Chapter Four Utility. Preferences - A Reminder u x y: x is preferred strictly to y.  x  y: x and y are equally preferred. u x y: x is preferred at least.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Preferences. Rationality in Economics u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker always chooses its most preferred alternative from its set of available.
Advertisements

Chapter Eighteen Technology. Technologies  A technology is a process by which inputs are converted to an output.  E.g. labor, a computer, a projector,
Chapter 3 Preferences Choose the “best” thing one can “afford” Start with consumption bundles (a complete list of the goods that is involved in consumer’s.
Chapter 4 Utility Functions. Utility Ordinal Utility: The only property of a utility assignment is “how it orders the bundles of goods.” The size of the.
Chapter 3. * Prerequisite: A binary relation R on X is said to be Complete if xRy or yRx for any pair of x and y in X; Reflexive if xRx for any x in X;
Utilities Indifference curves
Tastes/Preferences Indifference Curves.
Combinations (X1, Y1) and (X2, Y2) provide the same level of utility
PREFERENCES AND UTILITY
Axioms of Rational Choice
Chapter Six Demand. Income Changes u A plot of quantity demanded against income is called an Engel curve.
Chapter Four Utility. Utility Functions   A utility function U(x) represents a preference relation if and only if: x’ x” U(x’) > U(x”) x’ x” U(x’)
Utility.
Chapter Three Preferences.
Axioms of Rational Choice
Utility Functions A utility function U(x) represents a preference relation if and only if: x’ x” U(x’) > U(x”) x’ x” U(x’) < U(x”) x’  x” U(x’) = U(x”).
Chapter Six Demand. Properties of Demand Functions u Comparative statics analysis of ordinary demand functions -- the study of how ordinary demands x.
Chapter Three Preferences. Rationality in Economics u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker always chooses its most preferred alternative from its set.
Chapter Four Utility. Utility Functions u A preference relation that is complete, reflexive, transitive and continuous can be represented by a continuous.
Utility.
Chapter Three Preferences. Rationality in Economics u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker always chooses its most preferred alternative from its set.
Preferences. Preference Relation The consumer strictly prefers bundle X to bundle Y: The consumer is indifferent between X and Y:
Consumer Behavior There are 3 steps involved in studying consumer behavior. Consumer preferences: describe how and why people prefer one good to another.
Chapter Six Demand. Properties of Demand Functions u Comparative statics analysis of ordinary demand functions -- the study of how ordinary demands x.
Chapter Four Utility.
1 Chapter 3 PREFERENCES AND UTILITY Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
Utility. Utility Functions u Utility is a concept used by economists to describe consumer preferences. u Utility function is a function that assigns a.
Course: Microeconomics Text: Varian’s Intermediate Microeconomics 1.
Chapter Three Preferences. Rationality in Economics u Behavioral Postulate: An economic decisionmaker always chooses her most preferred alternative from.
Chapter Three Preferences 偏好. Structure 3.1 Preference relations 3.2 Assumptions about preferences 3.3 Graphical representation of preferences—indifference.
Chapter 5 Choice.
1 Welcome to EC 209: Managerial Economics- Group A By: Dr. Jacqueline Khorassani Week Four.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 4 Utility. © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 2 Preferences - A Reminder u x y: x is preferred strictly to y.  x.
Chapter 4 Utility.
Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior. Chapter 3: Consumer BehaviorSlide 2 Topics to be Discussed Consumer Preferences Budget Constraints Consumer Choice Revealed.
Course: Microeconomics Text: Varian’s Intermediate Microeconomics 1.
Chapter 3 Consumer Preferences.
Consumer Preferences and the Concept of Utility
1 Chapter 3 PREFERENCES AND UTILITY Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
Chapter 3 Preferences.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 3 Preferences.
1 Preferences Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 – Spring 2009.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 4 Utility. © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 2 Preferences - A Reminder u x y: x is preferred strictly to y.  x.
Chapter Three Preferences. u Consumer behavior is best understood in three distinct steps: 1. Consumer Preferences: The first step is to find a practical.
L03 Utility. Big picture u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from the set of affordable alternatives. u Budget.
Chapter 4 UTILITY.
Chapter Four Utility 效用.
Budgetary and Other Constraints on Choice
L02 Preferences. Rationality in Economics u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from the set of affordable alternatives.
L03 Utility. Quiz How much do you like microeconomics A: I love it (unconditionally) B: I cannot live without it C: I would die for it D: All of the above.
 This will explain how consumers allocate their income over many goods.  This looks at individual’s decision making when faced with limited income and.
UTILITY. Chapter 11 What is Utility? A way of representing preferences Utility is not money (but it is a useful analogy) Typical relationship between.
Preferences and Utility
Chapter 3 Preferences Intermediate Microeconomics:
18 Technology.
4 Utility.
L03 Utility.
L03 Utility.
3 Preferences.
Chapter Three Preferences.
Chapter Six Demand.
Chapter Four Utility.
L03 Utility.
L03 Utility.
Chapter 3 Preferences.
L03 Utility.
Utility Functions f ~ p p
Subject:Economics Class:1st Semester
Presentation transcript:

Chapter Four Utility

Preferences - A Reminder u x y: x is preferred strictly to y.  x  y: x and y are equally preferred. u x y: x is preferred at least as much as is y.  ~ 

Preferences - A Reminder u Completeness: For any two bundles x and y it is always possible to state either that x y or that y x. ~  ~ 

Preferences - A Reminder u Reflexivity: Any bundle x is always at least as preferred as itself; i.e. x x. ~ 

Preferences - A Reminder u Transitivity: If x is at least as preferred as y, and y is at least as preferred as z, then x is at least as preferred as z; i.e. x y and y z x z. ~  ~  ~ 

Utility Functions u A preference relation that is complete, reflexive, transitive and continuous can be represented by a continuous utility function. u Continuity means that small changes to a consumption bundle cause only small changes to the preference level.

Utility Functions   A utility function U(x) represents a preference relation if and only if: x’ x” U(x’) > U(x”) x’ x” U(x’) < U(x”) x’  x” U(x’) = U(x”). ~   

Utility Functions u Utility is an ordinal (i.e. ordering) concept. u E.g. if U(x) = 6 and U(y) = 2 then bundle x is strictly preferred to bundle y. But x is not preferred three times as much as is y.

Utility Functions & Indiff. Curves u Consider the bundles (4,1), (2,3) and (2,2).  Suppose (2,3) (4,1)  (2,2). u Assign to these bundles any numbers that preserve the preference ordering; e.g. U(2,3) = 6 > U(4,1) = U(2,2) = 4. u Call these numbers utility levels. 

Utility Functions & Indiff. Curves u An indifference curve contains equally preferred bundles. u Equal preference  same utility level. u Therefore, all bundles in an indifference curve have the same utility level.

Utility Functions & Indiff. Curves  So the bundles (4,1) and (2,2) are in the indiff. curve with utility level U   But the bundle (2,3) is in the indiff. curve with utility level U  6. u On an indifference curve diagram, this preference information looks as follows:

Utility Functions & Indiff. Curves U  6 U  4 (2,3) (2,2)  (4,1) x1x1 x2x2 

Utility Functions & Indiff. Curves u Another way to visualize this same information is to plot the utility level on a vertical axis.

U(2,3) = 6 U(2,2) = 4 U(4,1) = 4 Utility Functions & Indiff. Curves 3D plot of consumption & utility levels for 3 bundles x1x1 x2x2 Utility

Utility Functions & Indiff. Curves u This 3D visualization of preferences can be made more informative by adding into it the two indifference curves.

Utility Functions & Indiff. Curves U  U  Higher indifference curves contain more preferred bundles. Utility x2x2 x1x1

Utility Functions & Indiff. Curves u Comparing more bundles will create a larger collection of all indifference curves and a better description of the consumer’s preferences.

Utility Functions & Indiff. Curves U  6 U  4 U  2 x1x1 x2x2

Utility Functions & Indiff. Curves u As before, this can be visualized in 3D by plotting each indifference curve at the height of its utility index.

Utility Functions & Indiff. Curves U  6 U  5 U  4 U  3 U  2 U  1 x1x1 x2x2 Utility

Utility Functions & Indiff. Curves u Comparing all possible consumption bundles gives the complete collection of the consumer’s indifference curves, each with its assigned utility level. u This complete collection of indifference curves completely represents the consumer’s preferences.

Utility Functions & Indiff. Curves x1x1 x2x2

x1x1 x2x2

x1x1 x2x2

x1x1 x2x2

x1x1 x2x2

x1x1 x2x2

x1x1

x1x1

x1x1

x1x1

x1x1

x1x1

x1x1

x1x1

x1x1

x1x1

u The collection of all indifference curves for a given preference relation is an indifference map. u An indifference map is equivalent to a utility function; each is the other.

Utility Functions u There is no unique utility function representation of a preference relation. u Suppose U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 x 2 represents a preference relation. u Again consider the bundles (4,1), (2,3) and (2,2).

Utility Functions   U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 x 2, so U(2,3) = 6 > U(4,1) = U(2,2) = 4; that is, (2,3) (4,1)  (2,2). 

Utility Functions   U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 x 2 (2,3) (4,1)  (2,2). u Define V = U 2. 

Utility Functions   U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 x 2 (2,3) (4,1)  (2,2). u Define V = U 2.   Then V(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 2 x 2 2 and V(2,3) = 36 > V(4,1) = V(2,2) = 16 so again (2,3) (4,1)  (2,2). u V preserves the same order as U and so represents the same preferences.  

Utility Functions   U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 x 2 (2,3) (4,1)  (2,2). u Define W = 2U 

Utility Functions   U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 x 2 (2,3) (4,1)  (2,2). u Define W = 2U   Then W(x 1,x 2 ) = 2x 1 x so W(2,3) = 22 > W(4,1) = W(2,2) = 18. Again, (2,3) (4,1)  (2,2). u W preserves the same order as U and V and so represents the same preferences.  

Utility Functions u If –U is a utility function that represents a preference relation and – f is a strictly increasing function, u then V = f(U) is also a utility function representing. ~  ~ 

Goods, Bads and Neutrals u A good is a commodity unit which increases utility (gives a more preferred bundle). u A bad is a commodity unit which decreases utility (gives a less preferred bundle). u A neutral is a commodity unit which does not change utility (gives an equally preferred bundle).

Goods, Bads and Neutrals Utility Water x’ Units of water are goods Units of water are bads Around x’ units, a little extra water is a neutral. Utility function

Some Other Utility Functions and Their Indifference Curves u Instead of U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 x 2 consider V(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 + x 2. What do the indifference curves for this “perfect substitution” utility function look like?

Perfect Substitution Indifference Curves x1x1 x2x2 x 1 + x 2 = 5 x 1 + x 2 = 9 x 1 + x 2 = 13 V(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 + x 2.

Perfect Substitution Indifference Curves x1x1 x2x2 x 1 + x 2 = 5 x 1 + x 2 = 9 x 1 + x 2 = 13 All are linear and parallel. V(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 + x 2.

Some Other Utility Functions and Their Indifference Curves u Instead of U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 x 2 or V(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 + x 2, consider W(x 1,x 2 ) = min{x 1,x 2 }. What do the indifference curves for this “perfect complementarity” utility function look like?

Perfect Complementarity Indifference Curves x2x2 x1x1 45 o min{x 1,x 2 } = min{x 1,x 2 } = 5 min{x 1,x 2 } = 3 W(x 1,x 2 ) = min{x 1,x 2 }

Perfect Complementarity Indifference Curves x2x2 x1x1 45 o min{x 1,x 2 } = min{x 1,x 2 } = 5 min{x 1,x 2 } = 3 All are right-angled with vertices on a ray from the origin. W(x 1,x 2 ) = min{x 1,x 2 }

Some Other Utility Functions and Their Indifference Curves u A utility function of the form U(x 1,x 2 ) = f(x 1 ) + x 2 is linear in just x 2 and is called quasi- linear. u E.g. U(x 1,x 2 ) = 2x 1 1/2 + x 2.

Quasi-linear Indifference Curves x2x2 x1x1 Each curve is a vertically shifted copy of the others.

Some Other Utility Functions and Their Indifference Curves u Any utility function of the form U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 a x 2 b with a > 0 and b > 0 is called a Cobb- Douglas utility function. u E.g. U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 1/2 x 2 1/2 (a = b = 1/2) V(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 x 2 3 (a = 1, b = 3)

Cobb-Douglas Indifference Curves x2x2 x1x1 All curves are hyperbolic, asymptoting to, but never touching any axis.

Marginal Utilities u Marginal means “incremental”. u The marginal utility of commodity i is the rate-of-change of total utility as the quantity of commodity i consumed changes; i.e.

Marginal Utilities u E.g. if U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 1/2 x 2 2 then

Marginal Utilities u E.g. if U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 1/2 x 2 2 then

Marginal Utilities u E.g. if U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 1/2 x 2 2 then

Marginal Utilities u E.g. if U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 1/2 x 2 2 then

Marginal Utilities u So, if U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 1/2 x 2 2 then

Marginal Utilities and Marginal Rates-of-Substitution  The general equation for an indifference curve is U(x 1,x 2 )  k, a constant. Totally differentiating this identity gives

Marginal Utilities and Marginal Rates-of-Substitution rearranged is

Marginal Utilities and Marginal Rates-of-Substitution rearranged is And This is the MRS.

Marg. Utilities & Marg. Rates-of- Substitution; An example u Suppose U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 x 2. Then so

Marg. Utilities & Marg. Rates-of- Substitution; An example MRS(1,8) = - 8/1 = -8 MRS(6,6) = - 6/6 = -1. x1x1 x2x U = 8 U = 36 U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 x 2 ;

Marg. Rates-of-Substitution for Quasi-linear Utility Functions u A quasi-linear utility function is of the form U(x 1,x 2 ) = f(x 1 ) + x 2. so

Marg. Rates-of-Substitution for Quasi-linear Utility Functions  MRS = - f  (x 1 ) does not depend upon x 2 so the slope of indifference curves for a quasi-linear utility function is constant along any line for which x 1 is constant. What does that make the indifference map for a quasi- linear utility function look like?

Marg. Rates-of-Substitution for Quasi-linear Utility Functions x2x2 x1x1 Each curve is a vertically shifted copy of the others. MRS is a constant along any line for which x 1 is constant. MRS = - f(x 1 ’) MRS = -f(x 1 ”) x1’x1’ x1”x1”

Monotonic Transformations & Marginal Rates-of-Substitution u Applying a monotonic transformation to a utility function representing a preference relation simply creates another utility function representing the same preference relation. u What happens to marginal rates-of- substitution when a monotonic transformation is applied?

Monotonic Transformations & Marginal Rates-of-Substitution u For U(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 x 2 the MRS = - x 2 /x 1. u Create V = U 2 ; i.e. V(x 1,x 2 ) = x 1 2 x 2 2. What is the MRS for V? which is the same as the MRS for U.

Monotonic Transformations & Marginal Rates-of-Substitution u More generally, if V = f(U) where f is a strictly increasing function, then So MRS is unchanged by a positive monotonic transformation.