Successes: Results from Early Studies Households with higher incomes: consume more  MPC > 0 save more  MPC < 1 save a larger fraction of their income  APC  as Y  Very strong correlation between income and consumption  income seemed to be the main determinant of consumption

Problems for the Keynesian Consumption Function Based on the Keynesian consumption function, economists predicted that C would grow more slowly than Y over time. This prediction did not come true: As incomes grew, the APC did not fall, and C grew just as fast. Simon Kuznets showed that C/Y was very stable in long time series data.

The Consumption Puzzle Consumption function from long time series data (constant APC ) C Y Consumption function from cross-sectional household data (falling APC )

Irving Fisher and Intertemporal Choice The basis for much subsequent work on consumption. Assumes consumer is forward-looking and chooses consumption for the present and future to maximize lifetime satisfaction. Consumer’s choices are subject to an intertemporal budget constraint, a measure of the total resources available for present and future consumption

The basic two-period model Period 1: the present Period 2: the future Notation Y1 is income in period 1 Y2 is income in period 2 C1 is consumption in period 1 C2 is consumption in period 2 S = Y1 - C1 is saving in period 1 (S < 0 if the consumer borrows in period 1)

Deriving the intertemporal budget constraint Period 2 budget constraint: Rearrange to put C terms on one side and Y terms on the other: Explain the intuition/interpretation of the period 2 budget constraint. If students understand it, then everything else follows nicely. Finally, divide through by (1+r ):

The intertemporal budget constraint present value of lifetime consumption present value of lifetime income If your students are not familiar with the present value concept, it is explained in a very nice FYI box on p.439.

The intertemporal budget constraint The budget constraint shows all combinations of C1 and C2 that just exhaust the consumer’s resources. Saving Consump = income in both periods Borrowing Y1 Y2 The point (Y1, Y2) is always on the budget line because C1=Y1, C2=Y2 is always possible, regardless of the real interest rate or the existence of borrowing constraints. To obtain the expression for the horizontal intercept, set C2=0 in the equation for the intertemporal budget constraint and solve for C1. Similarly, the expression for the vertical intercept is the value of C2 when C1=0. There is intuition for these expressions. Take the vertical intercept, for example. If the consumer sets C1=0, then he will be saving all of his first-period income. In the second period, he gets to consume this saving plus interest earned, (1+r)Y1, as well as his second-period income. If the consumer chooses C1<Y1, then the consumer will be saving, so his C2 will exceed his Y2. Conversely, if consumer chooses C1>Y1, then consumer is borrowing, so his second-period consumption will fall short of his second-period income (he must use some of the second-period income to repay the loan). C1

The intertemporal budget constraint The slope of the budget line equals -(1+r ) 1 (1+r ) Y1 Y2 The slope of the budget line equals -(1+r): To increase C1 by one unit, the consumer must sacrifice (1+r) units of C2. C1

Consumer preferences Higher indifference curves represent higher levels of happiness. An indifference curve shows all combinations of C1 and C2 that make the consumer equally happy. C1 C2 IC2 IC1

Consumer preferences C1 C2 The slope of an indifference curve at any point equals the MRS at that point. Marginal rate of substitution (MRS ): the amount of C2 consumer would be willing to substitute for one unit of C1. IC1 1 MRS

Optimization C1 C2 The optimal (C1,C2) is where the budget line just touches the highest indifference curve. At the optimal point, MRS = 1+r O All points along the budget line are affordable, including the two points where the orange indifference curve intersects the budget line. However, the consumer prefers (and can afford) point O to these points, because O is on a higher indifference curve. At the optimal point, the slope of the indifference curve (MRS) equals the slope of the budget line (1+r).

How C responds to changes in Y An increase in Y1 or Y2 shifts the budget line outward. C1 C2 Results: Provided they are both normal goods, C1 and C2 both increase, …regardless of whether the income increase occurs in period 1 or period 2.

Keynes vs. Fisher Keynes: current consumption depends only on current income Fisher: current consumption depends only on the present value of lifetime income; the timing of income is irrelevant because the consumer can borrow or lend between periods.

How C responds to changes in r An increase in r pivots the budget line around the point (Y1,Y2 ). A A B As depicted here, C1 falls and C2 rises. However, it could turn out differently… Y1 Y2

How C responds to changes in r income effect If consumer is a saver, the rise in r makes him better off, which tends to increase consumption in both periods. substitution effect The rise in r increases the opportunity cost of current consumption, which tends to reduce C1 and increase C2. Both effects  C2. Whether C1 rises or falls depends on the relative size of the income & substitution effects. Note: Keynes conjectured that the interest rate matters for consumption only in theory. In Fisher’s theory, the interest rate doesn’t affect current consumption if the income and substitution effects are of equal magnitude. After you have shown and explained this slide, it would be useful to pause for a moment and ask your students (perhaps working in pairs) to do the analysis of an increase in the interest rate on the consumption choices of a borrower. In that case, the income effect tends to reduce both current and future consumption, because the interest rate hike makes the borrower worse off. The substitution effect still tends to increase future consumption while reducing current consumption. In the end, current consumption falls unambiguously; future consumption falls if the income effect dominates the substitution effect, and rises if the reverse occurs.

Constraints on borrowing In Fisher’s theory, the timing of income is irrelevant because the consumer can borrow and lend across periods. Example: If consumer learns that her future income will increase, she can spread the extra consumption over both periods by borrowing in the current period. However, if consumer faces borrowing constraints (aka “liquidity constraints”), then she may not be able to increase current consumption and her consumption may behave as in the Keynesian theory even though she is rational & forward-looking

Constraints on borrowing The budget line with no borrowing constraints Y2 Y1

Constraints on borrowing The borrowing constraint takes the form: C1  Y1 C1 C2 The budget line with a borrowing constraint Y2 Similar to Figure 16-8 on p. 445. Y1

Consumer optimization when the borrowing constraint is not binding The borrowing constraint is not binding if the consumer’s optimal C1 is less than Y1. (Figure 16-9, panel (a), on p.446) In this case, the consumer optimally was not going to borrow, so his inability to borrow has no impact on his choices. Y1

Consumer optimization when the borrowing constraint is binding The optimal choice is at point D. But since the consumer cannot borrow, the best he can do is point E. E (Figure 16-9, panel (b), on p.446) In this case, the consumer would like to borrow to achieve his optimal consumption at point D. If he faces a borrowing constraint, though, then the best he can do is at point E. If you have a few minutes of classtime available, have your students do the following experiment: (This is especially useful if you have recently covered Chapter 15 on Government Debt) Suppose Y1 is increased by $1000 while Y2 is reduced by $1000(1+r), so that the present value of lifetime income is unchanged. Determine the impact on C1 - when consumer does not face a binding borrowing constraint - when consumer does face a binding borrowing constraint Then relate the results to the discussion of Ricardian Equivalence from Chapter 15. Note that the intertemporal redistribution of income in this exercise could be achieved by a debt-financed tax cut in period 1, followed by a tax increase in period 2 that is just sufficient to retire the debt. In the text, pages 446-447 contain a case study on the high Japanese saving rate that relates to the material on borrowing constraints just covered. D Y1

The Life-Cycle Hypothesis due to Franco Modigliani (1950s) Fisher’s model says that consumption depends on lifetime income, and people try to achieve smooth consumption. The LCH says that income varies systematically over the phases of the consumer’s “life cycle,” and saving allows the consumer to achieve smooth consumption.

The Life-Cycle Hypothesis The basic model: W = initial wealth Y = annual income until retirement (assumed constant) R = number of years until retirement T = lifetime in years Assumptions: zero real interest rate (for simplicity) consumption-smoothing is optimal The initial wealth could be zero, or could be a gift from parents to help the consumer get started on her own.

The Life-Cycle Hypothesis Lifetime resources = W + RY To achieve smooth consumption, consumer divides her resources equally over time: C = (W + RY )/T , or C = aW + bY where a = (1/T ) is the marginal propensity to consume out of wealth b = (R/T ) is the marginal propensity to consume out of income

Implications of the Life-Cycle Hypothesis The Life-Cycle Hypothesis can solve the consumption puzzle: The APC implied by the life-cycle consumption function is C/Y = a(W/Y ) + b Across households, wealth does not vary as much as income, so high income households should have a lower APC than low income households. Over time, aggregate wealth and income grow together, causing APC to remain stable.

Implications of the Life-Cycle Hypothesis $ The LCH implies that saving varies systematically over a person’s lifetime. Wealth Income Saving Consumption Dissaving Retirement begins End of life

The Permanent Income Hypothesis due to Milton Friedman (1957) The PIH views current income Y as the sum of two components: permanent income Y P (average income, which people expect to persist into the future) transitory income Y T (temporary deviations from average income) The middle of page 452 gives two hypothetical examples that help students understand the concepts of permanent and transitory income.

The Permanent Income Hypothesis Consumers use saving & borrowing to smooth consumption in response to transitory changes in income. The PIH consumption function: C = aY P where a is the fraction of permanent income that people consume per year.

The Permanent Income Hypothesis The PIH can solve the consumption puzzle: The PIH implies APC = C/Y = aY P/Y To the extent that high income households have higher transitory income than low income households, the APC will be lower in high income households. Over the long run, income variation is due mainly if not solely to variation in permanent income, which implies a stable APC.

PIH vs. LCH In both, people try to achieve smooth consumption in the face of changing current income. In the LCH, current income changes systematically as people move through their life cycle. In the PIH, current income is subject to random, transitory fluctuations. Both hypotheses can explain the consumption puzzle.

The Random-Walk Hypothesis due to Robert Hall (1978) based on Fisher’s model & PIH, in which forward-looking consumers base consumption on expected future income Hall adds the assumption of rational expectations, that people use all available information to forecast future variables like income.

The Random-Walk Hypothesis If PIH is correct and consumers have rational expectations, then consumption should follow a random walk: changes in consumption should be unpredictable. A change in income or wealth that was anticipated has already been factored into expected permanent income, so it will not change consumption. Only unanticipated changes in income or wealth that alter expected permanent income will change consumption.

Implication of the R-W Hypothesis If consumers obey the PIH and have rational expectations, then policy changes will affect consumption only if they are unanticipated. This result is important because many policies affect the economy by influencing consumption and saving. For example, a tax cut to stimulate aggregate demand only works if consumers respond to the tax cut by increasing spending. The R-W Hypothesis implies that consumption will respond only if consumers had not anticipated the tax cut. This result also implies that consumption will respond immediately to news about future changes in income. Students connect with the following example: Suppose a student is job-hunting in her senior year for a job that will begin after graduation. If the student secures a job with a higher salary than she had expected, she is likely to start spending more now in anticipation of the higher-than-expected permanent income.

The Psychology of Instant Gratification Theories from Fisher to Hall assumes that consumers are rational and act to maximize lifetime utility. recent studies by David Laibson and others consider the psychology of consumers.

The Psychology of Instant Gratification Consumers consider themselves to be imperfect decision-makers. E.g., in one survey, 76% said they were not saving enough for retirement. Laibson: The “pull of instant gratification” explains why people don’t save as much as a perfectly rational lifetime utility maximizer would save.

Two Questions and Time Inconsistency 1. Would you prefer (A) a candy today, or (B) two candies tomorrow? 2. Would you prefer (A) a candy in 100 days, or (B) two candies in 101 days? In studies, most people answered A to question 1, and B to question 2. A person confronted with question 2 may choose B. 100 days later, when he is confronted with question 1, the pull of instant gratification may induce him to change his mind. The text discusses time inconsistency in this context. Time inconsistency was introduced and defined in chapter 14.

Summing up Keynes suggested that consumption depends primarily on current income. Recent work suggests instead that consumption depends on current income expected future income wealth interest rates Economists disagree over the relative importance of these factors and of borrowing constraints and psychological factors.

Chapter summary 1. Keynesian consumption theory Keynes’ conjectures MPC is between 0 and 1 APC falls as income rises current income is the main determinant of current consumption Empirical studies in household data & short time series: confirmation of Keynes’ conjectures in long time series data: APC does not fall as income rises

Chapter summary 2. Fisher’s theory of intertemporal choice Consumer chooses current & future consumption to maximize lifetime satisfaction subject to an intertemporal budget constraint. Current consumption depends on lifetime income, not current income, provided consumer can borrow & save. 3. Modigliani’s Life-Cycle Hypothesis Income varies systematically over a lifetime. Consumers use saving & borrowing to smooth consumption. Consumption depends on income & wealth.

Chapter summary 4. Friedman’s Permanent-Income Hypothesis Consumption depends mainly on permanent income. Consumers use saving & borrowing to smooth consumption in the face of transitory fluctuations in income. 5. Hall’s Random-Walk Hypothesis Combines PIH with rational expectations. Main result: changes in consumption are unpredictable, occur only in response to unanticipated changes in expected permanent income.

Chapter summary 6. Laibson and the pull of instant gratification Uses psychology to understand consumer behavior. The desire for instant gratification causes people to save less than they rationally know they should.