Valuation 2 and 3: Demand and welfare theory

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Competition and the Market
Advertisements

Social welfare and price changes Udayan Roy ECO61 Microeconomic Analysis Fall 2008.
Measuring Costs and Benefits Measuring Benefits and Costs (See Chap 4): –Consumers’ Willingness to Pay (WTP) –Consumer Surplus (CS) –Producers’ Surplus.
Chapter Fourteen Consumer’s Surplus. Monetary Measures of Gains-to- Trade  Suppose you know you can buy as much gasoline as you choose at a given price.
Welfare measurement: individual CS, CV, EV and PS
Chapter 14 Consumer’s Surplus
Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 – Spring 2009
Consumer Surplus. Monetary Measures of Gains-to- Trade  Basic idea of consumer surplus: We want a measure of how much a person is willing to pay for.
Consumer Equilibrium and Market Demand Chapter 4.
Welfare Measure with Price Changes
 Homework #2 due Thursday  Exam #1 on Thursday  Writing Assignment due Oct. 27th.
Chapter Fourteen Consumer’s Surplus. Monetary Measures of Gains-to- Trade  You can buy as much gasoline as you wish at $1 per gallon once you enter the.
Consumer Equilibrium and Market Demand Chapter 4.
Valuation 2: Environmental Demand Theory Why valuation? Theory of Consumer Demand Restricted Expenditure and Demand Functions for the Consumer.
Valuation 3: Welfare Measures Willingness to pay and willingness to act compensation Equivalent variation versus compensating variation Price changes versus.
The Idealized Competitive Model
Chapter 20: Consumer Choice
1 Chapter 6 From Demand to Welfare. Main Topics Dissecting the effects of a price change Measuring changes in consumer welfare using demand curves 2.
Elasticity and Consumer Surplus
 Homework #8 due Next Thursday  Group Outline due Nov. 11 (next Thurs.)
1 Consumer Choice and Demand Chapter 6 © 2006 Thomson/South-Western.
© 2008 Pearson Addison Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter Five Consumer Welfare and Policy Analysis.
Chapter 5: Theory of Consumer Behavior
1 13. Expenditure minimization Econ 494 Spring 2013.
ECMB36 LECTURE NOTES MEASURING CHANGES IN SOCIAL WELFARE Townley, Chapter 5.
Frank Cowell: Consumer Welfare CONSUMER: WELFARE MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell July Almost essential Consumer Optimisation.
Frank Cowell: Microeconomics Consumer: Welfare MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell Almost essential Firm: Optimisation Consumption: Basics.
Theory of Consumer Behavior
Modelling the labour market Labour supply decisions The effect of a minimum wage.
Economics of the Environment and Natural Resources Tutor Roger Perman (Economics) Overview This module does not assume a prior background in economics.
Welfare economics Outline Expressing changes in human well-being (utility) in monetary terms Deciding between monetary measures that are equally theoretically.
ECON 6012 Cost Benefit Analysis Memorial University of Newfoundland
CONSUMER SURPLUS, PRODUCER SURPLUS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS
Public Policy Analysis MPA 404 Lecture 16. Previous Lecture  A revision of the concepts of equilibrium.  The short run disequilibrium, and the long.
Consumption, Production, Welfare B: Consumer Behaviour Univ. Prof. dr. Maarten Janssen University of Vienna Winter semester 2013.
Chapter 10 CBA and valuation1 CHAPTER 10 Cost-Benefit Analysis and Valuation.
PARETO OPTIMALITY AND THE EFFICIENCY GOAL
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada 4/1 Chapter 4 More Demand Theory.
Module 12: Indifference Curves and Budget Constraints
Measuring Welfare Changes of Individuals Exact Utility Indicators –Equivalent Variation (EV) –Compensating Variation (CV) Relationship between Exact Utility.
5.1 Household Behavior and Consumer Choice We have studied the basics of markets: how demand and supply determine prices and how changes in demand and.
Chapter 4 Demand I have enough money to last me the rest of my life, unless I buy something. Jackie Mason.
 Consumer welfare from a good is the benefit a consumer gets from consuming that good in excess of the cost of the good.  If you buy a good for exactly.
Chapter 5 Consumer Welfare and Policy Analysis
Consumer Equilibrium and Market Demand
On visible choice set and scope sensitivity: - Dealing with the impact of study design on the scope sensitivity Improving the Practice of Benefit Transfer:
Expected Utility Lecture I. Basic Utility A typical economic axiom is that economic agents (consumers, producers, etc.) behave in a way that maximizes.
1 Consumer Choice and Demand CHAPTER 6 © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
1 Consumer Choice and Demand CHAPTER 6 © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
Summing up1 ECON 4910 Spring 2007 Environmental Economics Lecture 12 Summing up Lecturer: Finn R. Førsund.
©McGraw-Hill Education, 2014
Frank Cowell: Microeconomics Exercise 4.12 MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell November 2006.
Chapter Five The Demand Curve and the Behavior of Consumers.
Modeling the Market Process: A Review of the Basics Chapter 2 © 2007 Thomson Learning/South-WesternCallan and Thomas, Environmental Economics and Management,
Maximizing Wealth Means Maximizing What Others See as our Wealth. Wealth is what we value and we assume in macroeconomics that if everyone is at least.
Demand: It is the quantity of a good or service that customers are willing and able to purchase during a specified period under a given set of economic.
Environmental Demand Theory M Rafiq. Discussion Demand curve is an information on importance of a good for individual Out of limited income, allocation.
 This will explain how consumers allocate their income over many goods.  This looks at individual’s decision making when faced with limited income and.
1 Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization CHAPTER 6 Appendix © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
Consumer Welfare 1. 2 One way to evaluate the welfare cost of a price increase (from p x 0 to p x 1 ) would be to compare the expenditures required to.
Consumer Choice and Demand
Measuring Welfare Changes of Individuals
Consumer Choice and Demand
Theory of Consumer Behavior
Chapter Fourteen Consumer’s Surplus.
Chapter 5.
Theory of Consumer Behavior
Chapter 14 Consumer’s Surplus.
Chapter 5: Theory of Consumer Behavior
Chapter 5: Theory of Consumer Behavior
Presentation transcript:

Valuation 2 and 3: Demand and welfare theory What is so special about environmental goods? Theory of consumer demand for market goods Welfare effects of a price change: Equivalent variation versus compensating variation Consumer demand for environmental goods Welfare effects of a quantity change: Equivalent surplus versus compensating surplus Theory and practise

Last week Price and Value Total Economic Value Why and what to value? Uses of economic valuation

Why valuation? We must make choices about how to manage the human impact on natural systems Greater use of a particular environmental service or greater protection of a specific natural system results in less of something else (trade-off) To make the most of scarce resources we must compare what is gained from an activity with what is sacrificed by undertaking that activity Why? To assess the net impact of changes

What is so special about environmental goods and services? In economics the criterion for assessing the net impacts („benefits“ and „costs“ ) is the well-being of the members of society Well-being is defined as the individuals‘ preferences for goods Preferences are typically represented through demand functions Changes in well-being can be inferred by changes in prices or quantity Problem with environmental goods: no markets exist Individuals have preferences nevertheless Changes in well-being are derived by individuals’ max. willingness to pay for gains or (WTP) min. willingness to accept compensation for losses (WTA) Prices and marginal WTP or WTA are equivalent

Consumer demand theory: Market goods Consider a consumer who has a utility function This consumer maximises the utility of a bundle of goods x, with prices p, and income M This solves to the ordinary or Marshallian demand function Substituting the expression for xi gives the indirect utility function this gives you the highest level of utility attainable, given prices p and income Y

Consumer demand theory -2 Roy‘s identity relates x and v: That is, the derivative of indirect utility with respect to the ith price yields the ith demand function, after normalising by the marginal utility of income

Constructing an ordinary demand function x2 p1 I3 I2 I1 x1(p1,p2,y), demand for x1 C Budget constraint C A A B B x1 x1

Consumer demand theory -3 An alternative to generate a demand curve is to keep utility constant instead of income Here the consumer is assumed to minimize total expenditure to achieve a given level of utility at price level P This solves to the compensated or Hicksian demand function This gives the quantity demanded as a function of price and utility Income is of no consequence; as prices change, expenditures are adjusted to maintain constant utility.

Consumer demand theory -4 Demand for the ith commodity is the derivative of the expenditure function to the price of i

Constructing a compensated demand function x2 p1 I1 hx1(p1,p2,U1), demand for x1 C C A A B B Budget constraint x1 x1

Ordinary and compensated demand We derived ordinary and compensated demand functions Ordinary demand functions bundle income and price effects together Compensated demand function do not have this problem, but look at price effects alone To evaluate the effect of a governmental policy that changes relative prices we want to examine the price effect only Typically, economists estimate ordinary demand functions, as utility cannot be observed

Income and price effects x2 e/p21 A Price effect e/p22 B Income effect C I1 I0 D M x1

Surplus from ordinary and compensated demand If AB is an ordinary demand function like x1(p1,p2,M): Consumer Surplus= ABCD-BCDE=ABE A If AB is a compensated demand function like hx1(p1,p2,U1) the area under the curve correspond to changes in constant utility expenditures E B p*1 D C x*1 x1

Ordinary and compensated demand - 3 hx1(p1,p2,U0) Compensated demand hx1(p1,p2,U1) A B x1(p1,p2,M) Ordinary demand x1

Ordinary and compensated demand - 4 Properties of both demand functions are related We observe ordinary demand functions, but we are interested in compensated demand functions – the latter can be derived from the former if agents are rational, and even then it involves many steps including integration

Welfare effects of price changes Consider price fall P*  P# Willingness to pay (WTP) to secure price fall is known as compensating variation (CV) Willingness to accept compensation (WTAC) to forego price fall is known as equivalent variation There are gains and loss, so four measures (EV) Price decreases WTP to secure a gain (CV) WTAC to forego a gain (EV) Price increases WTP to prevent a loss (EV) WTAC to tolerate a loss (CV)

Welfare measures Compensating variation is the quantity of income that compensates consumers for a price change, that is, returns them to their original welfare Equivalent variation is an income change that yields the same utility change as the price change Both terms can be defined using the expenditure function

Ordinary and compensated demand: Welfare effects Compensated variation: ABEG Consumer Surplus: AEFB Equivilent variation: ADFB => If p decreases CV<DCS<EV hx1(p1,p2,U0) Compensated demand hx1(p1,p2,U1) E A D p01 F p11 x1(p1,p2,M) B G Ordinary demand x01 x11 x1

Consumer demand theory: Environmental goods Often demand for environmental commodities is only indirectly observed People change their behaviour in response to changes in the environment, but do not purchase environmental quality directly We‘ll repeat the analysis above, but now assume that only n-1 goods are directly traded; the nth good (named q) is the environmental commodity of interest

Restricted demand The environmental good q affects individuals utility This consumer maximises the utility of a bundle of goods X, with prices P, and income M This leads to restricted ordinary demand functions and a restricted indirect utility Again, Roy‘s identity relates x and v

Restricted demand - 2 The dual of the problem: Minimising expenditure This leads to the expenditure function function The Hicks-compensated demand function for changes in prices is The Hicks-compensated inverse demand (marginal WTP) for changes in q is Rearranging the equation yields the compensating demand for q

Restricted demand - 3 But... we can determine how expenditures change with q for some price of good x and implicitly defining a demand function for q only if we assume weak complementarity That is, if the demand for good x drops to zero, then demand for good q goes to zero as well and marginal changes in q no longer affect expenditure Example: if swimming is too expensive, water quality is irrelevant

Restricted compensated demand Choke price The income equivalent or marginal WTP for a change in q: ABC B C p*1 hx1(p1,q0,U1), initial demand for x1 hx1(p1,q0 +Dq ,U1), demand for x1 after increase in q D x1

Welfare effects of quantity changes Measures of „surplus“ instead of „variation“ when consumers are not free to vary the quantity of q In case of quantity changes, compensating and equivalent surplus are defined as U0 results from (P,q0,M)

Measures of changes in welfare for an environmental good Expenditure on private good x, M D ES/px If q0 increases to q1, income has to be reduced by CS/p to keep the same utility B M M=pxx A CS/px U3 U2 C U1 q0 q1 Quantity/quality of environmental good q

WTP and WTAC If the good is relatively unimportant ES and CS are roughly the same If environmental goods are relatively scarcer than market commodities, one may expect the compensating variation/surplus (WTP) to be smaller than the equivalent variation/surplus (WTAC) for improvements Differences between WTP and WTAC are mainly due to income effects People view gains and losses differently WTP is limited to an individual‘s income, WTAC is unbounded Confirmed by empirical studies, but not uncontested Implies that surveys, policies need to be carefully designed Income effects are small only if the good is of little value relative to your overall wealth

Theory and practice Horowitz and McConnell collect 208 observations of WTP and WTAC from 45 studies For all studies, the average ratio WTAC/WTP is 7.2 (0.9) However, for public or non-market goods, the ratio is 10.4 (2.5) For ordinary goods, it is 2.9 (0.3) For money, it is 2.1 (0.2)

Methods for measuring demand Indirect methods (use values) Surrogate market where we observe expenditures on a related goods Infer information on the trade-off between money and the environmental good Hedonic pricing Household production function approach Direct methods (use and non-use values) Hypothetical/constructed market Contingent valuation: “value contingent on there being a market” Choice modelling