Game Theory: Inside Oligopoly

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Oligopoly.
Advertisements

16 Oligopoly.
Oligopoly and Game Theory ETP Economics 101. Imperfect Competition  Imperfect competition refers to those market structures that fall between perfect.
Copyright©2004 South-Western 16 Oligopoly. Copyright © 2004 South-Western BETWEEN MONOPOLY AND PERFECT COMPETITION Imperfect competition refers to those.
Copyright © 2004 South-Western CHAPTER 16 OLIGOPOLY.
Copyright © 2010 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 10 Game Theory:
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy
Part 8 Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly
Oligopoly Games An Oligopoly Price-Fixing Game
Game Theory. Learning Objectives Define game theory, and explain how it helps to better understand mutually interdependent management decisions Explain.
1 Welcome to EC 209: Managerial Economics- Group A By: Dr. Jacqueline Khorassani Week Eleven.
1 Industrial Organization Collusion Univ. Prof. dr. Maarten Janssen University of Vienna Summer semester Week 17.
David Bryce © Adapted from Baye © 2002 Game Theory: The Competitive Dynamics of Strategy MANEC 387 Economics of Strategy MANEC 387 Economics.
Games With No Pure Strategy Nash Equilibrium Player 2 Player
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada 16/1 Chapter 16 Game Theory and Oligopoly.
Non-Cooperative Game Theory To define a game, you need to know three things: –The set of players –The strategy sets of the players (i.e., the actions they.
Chapter 10 Game Theory and Strategic Behavior
Game Theory: Inside Oligopoly
Strategic Decisions Making in Oligopoly Markets
ECON 201 OLIGOPOLIES & GAME THEORY 1. FIGURE 12.4 DUOPOLY EQUILIBRIUM IN A CENTRALIZED CARTEL 2.
A camper awakens to the growl of a hungry bear and sees his friend putting on a pair of running shoes, “You can’t outrun a bear,” scoffs the camper. His.
Basic Oligopoly Models
Oligopoly The challenge of analyzing interdependent strategic decisions.
Game Theory: Inside Oligopoly Pertemuan
Objectives © Pearson Education, 2005 Oligopoly LUBS1940: Topic 7.
David Bryce © Adapted from Baye © 2002 Game Theory: The Competitive Dynamics of Strategy MANEC 387 Economics of Strategy MANEC 387 Economics.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2013 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Chapter 13: Strategic Decision Making in Oligopoly Markets.
CHAPTER 9 Basic Oligopoly Models Copyright © 2014 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written.
© 2008 Pearson Addison Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter Fourteen Game Theory.
APEC 8205: Applied Game Theory Fall 2007
1 Lecture 2: What is game theory?*  Formal analysis of strategic behaviour, that is, relation between inter-dependent agents. The interplay of competition.
Oligopoly Oligopoly is a market dominated by a relatively small number of large firms » Unconcentrated markets have HH < 1,000 Products are either standardized.
UNIT III: COMPETITIVE STRATEGY
Chapter 10 Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly.
Game Theory.
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy
CHAPTER 15 Oligopoly. 2 What you will learn in this chapter: The meaning of oligopoly, and why it occurs Why oligopolists have an incentive to act in.
Introduction to Game Theory and Strategic Interactions.
OLIGOPOLY Chapter 16. The Spectrum of Market Structures.
Perfect competition, with an infinite number of firms, and monopoly, with a single firm, are polar opposites. Monopolistic competition and oligopoly.
ECON 201 Oligopolies & Game Theory 1. 2 An Economic Application of Game Theory: the Kinked-Demand Curve Above the kink, demand is relatively elastic because.
© 2007 Worth Publishers Essentials of Economics Krugman Wells Olney Prepared by: Fernando & Yvonn Quijano.
CHAPTER 15 Oligopoly PowerPoint® Slides by Can Erbil © 2004 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved.
제 10 장 게임이론 Game Theory: Inside Oligopoly
Oligopolies & Game Theory
Chapter 10 Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly © 2009 South-Western/ Cengage Learning.
1 GAME THEORY AND OLIGOPOLY l Principles of Microeconomic Theory, ECO 284 l John Eastwood l CBA 247 l l address:
Chapter 6 Extensive Form Games With Perfect Information (Illustrations)
Noncooperative Collusion The Cournot Oligopoly model was a single-period noncooperative model. In most models of imperfect competition, it is true that.
Monopolistic competition and Oligopoly
Oligopoly and Game Theory ETP Economics 101. Imperfect Competition  Imperfect competition refers to those market structures that fall between perfect.
Topics to be Discussed Gaming and Strategic Decisions
GAME THEORY and its Application Chapter 06. Outlines... Introduction Prisoner`s dilemma Nash equilibrium Oligopoly price fixing Game Collusion for profit.
Econ 545, Spring 2016 Industrial Organization Anticompetitive actions: Cartels and collusion.
Econ 545, Spring 2016 Industrial Organization Dynamic Games.
University of Papua New Guinea Principles of Microeconomics Lecture 13: Oligopoly.
BUS 525: Managerial Economics Game Theory: Inside Oligopoly
Copyright©2004 South-Western 17 Oligopoly. Copyright © 2004 South-Western BETWEEN MONOPOLY AND PERFECT COMPETITION Imperfect competition includes industries.
1 Welcome to EC 209: Managerial Economics- Group A By: Dr. Jacqueline Khorassani Study Guide Week Ten (Sorry this week I am a little late.)
Chapter 12 Game Theory Presented by Nahakpam PhD Student 1Game Theory.
Microeconomics 1000 Lecture 13 Oligopoly.
Markets with Only a Few Sellers
Oligopolies & Game Theory
Game Theory: The Competitive Dynamics of Strategy
Oligopolies & Game Theory
BEC 30325: MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS
Oligopoly and Game Theory
Presentation transcript:

Game Theory: Inside Oligopoly

Introduction Behavior of competitors, or impact of own actions, cannot be ignored in oligopoly Managers maximize profit or market share by outguessing competitors Insight into oligopolistic markets by using GAME THEORY (Von Neumann and Morgenstern in 1950): designed to evaluate situations with conflicting objectives or bargaining processes between at least two parties.

Types of Games Normal Form vs. Extensive Form Simultaneous vs. Sequential (act without knowing (one player moves other player’s strategy) after observing others) One Shot vs. Repeated (infinite and finite with uncertain and certain final period) Zero Sum vs. Non-zero Sum (market share) (profit maximization)

A Normal Form Game Elements of the game: Players Strategies or feasible actions Payoff matrix Planed decision or actions Player 2 12,11 11,12 14,13 Player 1 11,10 10,11 12,12 10,15 10,13 13,14 Results from strategy dependent on the strategies of all the players

Dominant Strategy Regardless of whether Player 2 chooses A, B, or C, Player 1 is better off choosing “a”! (Indiana Jones and the Holy Grail) “a” is Player 1’s Dominant Strategy! Player 2 2’s best strategy c c a 12,11 11,12 14,13 Player 1 11,10 10,11 12,12 10,15 10,13 13,14 1’s best a a a strategy

The Outcome What should player 2 do? 2 has no dominant strategy, but should reason that 1 will play “a”. Therefore 2 should choose “C”. Player 2 12,11 11,12 14,13* 14,13 Player 1 11,10 10,11 12,12 10,15 10,13 13,14 This outcome is called a Nash equilibrium (set of strategies were no player can improve payoffs by unilaterally changing own strategy given other player’s strategy) “a” 1’s best response to “C” and “C” is 2’s best response to “a”.

Best Response Strategy Try to predict the likely action of competitor to identify your best response: Conjecture choice of rival Select your own best response Was conjecture reasonable or Look for dominant strategies Put yourself in your rival’s shoes

Market-Share Game Equilibrium • Two managers want to maximize market share (zero-sum game) • Strategies are pricing decisions • Simultaneous moves • One-shot game Manager 2 Manager 1 Nash Equilibrium

Dominated Strategy Dominance exception rather than rule In absence of dominance it might be possible to simplify the game by eliminating dominated strategy (never played: lowest payoff regardless of other player’s strategy) Steelers trial by 2, have the ball & enough time for 2 plays Payoff matrix in yards gained by offense: no dominant strategy Pass dominant offense without Blitz (dominated defense) Defense Best Defense Run Pass 2 6 14 Offense 8 7* 10 Best Offense Pass Pass Run

Maximin or Secure Strategy In absence of dominant strategy risk averse players may abandon Nash or best response (*) and seek maximin option (^) that maximizes the minimum possible payoff. This is not design to maximize payoff but rather to avoid highly unfavorable outcomes (choose the best of all worst). Firm 1 Firm 2 Best for 1 New 6 None 3 Min for 2 None 3 New 2 Best Min for 2 for 1 New 6 New 3 None 3 None 2 Board of Getty Oil agreed to sell 40% stake to Pennzoil @ $128.5 in Jan 1984. Board of Getty Oil subsequently accepted Texaco’s offer for 100% @ $128. Pennzoil sued Texaco for breach of contract & received $10 bill jury award in 1985. Texaco appealed. Before Supreme Court’s decision, they settled for $3 bill in 1987 .

Examples of Coordination Games Industry standards size of floppy disks size of CDs etc. National standards electric current traffic laws

A Coordination Problem: Three Nash Equilibria! Player 2 Player 1

Key Insights: In some cases one-shot, non-cooperative games result in undesirable outcome for individuals (prisoner’s dilemma) and some times for society (advertisement). Communication can help solve coordination problems. Sequential moves can help solve coordination problems. Time in jail, Nash (*) and Maximin (^) equilibrium in Prisoner’s dilemma. Suspect 2 Best Max for 2 for 1 Confess Confess Do Not Confess Suspect 1 Best for 1 Confess Do Not Max for 2 Confess Confess

One-Shot Advertising Game Equilibrium • Kellogg’s & General Mills want to maximize profits • Strategies consist of advertising campaigns • Simultaneous moves • One-shot interaction • Repeated interaction General Mills Kellogg’s Nash Equilibrium

Repeating the game 2 times will not improve outcome In the last period the game is a one-shot game, so equilibrium entails High Advertising. Period 1 is “really” the last period, since everyone knows what will happen in period 2. Equilibrium entails High Advertising by each firm in both periods. The same holds true if we repeat the game any known, finite number of times. General Mills * Kellogg’s Nash Equilibrium

Can collusion work if firms play the game each year, forever? Consider the “trigger strategy” by each firm: “Don’t advertise, provided the rival has not advertised in the past. If the rival ever advertises, “punish” it by engaging in a high level of advertising forever after.” Each firm agrees to “cooperate” so long as the rival hasn’t “cheated”, which triggers punishment in all future periods. “Tit-for-tat strategy” of copying opponents move from the previous period dominates “trigger strategy” for: Simple to understand Never invites nor rewards cheating Forgiving: allows cheater to restore cooperation by reversing actions

Suppose General Mills adopts this trigger strategy. Kellogg’s profits? Cooperate = 12 +12/(1+i) + 12/(1+i)2 + 12/(1+i)3 + … = 12 + 12/i Value of a perpetuity of $12 paid at the end of every year Cheat = 20 +2/(1+i) + 2/(1+i)2 + 2/(1+i)3 + … = 20 + 2/i General Mills Kellogg’s

Kellogg’s Gain to Cheating: Cheat - Cooperate = 20 + 2/i - (12 + 12/i) = 8 - 10/i Suppose i = .05 Cheat - Cooperate = 8 - 10/.05 = 8 - 200 = -192 It doesn’t pay to deviate. Collusion is a Nash equilibrium in the infinitely repeated game! General Mills Kellogg’s

Benefits & Costs of Cheating Cheat - Cooperate = 8 - 10/i 8 = Immediate Benefit (20 - 12 today) 10/i = PV of Future Cost (12 - 2 forever after) If Immediate Benefit > PV of Future Cost Pays to “cheat”. If Immediate Benefit  PV of Future Cost Doesn’t pay to “cheat”. General Mills Kellogg’s

Key Insight Collusion can be sustained as a Nash equilibrium when game lasts infinitely many periods or finitely many periods with uncertain “end”. Doing so requires: Ability to monitor actions of rivals Ability (and reputation for) punishing defectors Low interest rate High probability of future interaction

Real World Examples of Collusion: Garbage Collection Industry Homogeneous products Known identity of customers Bertrand oligopoly Known identity of competitors Firm 2 One-Shot Bertrand (Nash) Equilibrium Firm 1 Firm 2 Repeated Game Equilibrium Firm 1

Real World Examples of Collusion: OPEC Cartel founded in 1960 by Iran, Iraq, Kuwait, Saudis and Venezuela: “to co-ordinate and unify petroleum policies among Members in order to secure fair and stable prices” Absent collusion: PCompetition < PCournot (OPEC) < PMonopoly Venezuela One-Shot Cournot (Nash) Equilibrium Saudi Arabia Venezuela Repeated Game Equilibrium Assuming a Low Interest Rate Saudi Arabia

OPEC’s Demise Low Interest Rates High Interest Rates

Simultaneous-Move Bargaining Management and a union are negotiating a wage increase. Strategies are wage offers & wage demands. Simultaneous, one-shot move at making a deal. Successful negotiations lead to $600 million in surplus (to be split among the parties), failure results in a $100 million loss to the firm and a $3 million loss to the union. Experiments suggests that, in the absence of any “history,” real players typically coordinate on the “fair outcome” When there is a “bargaining history,” other outcomes may prevail Union Three Nash Equilibriums in Normal Form Management

Single Offer Bargaining Now suppose the game is sequential in nature, and management gets to make the union a “take-it-or-leave-it” offer. Analysis Tool: Write the game in extensive form Summarize the players Their potential actions Their information at each decision point The sequence of moves and Each player’s payoff

To get The Game in Extensive Form Step 1: Management’s Move Step 2: Add the Union’s Move Step 3: Add the Payoffs Firm 10 5 1 Union Accept Reject 100, 500 -100, -3 300, 300 500, 100

Step 4: Identify Nash Equilibriums Outcomes such that neither player has an incentive to change its strategy, given the strategy of the other Firm 10 5 1 Union Accept Reject 100, 500 -100, -3 300, 300 500, 100

Step 5: Find the Subgame Perfect Nash Equilibriums Outcomes where no player has an incentive to change its strategy, given the strategy of the rival, that are based on “credible actions”: not the result of “empty threats” (not in its “best self interest”). Firm 10 5 1 Union Accept Reject 100, 500 -100, -3 300, 300 500, 100

Re-Cap In take-it-or-leave-it bargaining, there is a first-mover advantage. Management can gain by making a take-it or leave-it offer to the union. But... Management should be careful, however; real world evidence suggests that people sometimes reject offers on the the basis of “principle” instead of cash considerations.

Pricing to Prevent Entry: An Application of Game Theory Two firms: an incumbent and potential entrant. Identify Nash and then Subgame Perfect Equilibria. Entrant Out Enter Incumbent Hard Soft -1, 1 5, 5 0, 10 * Establishing a reputation for being unkind to entrants can enhance long-term profits. It is costly to do so in the short-term, so much so that it isn’t optimal to do so in a one-shot game.

The Value of a Bad Reputation: Price Retaliation In early 1970s General Foods’ Maxwell House dominated the non-instant coffee market in the Eastern USA, while Proctor & Gamble’s Folgers dominate Western USA. In 1971 P&G started advertising & distributing Folgers in Cleveland and Pittsburgh. GF’s immediately increased advertisement & lowered prices (sometimes below cost) in these regions & midwestern cities (Kansas City) where both marketed. GF’s profit dropped from 30% in 1970 to –30% in 1974. When P&G reduced its promotional activities, GF’s price increased and profits were restored.

Limit Pricing Strategy where an incumbent prices below the monopoly price in order to keep potential entrants out of the market. Goal is to lessen competition by eliminating potential competitors’ incentives to enter the market. Incumbent produces QL instead of monopoly output QM. Resulting price, PL, is lower than monopoly price PM. Residual demand curve is the market demand DM minus QL. Entry is not profitable because entrant’s residual demand lies below AC Optimal limit pricing results in a residual demand such that, if the entrant entered and produced Q units, its profits would be zero. Quantity $ Q M P AC Entrant's residual demand curve D P = AC L (DM – QL)