Rational Shapes of the Volatility Surface

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
© 2002 South-Western Publishing 1 Chapter 6 The Black-Scholes Option Pricing Model.
Advertisements

Chapter 12: Basic option theory
1/19 Motivation Framework Data Regressions Portfolio Sorts Conclusion Option Returns and Individual Stock Volatility Jie Cao, Chinese University of Hong.
D. M. ChanceAn Introduction to Derivatives and Risk Management, 6th ed.Ch. 7: 1 Chapter 7: Advanced Option Strategies “It takes two things to make a good.
A State Contingent Claim Approach To Asset Valuation Kate Barraclough.
Valuation of Financial Options Ahmad Alanani Canadian Undergraduate Mathematics Conference 2005.
I.Generalities. Bruno Dupire 2 Market Skews Dominating fact since 1987 crash: strong negative skew on Equity Markets Not a general phenomenon Gold: FX:
1 Using VIX Futures as Option Market-Makers’ Short Hedge 10 December 2010 Yueh-Neng Lin, Anchor Y. Lin National Chung Hsing University
Chapter 21 Value at Risk Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 8th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2012.
Options Week 7. What is a derivative asset? Any asset that “derives” its value from another underlying asset is called a derivative asset. The underlying.
Corporate Banking and Investment Mathematical issues with volatility modelling Marek Musiela BNP Paribas 25th May 2005.
Stochastic Volatility Modelling Bruno Dupire Nice 14/02/03.
Chapter 19 Volatility Smiles
Volatility Smiles Chapter 18 Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 7th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull
MGT 821/ECON 873 Volatility Smiles & Extension of Models
Pricing Derivative Financial Products: Linear Programming (LP) Formulation Donald C. Williams Doctoral Candidate Department of Computational and Applied.
1 16-Option Valuation. 2 Pricing Options Simple example of no arbitrage pricing: Stock with known price: S 0 =$3 Consider a derivative contract on S:
© 2004 South-Western Publishing 1 Chapter 6 The Black-Scholes Option Pricing Model.
© 2002 South-Western Publishing 1 Chapter 6 The Black-Scholes Option Pricing Model.
FIN 685: Risk Management Topic 3: Non-Linear Hedging Larry Schrenk, Instructor.
How Traders Manage Their Exposures
Choosing an Investment Portfolio
Chrif YOUSSFI Global Equity Linked Products
Volatility and Hedging Errors
Lecture 11 Volatility expansion Bruno Dupire Bloomberg LP.
Options and risk measurement. Definition of a call option  A call option is the right but not the obligation to buy 100 shares of the stock at a stated.
5.2Risk-Neutral Measure Part 2 報告者:陳政岳 Stock Under the Risk-Neutral Measure is a Brownian motion on a probability space, and is a filtration for.
Chapter 5: Option Pricing Models: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model
5.1 Option pricing: pre-analytics Lecture Notation c : European call option price p :European put option price S 0 :Stock price today X :Strike.
Chapter 5: Option Pricing Models: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model
Quantitative Finance Society Introduction to Options.
Options and Bubble Written by Steven L. Heston Mark Loewenstein Gregory A. Willard Present by Feifei Yao.
Pricing Cont’d & Beginning Greeks. Assumptions of the Black- Scholes Model  European exercise style  Markets are efficient  No transaction costs 
Chance/BrooksAn Introduction to Derivatives and Risk Management, 9th ed.Ch. 7: 1 Chapter 7: Advanced Option Strategies Read every book by traders to study.
Chapter 7: Advanced Option Strategies
JUMP DIFFUSION MODELS Karina Mignone Option Pricing under Jump Diffusion.
FEC FINANCIAL ENGINEERING CLUB. MORE ON OPTIONS AGENDA  Put-Call Parity  Combination of options.
Quantitative Finance Society Options, explained. State of the Markets What’s been going on?
Martingales Charles S. Tapiero. Martingales origins Its origin lies in the history of games of chance …. Girolamo Cardano proposed an elementary theory.
Option Pricing Models I. Binomial Model II. Black-Scholes Model (Non-dividend paying European Option) A. Black-Scholes Model is the Limit of the Binomial.
BLACK-SCHOLES OPTION PRICING MODEL Chapters 7 and 8.
Are Options Mispriced? Greg Orosi. Outline Option Calibration: two methods Consistency Problem Two Empirical Observations Results.
Financial Risk Management of Insurance Enterprises Valuing Interest Rate Options and Swaps.
Advanced Risk Management I Lecture 6 Non-linear portfolios.
Introduction to Financial Engineering
THE GREEKS  Options prices are always based on market supply and demand.  However predictive models have been developed to measure effect on changes.
Financial Risk Management of Insurance Enterprises Valuing Interest Rate Options.
Volatility Smiles. What is a Volatility Smile? It is the relationship between implied volatility and strike price for options with a certain maturity.
Chapter 13 Market-Making and Delta-Hedging.
1 Options Option Basics Option strategies Put-call parity Binomial option pricing Black-Scholes Model.
HJM Models.
Survey of Local Volatility Models Lunch at the lab Greg Orosi University of Calgary November 1, 2006.
Option Pricing Dr. J.D. Han. 2 *Currency Option in Practice USD call/JP Yen put “Face values in dollars = $10,000,000 Option call/put = USD call or JPY.
FEC FINANCIAL ENGINEERING CLUB. AN INTRO TO OPTIONS.
Option Pricing Models: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model aka Black – Scholes Option Pricing Model (BSOPM)
Option Valuation.
Monte-Carlo Simulations Seminar Project. Task  To Build an application in Excel/VBA to solve option prices.  Use a stochastic volatility in the model.
Chapter 23 Volatility. Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved Introduction Implied volatility Volatility estimation Volatility.
Class Business Upcoming Groupwork Course Evaluations.
1 1 Ch20&21 – MBA 566 Options Option Basics Option strategies Put-call parity Binomial option pricing Black-Scholes Model.
Volatility Smiles and Option Pricing Models YONSEI UNIVERSITY YONSEI UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF BUSINESS In Joon Kim.
Lecture 8: Finance: GBM model for share prices, futures and options, hedging, and the Black-Scholes equation Outline: GBM as a model of share prices futures.
OPTIONS PRICING AND HEDGING WITH GARCH.THE PRICING KERNEL.HULL AND WHITE.THE PLUG-IN ESTIMATOR AND GARCH GAMMA.ENGLE-MUSTAFA – IMPLIED GARCH.DUAN AND EXTENSIONS.ENGLE.
Chapter 19 Volatility Smiles Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 8th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull
Comments from Instructor: A detailed yet analytical paper, which puts class materials into good application, and takes one step further, if simple, to.
Financial Risk Management of Insurance Enterprises
SDE & Statistics MiniCourse Topics List for the Exam
Jainendra Shandilya, CFA, CAIA
Generalities.
Presentation transcript:

Rational Shapes of the Volatility Surface Jim Gatheral Global Equity-Linked Products Merrill Lynch

References Bakshi, G. , Cao C., Chen Z., “Empirical Performance of Alternative Option Pricing Models” Journal of Finance, 52, 2003-2049. J. Gatheral, Courant Institute of Mathematical Sciences Lecture Notes, http://www.math.nyu.edu/fellows_fin_math/gatheral/. Hardy M. Hodges. “Arbitrage Bounds on the Implied Volatility Strike and Term Structures of European-Style Options.” The Journal of Derivatives, Summer 1996. Roger Lee, “Local volatilities in Stochastic Volatility Models”, Working Paper, Stanford University, 1999. R. Merton, “Option Pricing When Underlying Stock Returns are Discontinuous,” Journal of Financial Economics, 3, January-February 1976. Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

Goals Derive arbitrage bounds on the slope and curvature of volatility skews. Investigate the strike and time behavior of these bounds. Specialize to stochastic volatility and jumps. Draw implications for parameterization of the volatility surface. Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

Slope Constraints No arbitrage implies that call spreads and put spreads must be non-negative. i.e. In fact, we can tighten this to Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

In conventional notation, we get Translate these equations into conditions on the implied total volatility as a function of . In conventional notation, we get Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

Assuming we can plot these bounds on the slope as functions of . Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

Note that we have plotted bounds on the slope of total implied volatility as a function of y. This means that the bounds on the slope of BS implied volatility get tighter as time to expiration increases by . Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

Convexity Constraints No arbitrage implies that call and puts must have positive convexity. i.e. Translating these into our variables gives Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

We get a complicated expression which is nevertheless easy to evaluate for any particular function . This expression is equivalent to demanding that butterflies have non-negative value. Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

Again, assuming and we can plot this lower bound on the convexity as a function of . Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

Implication for Variance Skew Putting together the vertical spread and convexity conditions, it may be shown that implied variance may not grow faster than linearly with the log-strike. Formally, Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

Local Volatility Local volatility is given by Local variances are non-negative iff arbitrage constraints are satisfied. Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

Time Behavior of the Skew Since in practice, we are interested in the lower bound on the slope for most stocks, let’s investigate the time behavior of this lower bound. Recall that the lower bound on the slope can be expressed as Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

Reinstating explicit dependence on T, we get For small times, so Reinstating explicit dependence on T, we get That is, for small T. Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

Then, the lower bound on the slope Also, Then, the lower bound on the slope Making the time-dependence of explicit, Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

because for any choice of positive constants a, b In particular, the time dependence of the at-the-money skew cannot be because for any choice of positive constants a, b Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

Assuming , we can plot the variance slope lower bound as a function of time. Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

A Practical Example of Arbitrage We suppose that the ATMF 1 year volatility and skew are 25% and 11% per 10% respectively. Suppose that we extrapolate the vol skew using a rule. Now, buy 99 puts struck at 101 and sell 101 puts struck at 99. What is the value of this portfolio as a function of time to expiration? Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

Arbitrage! Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

With more reasonable parameters, it takes a long time to generate an arbitrage though…. 50 Years! No arbitrage! Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

So Far…. We have derived arbitrage constraints on the slope and convexity of the volatility skew. We have demonstrated that the rule for extrapolating the skew is inconsistent with no arbitrage. Time dependence must be at most for large T Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

Stochastic Volatility Consider the following special case of the Heston model: In this model, it can be shown that Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

For a general stochastic volatility theory of the form: with we claim that (very roughly) Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

Then, for very short expirations, we get - a result originally derived by Roger Lee and for very long expirations, we get Both of these results are consistent with the arbitrage bounds. Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

Doesn’t This Contradict ? Market practitioners’ rule of thumb is that the skew decays as . Using (from Bakshi, Cao and Chen), we get the following graph for the relative size of the at-the-money variance skew: Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

ATM Skew as a Function of Stochastic Vol. ( ) Actual SPX skew (5/31/00) Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

Heston Implied Variance y=ln(K/F) Parameters: from Bakshi, Cao and Chen. Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

A Simple Regime Switching Model To get intuition for the impact of volatility convexity, we suppose that realised volatility over the life of a one year option can take one of two values each with probability 1/2. The average of these volatilities is 20%. The price of an option is just the average option price over the two scenarios. We graph the implied volatilities of the resulting option prices. Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

High Vol: 21%; Low Vol: 19% Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

High Vol: 39%; Low Vol: 1% Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

Intuition As , implied volatility tends to the highest volatility. If volatility is unbounded, implied volatility must also be unbounded. From a trader’s perspective, the more out-of-the-money (OTM) an option is, the more vol convexity it has. Provided volatility is unbounded, more OTM options must command higher implied volatility. Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

Asymmetric Variance Gamma Implied Variance y=ln(K/F) Parameters: Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

Jump Diffusion Consider the simplest form of Merton’s jump-diffusion model with a constant probability of a jump to ruin. Call options are valued in this model using the Black-Scholes formula with a shifted forward price. We graph 1 year implied variance as a function of log-strike with : Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

Jump-to-Ruin Model Parameters: Implied Variance y=ln(K/F) Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

So, even in jump-diffusion, is linear in as . In fact, we can show that for many economically reasonable stochastic-volatility-plus-jump models, implied BS variance must be asymptotically linear in the log-strike as . This means that it does not make sense to plot implied BS variance against delta. As an example, consider the following graph of vs. d in the Heston model: Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

Variance vs d in the Heston Model Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000

Implications for Parameterization of the Volatility Surface Implied BS variance must be parameterized in terms of the log-strike (vs delta doesn’t work). is asymptotically linear in as decays as as tends to a constant as Risk 2000, Tuesday 13 June 2000