Variable Public Good Quantities E.g. how many broadcast TV programs, or how much land to include into a national park.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Welfare Analysis Consumer Surplus; Producer Surplus
Advertisements

4. Public Goods.
Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. Public Goods -- Definition u A good is purely public if it is both nonexcludable and nonrival in consumption. –Nonexcludable.
MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell
Chapter 4: Public Goods Econ 330: Public Finance Dr. Reyadh Faras
Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods. u 35: Public Goods u 36: Asymmetric Information u 17: Auctions u 33: Law & Economics u 34: Information Technology u.
Chapter 36 Public Goods Suppose there are two nonsmokers and one smoker. Even if nonsmokers are entitled to clean air, they first have to agree among themselves.
Equilibrium. Market Equilibrium  A market is in equilibrium when total quantity demanded by buyers equals total quantity supplied by sellers.  An equilibrium.
Chapter Twenty-Nine Exchange. u Two consumers, A and B. u Their endowments of goods 1 and 2 are u E.g. u The total quantities available and units of good.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 14 Consumer’s Surplus.
Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 – Spring 2009
1 Intermediate Microeconomics Equilibrium. 2 Partial Equilibrium We have now derived both the market demand curve (Q d (p)) and market supply curve (Q.
14. Externalities Varian, Chapter 33.
Chapter Thirty-Three Law and Economics. Effects of Laws u Property right assignments affect –asset, income and wealth distributions; v e.g. nationalized.
General Equilibrium and Efficiency. General Equilibrium Analysis is the study of the simultaneous determination of prices and quantities in all relevant.
1 Analyzing the Economic Impact of Taxes Module 7.
Market size and tax competition Gianmarco I.P. Ottaviano, Tanguy van Ypersele.
Frank Cowell: Efficiency-Waste EFFICIENCY: WASTE MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell Almost essential Welfare and Efficiency Almost essential.
Chapter 34 Externalities. Externalities An externality is a cost or a benefit imposed upon someone by actions taken by others. The cost or benefit is.
1 Externalities and Public Goods Chapter Chapter Seventeen Overview 1.Motivation 2.Inefficiency of Competition with Externalities 3.Allocation Property.
Topic 2: Production Externalities
Chapter 7 General Equilibrium and Market Efficiency
Chapter Fourteen Consumer’s Surplus. Monetary Measures of Gains-to- Trade  You can buy as much gasoline as you wish at $1 per gallon once you enter the.
Agent Technology for e-Commerce Chapter 10: Mechanism Design Maria Fasli
Chapter Twenty-Nine Exchange. u Two consumers, A and B. u Their endowments of goods 1 and 2 are u E.g. u The total quantities available and units of good.
Public Choice Chapter 6 (Part 2).
Chapter Thirty-Four Externalities. u An externality is a cost or a benefit imposed upon someone by actions taken by others. The cost or benefit is thus.
PUBLIC GOODS Snyder and Nicholson, Copyright ©2008 by Thomson South-Western. All rights reserved.
Welfare economics Outline Expressing changes in human well-being (utility) in monetary terms Deciding between monetary measures that are equally theoretically.
ECON 6012 Cost Benefit Analysis Memorial University of Newfoundland
1 Exchange Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 – Spring 2009.
Terrel Gallaway: Public Finance 1 Excess Burden u The First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics says that, under ideal conditions, the behavior of.
Chapter 9 The Analysis of Competitive Markets. Chapter 9Slide 2 The Efficiency of a Competitive Market When do competitive markets generate an inefficient.
Market Efficiency and Market Failure Autumn 2011.
1 Exchange. 2 Two consumers, A and B. Their endowments of goods 1 and 2 are E.g. The total quantities available and units of good 1 units of good 2. and.
Market Failure. Occurs when free market forces, using the price mechanism, fail to produce the products that people want, in the quantities they desire.
Microeconomics 2 John Hey. Last 2 weeks of teaching Today: lecture 33 on Public Goods. Tomorrow: lecture 34 on Asymmetric Information. Next Monday: last.
Mechanism Design II CS 886:Electronic Market Design Sept 27, 2004.
Oct The Analysis of Competitive Markets.
1 Analyzing the Economic Impact of Taxes Module 7.
1 Intermediate Microeconomics Public Goods. 2 Consider an unregulated world, where a firm has the implicit property rights to the air. Therefore, it is.
Market Failure. Occurs when free market forces, using the price mechanism, fail to produce the products that people want, in the quantities they desire.
Chapter 36 Public Goods.
C h a p t e r 2 EFFICIENCY, MARKETS, AND GOVERNMENTS
Analyzing the Economic Impact of Taxes
Chapter 32 Exchange.
Taxes & Subsidies Economic Welfare Supplement
16 Equilibrium.
L23 Public Goods.
Implementation in Bayes-Nash equilibrium
Chapter Thirty-Two Externalities.
L23 Public Goods.
L23 Public Goods.
L24 Public Goods.
L24 Public Goods.
14 Consumer’s Surplus.
Implementation in Bayes-Nash equilibrium
L23 Public Goods.
Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 – Spring 2009
L24 Public Goods.
Chapter 14 Consumer’s Surplus.
L24 Public Goods.
Chapter Thirty-Three Law and Economics.
L24 Public Goods.
Chapter 14 Consumer’s Surplus.
Chapter Thirty-Five Public Goods.
Chapter 37 Public Goods Key Concept: Free Riding.
L24 Public Goods.
Taxes & Subsidies Economic Welfare Supplement
Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 – Spring 2009
Presentation transcript:

Variable Public Good Quantities E.g. how many broadcast TV programs, or how much land to include into a national park.

Variable Public Good Quantities E.g. how many broadcast TV programs, or how much land to include into a national park. c(G) is the production cost of G units of public good. Two individuals, A and B. Private consumptions are x A, x B.

Variable Public Good Quantities Budget allocations must satisfy

Variable Public Good Quantities Budget allocations must satisfy MRS A & MRS B are A & B’s marg. rates of substitution between the private and public goods. Pareto efficiency condition for public good supply is

Variable Public Good Quantities Pareto efficiency condition for public good supply is Why?

Variable Public Good Quantities Pareto efficiency condition for public good supply is Why? The public good is nonrival in consumption, so 1 extra unit of public good is fully consumed by both A and B.

Variable Public Good Quantities Suppose MRS A is A’s utility-preserving compensation in private good units for a one-unit reduction in public good. Similarly for B.

Variable Public Good Quantities is the total payment to A & B of private good that preserves both utilities if G is lowered by 1 unit.

Variable Public Good Quantities is the total payment to A & B of private good that preserves both utilities if G is lowered by 1 unit. Since, making 1 less public good unit releases more private good than the compensation payment requires  Pareto-improvement from reduced G.

Variable Public Good Quantities Now suppose

Variable Public Good Quantities Now suppose is the total payment by A & B of private good that preserves both utilities if G is raised by 1 unit.

Variable Public Good Quantities Now suppose is the total payment by A & B of private good that preserves both utilities if G is raised by 1 unit. This payment provides more than 1 more public good unit  Pareto-improvement from increased G.

Variable Public Good Quantities Hence, necessarily, efficient public good production requires

Variable Public Good Quantities Hence, necessarily, efficient public good production requires Suppose there are n consumers; i = 1,…,n. Then efficient public good production requires

Demand Revelation A scheme that makes it rational for individuals to reveal truthfully their private valuations of a public good is a revelation mechanism. E.g. the Groves-Clarke taxation scheme. How does it work?

Demand Revelation N individuals; i = 1,…,N. All have quasi-linear preferences. v i is individual i’s true (private) valuation of the public good. Individual i must provide c i private good units if the public good is supplied.

Demand Revelation n i = v i - c i is net value, for i = 1,…,N. Pareto-improving to supply the public good if

Demand Revelation n i = v i - c i is net value, for i = 1,…,N. Pareto-improving to supply the public good if

Demand Revelation If and or and then individual j is pivotal; i.e. changes the supply decision.

Demand Revelation What loss does a pivotal individual j inflict on others?

Demand Revelation What loss does a pivotal individual j inflict on others? If then is the loss.

Demand Revelation What loss does a pivotal individual j inflict on others? If then is the loss.

Demand Revelation For efficiency, a pivotal agent must face the full cost or benefit of her action. The GC tax scheme makes pivotal agents face the full stated costs or benefits of their actions in a way that makes these statements truthful.

Demand Revelation The GC tax scheme: Assign a cost c i to each individual. Each agent states a public good net valuation, s i. Public good is supplied if otherwise not.

Demand Revelation A pivotal person j who changes the outcome from supply to not supply pays a tax of

Demand Revelation A pivotal person j who changes the outcome from supply to not supply pays a tax of A pivotal person j who changes the outcome from not supply to supply pays a tax of

Demand Revelation Note: Taxes are not paid to other individuals, but to some other agent outside the market.

Demand Revelation Why is the GC tax scheme a revelation mechanism?

Demand Revelation Why is the GC tax scheme a revelation mechanism? An example: 3 persons; A, B and C. Valuations of the public good are: $40 for A, $50 for B, $110 for C. Cost of supplying the good is $180.

Demand Revelation Why is the GC tax scheme a revelation mechanism? An example: 3 persons; A, B and C. Valuations of the public good are: $40 for A, $50 for B, $110 for C. Cost of supplying the good is $180. $180 < $40 + $50 + $110 so it is efficient to supply the good.

Demand Revelation Assign c 1 = $60, c 2 = $60, c 3 = $60.

Demand Revelation Assign c 1 = $60, c 2 = $60, c 3 = $60. B & C’s net valuations sum to $( ) + $( ) = $40 > 0. A, B & C’s net valuations sum to $( ) + $40 = $20 > 0.

Demand Revelation Assign c 1 = $60, c 2 = $60, c 3 = $60. B & C’s net valuations sum to $( ) + $( ) = $40 > 0. A, B & C’s net valuations sum to $( ) + $40 = $20 > 0. So A is not pivotal.

Demand Revelation If B and C are truthful, then what net valuation s A should A state?

Demand Revelation If B and C are truthful, then what net valuation s A should A state? If s A > -$20, then A makes supply of the public good, and a loss of $20 to him, more likely.

Demand Revelation If B and C are truthful, then what net valuation s A should A state? If s A > -$20, then A makes supply of the public good, and a loss of $20 to him, more likely. A prevents supply by becoming pivotal, requiring s A + $( ) + $( ) < 0; I.e. A must state s A < -$40.

Demand Revelation Then A suffers a GC tax of -$10 + $50 = $40, A’s net payoff is - $20 - $40 = -$60 < -$20.

Demand Revelation Then A suffers a GC tax of -$10 + $50 = $40, A’s net payoff is - $20 - $40 = -$60 < -$20. A can do no better than state the truth; s A = -$20.

Demand Revelation Assign c 1 = $60, c 2 = $60, c 3 = $60.

Demand Revelation Assign c 1 = $60, c 2 = $60, c 3 = $60. A & C’s net valuations sum to $( ) + $( ) = $30 > 0. A, B & C’s net valuations sum to $( ) + $30 = $20 > 0.

Demand Revelation Assign c 1 = $60, c 2 = $60, c 3 = $60. A & C’s net valuations sum to $( ) + $( ) = $30 > 0. A, B & C’s net valuations sum to $( ) + $30 = $20 > 0. So B is not pivotal.

Demand Revelation What net valuation s B should B state?

Demand Revelation What net valuation s B should B state? If s B > -$10, then B makes supply of the public good, and a loss of $10 to him, more likely.

Demand Revelation What net valuation s B should B state? If s B > -$10, then B makes supply of the public good, and a loss of $10 to him, more likely. B prevents supply by becoming pivotal, requiring s B + $( ) + $( ) < 0; I.e. B must state s B < -$30.

Demand Revelation Then B suffers a GC tax of -$20 + $50 = $30, B’s net payoff is - $10 - $30 = -$40 < -$10. B can do no better than state the truth; s B = -$10.

Demand Revelation Assign c 1 = $60, c 2 = $60, c 3 = $60.

Demand Revelation Assign c 1 = $60, c 2 = $60, c 3 = $60. A & B’s net valuations sum to $( ) + $( ) = -$30 < 0. A, B & C’s net valuations sum to $( ) - $30 = $20 > 0.

Demand Revelation Assign c 1 = $60, c 2 = $60, c 3 = $60. A & B’s net valuations sum to $( ) + $( ) = -$30 < 0. A, B & C’s net valuations sum to $( ) - $30 = $20 > 0. So C is pivotal.

Demand Revelation What net valuation s C should C state?

Demand Revelation What net valuation s C should C state? s C > $50 changes nothing. C stays pivotal and must pay a GC tax of -$( ) - $( ) = $30, for a net payoff of $( ) - $30 = $20 > $0.

Demand Revelation What net valuation s C should C state? s C > $50 changes nothing. C stays pivotal and must pay a GC tax of -$( ) - $( ) = $30, for a net payoff of $( ) - $30 = $20 > $0. s C < $50 makes it less likely that the public good will be supplied, in which case C loses $110 - $60 = $50.

Demand Revelation What net valuation s C should C state? s C > $50 changes nothing. C stays pivotal and must pay a GC tax of -$( ) - $( ) = $30, for a net payoff of $( ) - $30 = $20 > $0. s C < $50 makes it less likely that the public good will be supplied, in which case C loses $110 - $60 = $50. C can do no better than state the truth; s C = $50.

Demand Revelation GC tax scheme implements efficient supply of the public good.

Demand Revelation GC tax scheme implements efficient supply of the public good. But, causes an inefficiency due to taxes removing private good from pivotal individuals.