By Ronald R. Braeutigam & John C. Panzar Presented by Fadhila Diversification Incentives under “price-based” and “cost-based” Regulation.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Gender Perspectives in Introduction to Tariffs Gender Module #5 ITU Workshops on Sustainability in Telecommunication Through Gender & Social Equality.
Advertisements

Part 6 Perfect Competition
Chapter 7 Production, Firms and the Market. Profit & the Firm The Bottom Line Incentive and reward for risks Leads to better decision making and greater.
Perfect Competition 12.
 Introduction  Simple Framework: The Margin Rule  Model with Product Differentiation, Variable Proportions and Bypass  Model with multiple inputs.
Modeling the Market Process: A Review of the Basics
14 Perfect Competition CHAPTER Notes and teaching tips: 4, 7, 8, 9, 25, 26, 27, and 28. To view a full-screen figure during a class, click the red “expand”
When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Explain a perfectly competitive firm’s profit-
Perfect Competition In Markets Ir. Muhril A, M.Sc., Ph.D.1 Perfect Competition In Markets
Harcourt, Inc. items and derived items copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. Monopoly u A monopoly is the sole seller of its product.  its product does not.
The Averch-Johnson Effect
Ch. 12: Monopoly Causes of monopoly
Ch 8: Profit Max Under Perfect Competition Three assumptions in p.c. model: 1) Price-taking: many small firms, none can affect mkt P by  ing Q  no mkt.
Chapter 10: Perfect competition
Ch. 12: Perfect Competition.
Monopoly A monopoly is a single supplier to a market
Economic Efficiency and the Competitive Ideal © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
12 MONOPOLY CHAPTER.
8 Perfect Competition  What is a perfectly competitive market?  What is marginal revenue? How is it related to total and average revenue?  How does.
Profit Maximization and the Decision to Supply
LUBS1940: Topic 5 Perfect Competition and Monopoly Market Structures
Competitive Markets for Goods and Services
John R. Swinton, Ph.D. Center for Economic Education Georgia College & State University.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2013 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2009 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Chapter 9 Lecture 11 AND 12 PURE COMPETITION.
Copyright © 2004 South-Western Monopoly vs. Competition While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker. A firm is considered.
Price Discrimination Price discrimination is the practice of selling different units of a good or service for different prices. To be able to price discriminate,
Chapter 10-Perfect Competition McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2015 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
13 PART 5 Perfect Competition
Michael Parkin ECONOMICS 5e CHAPTER 13 Monopoly 1.
Perfect Competition Mikroekonomi 730g  The Four Conditions For Perfect Competition  The Short-run Condition For Profit Maximization  The Short-run.
Chapter 9 Pure Competition McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Pure Competition Chapter 10. Chapter 23 Table 23.1 Four types of Market Organization.
Chpt 12: Perfect Competition 1. Quick Reference to Basic Market Structures Market StructureSeller Entry Barriers# of SellersBuyer Entry Barriers# Buyers.
Copyright 2008 The McGraw-Hill Companies Pure Competition.
CHAPTER 8 Managing in Competitive, Monopolistic, and Monopolistically Competitive Markets McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2014 by The McGraw-Hill Companies,
Lecture Notes. Firm Supply in Competitive Markets Market Environment: ways firms interact in making pricing and output decisions. Possibilities: (1) Perfect.
MONOPOLY. Monopoly Recall characteristics of a perfectly competitive market: –many buyers and sellers –market participants are “price takers” –economic.
1 Chapters 9: Perfect Competition. 2 Perfect Competition Assumptions: Free Entry All buyers and sellers have perfect information Many firms producing.
Chapter 14 Firms in Competitive Markets. What is a Competitive Market? Characteristics: – Many buyers & sellers – Goods offered are largely the same –
Ch. 12 : Firms in Perfectly Competitive Markets ECONOMICS
Eco 6351 Economics for Managers Chapter 6. Competition Prof. Vera Adamchik.
PERFECT COMPETITION 11 CHAPTER. Objectives After studying this chapter, you will able to  Define perfect competition  Explain how price and output are.
Monopoly CHAPTER 12. After studying this chapter you will be able to Explain how monopoly arises and distinguish between single-price monopoly and price-discriminating.
Introduction to Business LECTURE 2: Introduction to Business MGT
Perfect Competition CHAPTER 10 When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Explain a perfectly.
Models of Competition Part I: Perfect Competition
1.  exists when a single firm is the sole producer of a product for which there are no close substitutes. 2.
Perfect Competition CHAPTER 11. What Is Perfect Competition? Perfect competition is an industry in which  Many firms sell identical products to many.
Perfect Competition CHAPTER 11 C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to 1 Explain a perfectly.
Managerial Economics Market Structures Aalto University School of Science Department of Industrial Engineering and Management January 12 – 28, 2016 Dr.
Perfect Competition. Objectives After studying this chapter, you will able to  Define perfect competition  Explain how price and output are determined.
The Industry Supply Curve. Industry Supply Curve Industry Supply Curve is the relationship between price and the total output of an industry as a whole.
Chapter 14 Questions and Answers.
© 2010 Pearson Education Canada Perfect Competition ECON103 Microeconomics Cheryl Fu.
Lecture 7 Chapter 20: Perfect Competition 1Naveen Abedin.
12 PERFECT COMPETITION. © 2012 Pearson Education.
Perfect Competition Ch. 20, Economics 9 th Ed, R.A. Arnold.
AP Microeconomics Final Review
Chapter 14 Firms in Competitive Markets
Unit 3 : Reading Quiz # 9 : 6 points
C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to Explain a perfectly competitive firm’s profit-
Cost Curves & Competitive Markets Test
#1 MC MR=D=AR= P ATC AVC Q $ Should the firm produce?
AP MICRO REVIEW FINAL EXAM
Perfect Competition Chapter 11.
THE FIRM AND ITS CUSTOMERS: PART 2
PURE CompetITion.
Econ 100 Lecture 4.2 Perfect Competition.
Perfect Competition Econ 100 Lecture 5.4 Perfect Competition
Presentation transcript:

By Ronald R. Braeutigam & John C. Panzar Presented by Fadhila Diversification Incentives under “price-based” and “cost-based” Regulation

Participation in two markets (regulated and unregulated) 1.Occurred in connection with regulatory reform of deregulation & divestiture: a)Example: AT&T divestiture companies sought to provide: i.Basic regulated telephone service ii.Information service supplied in increasingly competitive market (non-regulated) 2. Issues: a)Enables the company to cross-subsidize in the competitive market b)Regulators can not easily structure a fair price taking advantage of economies of scope Introduction

“Cost-Based” regulation form (combines elements from ROR & FDC) 1.Allocate costs that can be directly and unambiguously attributed 2.Allocate costs that cannot be unambiguously assigned to an individual service using allocation formula For each service, TR=TC “Price-Based” regulation form 1.The firm is regulated by rate caps determined exogenously from the non- competitive market Cost-Based Vs. Price-Based

Models developed w.r.t: 1.Incentives for cost misreporting 2.Choice of Technology 3.Cost-reducing innovation 4.Choices of prices 5.Choices of output levels 6.Diversification into competitive markets To analyze regulation prospect for economically efficient diversification by regulated firms operating under cost-based and price-based form regulations Objective

Model of regulated firm in two markets: 1.Market 1 “core market” Firm operate in a monopoly Relatively inelastic demand Y 1 is level of output, P 1 (y 1 ) is the inverse demand for the service 2.Market 2 “noncore market” Firm operate in a competitive market as a price taker Homogeneous service with n number of other identical unregulated firms Y 2 is level of output produced by regulated company, Y e is level of output produced by each other firm Q = (Y 2 + nY e ) is total output Equilibrium at P e = C e ’’(y e ) Consumer surplus is constant, Producer surplus is zero Problem Structure I

Problem Structure II Regulated firm cost structure: C(y 1,y 2 ) = F + c 1 (y 1 ) + c 2 (y 2 ) … (1) Where, F = common cost of production (fixed) c i (y i ) = cost of production that can be unambiguously be associated with the production of service i (i=1,2)

ROR regulation (incentive for cost misreport) Averch & Johnson (1962) key assumption of profit-maximizing firm behavior operates under constraint on the ROR earned on investment is allowed ROR exceeds the actual cost of capital Joskow (1974) suggested that in reality regulators might attempt to allow a return equal to the actual cost of capital In Averch & Johnson model where regulated firms serves two markets (a monopoly and competitive market)a firm might have a long-run incentive to price below LRMC in the competitive market ROR Regulation I

This analysis differs from Averch & Johnson in two aspects: 1.Similar to Joskow, assume that regulator allows a rate of return equal to the actual cost of capital 1.A single ROR constraint is imposed to the entire enterprise instead of employing a practice tries to separate monopoly from competitive service in revenue proceeding ROR Regulation II

Common allocator functions in regulatory practice include: Relative quantities f(y 1,y 2 ) = y 1 /(y 1 +y 2 ); Relative attributable costf(y1,y2) = c1/(c1+c2); Relative revenues f(y 1,y 2 ) = R 1 (y 1 )/(R 1 (y 1 )+P e *y 2 ) where 0≤f(y 1,y 2 )≤1 But they assume that regulatory constraint takes the form of: If the firm wishes to enter into the competitive market, it has to provide a level of output that maximizes the profit π (since it’s a price taker in MKT 2) Cost-Based Regulation Model I

The Lagrange multiplier: Where, R 1 (y 1 ) = y 1 p 1 (y 1 ) max. amount of revenue at MKT 1 u 1 = waste directly attributed to the core service u 2 = waste directly attributed to the noncore service u F = waste characterized as common cost 0<λ<1 implies that u 1 =0, u 2 =0, u F =0 Given the technology, the enterprise avoids unproductive inputs An assumption anticipated that a firm can has incentive to choose technology that do not minimize cost (Proposition 2) Cost-Based Regulation Model II

Choice of output level I

Choice of output level II

Constraint lies in the negative profit region Allocator function discourage diversification except for point E Choice of output level III

Question: Does the firm has an incentive to employ a technology that fails to minimize cost? Generalized the regulated firm cost structure Attributable cost function for each service would have common cost F as the amount spent by the firm on a public input Constrained optimization problem (to minimize TC of output produced ) Proposition 2 “The Profit-maximizing firm operating under a binding ROR constraint may choose an inefficient level of common facilities. It will overinvest (underinvest) in common facilities if, at the margin, the cost reduction such facilities yield for the core service are less than (greater than) the common costs allocated to he core service.” Choice of Technology

Applying envelop theorem on equation (4): The firm would prefer a cost reduction in the noncore market to a reduction in the common cost The firm would prefer a cost reduction in the common cost to a reduction in the core service Innovation cost is not addressed Under ROR incentive to innovate are affected by the way the cost of innovation effort are entered into the constraint. Four cases on dealing with cost-reducing expenditure: 1.Case 1: Allocating all to the noncore service 2.Case 2: Allocating all as common cost 3.Case 3: Allocating all to the core service 4.Case 4: Allocate it based on the designed service Cost-Reducing innovation Incentive I

Case 1: Allocating all to the noncore service The firm would innovate in the noncore market up to the point at which the last dollar's expenditure yields a dollar's cost reduction. The firm would behave as an unconstrained profit maximizer. The firm would underinvest in innovation in both common costs and in the core market. The revenue requirement is decreased as costs fall No addition to the revenue requirement is made to allow for the cost- reducing expenditures. The firm will not innovate as much as it would have in the absence of the regulatory constraint. Cost-Reducing innovation Incentive II

Case 2: Allocating all as common cost Overinvest in noncore market: Enable it to invest beyond the point at which the one dollar expenditure is just equal to the cost reduction. Underinvest in the core market: The last dollar's expenditure would tighten the constraint therefore be unprofitable for the firm Case 3: Allocating all to the core service overinvest in common costs and in the noncore market Case 4: Allocate it based on the designed service Increases the revenue requirement represented by the regulatory constraint by: 1.Innovative expenditures attributable to the noncore service 2.Innovative expenditures which are common No overinvestment or underinvestment Cost-Reducing innovation Incentive III

Proposition 3. (Cost reducing innovation). “If costs of innovation are treated homogeneously (as in Cases 1, 2 and 3), the levels of innovative effort will generally not be efficient, leading either to underinvestment in cost-reducing innovation in the core market, overinvestment in cost-reducing innovation in the noncore market, or both. If the regulator attempts to allocate expenditures on cost-reducing efforts (as in Case 4), it will have to deal with the incentive the firm will have to characterize such costs as attributable to the core service wherever possible.” Cost-Reducing innovation Incentive IV

Objective: To show if products are vertically related to one another the previous findings about rate-of-return regulation are unchanged Profit of the firm will be: ROR constraint All the propositions stated holds 1.Proposition 1: Pareto inefficiency 2.Proposition 2: Choice of technology 3.Proposition 3: Cost reducing innovation Vertical Relationship

ROR constraint The major difference between markets 2 and 3 is that for some reason service 3 is included in the ROR constraint for the firm, while service 2 remains outside that constraint. Proposition 4 “If the regulated firm's activities in a competitive market are included in the ROR constraint, the firm will have an incentive to overproduce; market price will be below marginal cost in such a market.” Pricing below MC

Price-cap (Price-based): “A regulator sets a ceiling on the rate to be charged in the regulated market; as long as the ceiling is satisfied, the firm can be allowed to enter into and produce whatever output levels it desires in other (non-regulated) markets.” Economic properties 1.The firm has no incentive to waste variables u 1, u 2, & u F do not enter into a price-level constraint at all. 2.Incentives to misreport cost allocations and choose an inefficient technology disappear, since cost allocation is not required under this regulatory scheme. 3.The firm will also have the same incentive to undertake cost-reducing innovation as an unregulated firm 4.The firm will produce in the noncore market up to the point at which marginal cost equals price. the chosen output will be Pareto efficient. 5.if the price cap is appropriately chosen, the firm will diversify into a noncore market if and only if diversification is Pareto superior to remaining undiversified Diversification Incentive under Price-Cap Regulation I

Core Service (no diversification): At Point E, breakeven point Noncore Service (with diversification): Point M, constrained profit maximizing point Point G, Pareto efficient P 1 & P 2 are unchanged, so movement from E to M does not alter CS Diversification Incentive under Price-Cap Regulation II

Price-cap Problems: 1.Pareto-efficient market outcomes at point G must be known when the price –cap is set i.Too low price-cap will threaten economic viability ii.Too high price-cap will make ratepayers as losers in the core market 2.Can the price-cap adequately capture variations in factor prices, general price levels, technology, consumer tastes, and income 3.can the regulator credibly precommit to a system of price-cap regulation? 4.What form a price index should take when a firm provides two or more core services Diversification Incentive under Price-Cap Regulation III

The ROR regulation gives the firm: 1.An incentives to misreport cost allocations, 2.Choose an inefficient technology (in some cases) 3.Undertake cost-reducing innovation in an inefficient way 4.Under produce in a noncore market 5.Price below marginal cost in a competitive market which happens to be included in the set of core markets regulated by an aggregate ROR constraint 6.View diversification decisions inefficiently The Price-cap can induce the firm to: 1.Minimize costs 2.Produce efficiently in noncore markets 3.Undertake cost-reducing innovation 4.Diversify into a noncore market if only diversification is efficient. Since cost allocation is not required under Price-cap regulation Incentives to misreport cost allocations and choose an inefficient technology simply disappear, Conclusion