Chapter 10: The Social Discount Rate, Cost of Public Funds, and the Value of Information © Harry Campbell & Richard Brown School of Economics The University.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
MACROECONOMICS What is the purpose of macroeconomics? to explain how the economy as a whole works to understand why macro variables behave in the way they.
Advertisements

Chapter 8 A roadmap ahead: So far we have studied how aggregate economic performance is defined and measured. In the next few chapters we will study the.
Investment and Saving Decisions
Consumer and Producer Surplus in Benefit-Cost Analysis (Campbell & Brown Chapter 7) Harry Campbell & Richard Brown School of Economics UQ, St. Lucia 2003.
© Harry Campbell & Richard Brown School of Economics The University of Queensland BENEFIT-COST ANALYSIS Financial and Economic Appraisal using Spreadsheets.
1 Finance: Net Present Value 8.1 ECON 201 Summer 2009.
A closed economy, market-clearing model
Demand for goods & services
Copyright © 2006 Pearson Education Canada Fiscal Policy 24 CHAPTER.
22 Aggregate Supply and Aggregate Demand
1 Capital, Interest, and Corporate Finance Chapter 13 © 2006 Thomson/South-Western.
The Influence of Monetary and Fiscal Policy on Aggregate Demand
FNCE 3020 Financial Markets and Institutions Fall Semester 2005 Lecture 3 The Behavior of Interest Rates.
Ch. 17: Demand and Supply in Factor Markets Objectives – The firm’s choice of the quantities of labor and capital to employ. – People’s choices of the.
1 Aggregate Expenditure Components Chapter 24 © 2006 Thomson/South-Western.
8 CAPITAL, INVESTMENT, AND SAVING CHAPTER.
Chapter 11: Cost-Benefit Analysis Econ 330: Public Finance Dr
Investment, the Capital Market, and the Wealth of Nations
Basic Tools of Finance Finance is the field that studies how people make decisions regarding the allocation of resources over time and the handling of.
Micro and Macro- the difference?
Ch. 18: Demand and Supply in Factor Markets
Source: Mankiw (2000) Macroeconomics, Chapter 3 p Determinants of Demand for Goods and Services Examine: how the output from production is used.
Ch. 7. At Full Employment: The Classical Model
Chapter 30: The Labor Market Copyright © 2013 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin 13e.
Chapter 8 The Classical Long-Run Model Part 1 CHAPTER 1.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Chapter 15: Saving, Capital Formation, and Financial Markets.
© Harry Campbell & Richard Brown School of Economics The University of Queensland BENEFIT-COST ANALYSIS Financial and Economic Appraisal using Spreadsheets.
P.V. VISWANATH FOR A FIRST COURSE IN FINANCE 1. 2 NPV and IRR  How do we decide to invest in a project or not? Using the Annuity Formula  Valuing Mortgages.
 How does demand and supply change when things happen in the economy, like:  Inflation  Unemployment  Levels of spending  Real output  We look at.
Investment CHAPTER 17.
Labour and Capital Market
Copyright © 2004 South-Western 20 The Influence of Monetary and Fiscal Policy on Aggregate Demand.
ECON 6012 Cost Benefit Analysis Memorial University of Newfoundland
PPA 723: Managerial Economics Lecture 9: Applications of Consumer Choice.
Chapter 8: Valuing Traded and Non-traded Commodities in Benefit-Cost Analysis © Harry Campbell & Richard Brown School of Economics The University of Queensland.
ECN 202: Principles of Macroeconomics Nusrat Jahan Lecture-5 Saving, Investment & Financial System.
1 Ch. 7. At Full Employment: The Classical Model The relationship between the quantity of labor employed and real GDP What determines the full-employment.
Interest ratesslide 1 INTEREST RATE DETERMINATION The rate of interest is the price of money to borrow and lend. Rates of interest are expressed as decimals.
Business Funding & Financial Awareness Time Value of Money – The Role of Interest Rates in Decision Taking J R Davies May 2011.
Pro Forma Income Statement Projected or “future” financial statements. The idea is to write down a sequence of financial statements that represent expectations.
Slide 0 CHAPTER 3 National Income Outline of model A closed economy, market-clearing model Supply side  factor markets (supply, demand, price)  determination.
Inflation Lesson Two A Reflection – Inflation Lesson One Understand Savings and Investment, Interest Rates and Economic Activity, Fiscal Policy, and Net.
CHAPTER 3 National Income slide 0 In this chapter you will learn:  what determines the economy’s total output/income  how the prices of the factors of.
© Harry Campbell & Richard Brown School of Economics The University of Queensland BENEFIT-COST ANALYSIS Financial and Economic Appraisal using Spreadsheets.
Chapter 10 Choices Involving Time Copyright © 2014 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written.
Review of the previous lecture 1. Total output is determined by  how much capital and labor the economy has  the level of technology 2. Competitive firms.
Financial Markets and Institutions PowerPoint Slides for: By Jeff Madura Prepared by David R. Durst The University of Akron.
Economics 202 Principles Of Macroeconomics Lecture 10 Investment, Savings and the Real Interest Rate The role of the Government Savings and Investment.
Determination of Interest Rates
Chapter 6: Perfectly Competitive Supply
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 9 A Real Intertemporal Model with Investment.
1 The Classical Long-Run Model. 2 Classical Model A macroeconomic model that explains the long- run behavior of the economy Classical model was developed.
© 2011 Pearson Education Aggregate Supply and Aggregate Demand 13 When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to 1 Define and.
Macroeconomics Econ 2301 Dr. Frank Jacobson Coach Stuckey Chapter 11.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western. The Influence of Monetary and Fiscal Policy on Aggregate Demand Many factors influence aggregate demand besides monetary.
Copyright © 2004 South-Western 34 The Influence of Monetary and Fiscal Policy on Aggregate Demand.
MACROECONOMICS © 2013 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich N. Gregory Mankiw National Income: Where It Comes From.
© 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved 9-1 Chapter Outline The FE Line: Equilibrium in the Labor Market The IS Curve: Equilibrium in the Goods.
BENEFIT-COST ANALYSIS Financial and Economic Appraisal using Spreadsheets Ch. 3: Decision Rules © Harry Campbell & Richard Brown School of Economics The.
Measuring and Increasing Profit. Unit 1 Reminder – What is Profit? Profit is the reward or return for taking risks & making investments.
CHAPTER 14 (Part 2) Money, Interest Rates, and the Exchange Rate.
7 AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY CHAPTER.
Copyright © 2004 South-Western 34 The Influence of Monetary and Fiscal Policy on Aggregate Demand.
Lecture outline Crowding out effect Closed and open economies Ricardian equivalence revisited Debt burden and dead weight loss.
Prepared by Apostolos Serletis
The Classical Long-Run Model
Lecture 17 Production function and labour demand
AS-AD curves: how natural is the natural rate of unemployment?
Presentation transcript:

Chapter 10: The Social Discount Rate, Cost of Public Funds, and the Value of Information © Harry Campbell & Richard Brown School of Economics The University of Queensland BENEFIT-COST ANALYSIS BENEFIT-COST ANALYSIS Financial and Economic Appraisal using Spreadsheets

Three reasons why NPV>0 may not be the appropriate rule to identify projects which are efficient from a social viewpoint: the social discount rate may be lower than the market rate of interest; the marginal cost of public funds may exceed unity (ie. $1 of public funds costs more than $1); undertaking an irreversible investment involves a loss of option value.

The Social Discount Rate Why does the market discount future benefits and costs? impatience: people value utility today more highly than utility tomorrow. In making choices, future utility is discounted in comparison with utility in the present; diminishing marginal utility of consumption: people expect to be wealthier in the future. An extra dollar in the future will add less to utility than an extra dollar today.

The observed market rate of interest is the sum of the utility discount factor (reflecting impatience) and the utility growth factor (reflecting diminishing marginal utility of consumption). Example: economic growth rate: 2% elasticity of marginal utility of income: 1.5 utility growth factor: 1.5 x 2% = 3% utility discount factor: 1% real market rate of interest: 3% + 1% = 4%

Why do people argue that a social discount rate, lower than the market rate of interest, should be used to discount public projects? We should not be discounting the utility of future generations who are not able to participate in markets which determine levels of current investment, and, hence, future utility levels. It is argued that there is, in effect, a ‘missing market’ and we need to use non-market methods to determine the appropriate price (in this case an inter-temporal price in the form of a discount factor).

What is the appropriate discount rate for public projects? It is reasonable to employ a utility growth factor in discounting public projects: if future generations are going to be wealthier than us, we should take this into account in sacrificing present consumption to make provision for the future. It is not reasonable to employ a utility discount factor in discounting public projects: we should not treat the utility of future generations as any less important than that of the present generation.

Developing our simple example: instead of using the real market rate of interest of 4% as the discount rate for public projects, we would adjust it downwards by the amount of the utility discount factor (1%) to get a social discount rate equal to the utility growth factor (3%). Using a social discount rate would tend to make investment projects more attractive, but the 1% difference in discount rate would be crucial in only a few cases.

The Marginal Cost of Public Funds Raising public funds to undertake investment projects involves three types of costs: collection costs: costs of running the tax office; compliance costs: costs incurred by taxpayers; deadweight loss: costs of misallocation of resources as people respond to prices distorted by taxes.

Compliance and collection costs are largely fixed costs: they do not change when the amount of tax collected changes by a small amount. Since any given project will involve relatively small changes in the flow of public funds, compliance and collection costs can be ignored in social benefit-cost analysis. The amount of deadweight loss tends to rise (fall) as the amount of public funds raised rises (falls). A project which requires additional public funds imposes an additional deadweight loss on the economy; and a project which contributes to public funds reduces the amount of deadweight loss.

When the additional deadweight loss is taken into account, the NPV rule becomes: NPV = B - C - D > 0 where: B is the PV of project benefits C is the PV of project costs D is the additional deadweight loss The NPV rule could also be written as: B - C[(C+D)/C] >0, or B/C > (C+D)/C where (C+D)/C is the marginal cost of public funds.

There are three main ways of raising additional public funds: borrowing from the public i.e. selling government bonds in the market; borrowing from the central bank i.e. printing money; raising tax rates. If the required quantity of public funds is raised at minimum cost, the marginal cost of public funds from each source will be the same.

The deadweight loss resulting from selling bonds to the public. Suppose $100 worth of government bonds is sold on the market, and that $50 is diverted from private consumption spending, and $50 from private investment spending. The tax rate on the returns to private investment is around 1/3. Since the after-corporation tax rate of return on private investment must equal the government bond rate r, the before-tax rate of return on private investment must be r* = 1.5r. (Why? Because r*(1 - 1/3) = r )

Now we can work out the cost to the economy of displacing $50 worth of private consumption and $50 worth of private investment: the loss of $50 worth of private consumption costs $50 the $50 worth of private investment would have yielded an annual before-tax return of $50r*. The present value of this return (at the market rate of interest) is $50(r*/r) = $50*1.5 = $75. The cost to the economy of raising $100 of public funds by borrowing from the public is $125. The deadweight loss is $25 and the marginal cost of public funds is $1.25 per dollar i.e

The deadweight loss resulting from collecting additional tax revenues. There is a wide range of taxes in our economy: personal and business income taxes goods and services tax excise duties on petrol, tobacco, alcohol etc. It can be argued that eventually all these taxes are borne by households. We can consolidate all these taxes into a single tax which can be regarded as a tax on the labour supply of households.

When the government wishes to raise additional tax revenue, it has a wide range of choice as to which tax rates to increase. However, we can argue that the effect is simply to increase the consolidated rate of tax on labour supply by households. Assuming that the aggregate labour supply curve of households is upward sloping, an increase in the rate of tax will cause a reduction in labour supply.

Figure 10.1 Taxation and Labour Supply $ D C S GF BA E W W0W0 W1W1 L0L0 L1L1 Quantity of Labour (Hours)

In Figure 10.1: the after-tax wage falls from W 0 to W 1 as a result of the increase in tax rate; the quantity of labour supplied falls from L 0 to L 1 because of the upward sloping supply curve. The cost to households of the tax increase is the loss of producer surplus: ABDE + BCD The extra tax revenue to government is measured by: ABDE - FGCB The cost per dollar of additional revenue is the ratio of the cost to households to the extra tax revenue.

Summary: Cost to the economy of additional public funds: Area ABDE + BCD; Quantity of additional public funds: Area ABDE - FGCB Cost per additional dollar of public funds: MC =ABDE + BCD ABDE - FGCB MC = (ABDE - FGCB) + (BCD + FGCB) (ABDE - FGCB) = 1 + FGCD (ABDE - FGCB)

How to interpret the formula for the marginal cost of public funds: MC = 1 + FGCD (ABDE - FGCB) The cost of an extra dollar of public funds is: $1 plus the additional deadweight loss per dollar of extra funds. Why does area FGCD represent an additional deadweight loss?

The effect of the tax rate increase is to divert a quantity of labour (L 0 - L 1 ) from work to leisure. In work that quantity of labour would have produced output with a value measured by area FGL 0 L 1. The value of the corresponding extra leisure time is measured by area DCL 0 L 1. The difference between these two measures is a loss to the economy, termed a deadweight loss. The marginal cost of public funds is: 1 + additional deadweight loss additional quantity of funds

Two complications: 1.When household labour supply falls, household earned income falls. When earned income falls, the household’s eligibility for social security payments rises. Some of the extra tax revenue raised will have to be used to fund increased social security payments rather than the public project the extra tax revenues are intended to fund. 2. Some public projects will, by their nature, cause a shift of the labour supply curve, and this may tend to increase or decrease the effects of the tax rate increase on the quantity of labour supplied and the quantity of leisure demanded.

Estimates of the marginal cost of public funds: In Australia and other OECD countries most estimates of the marginal cost of public funds are in the range. In other words, there is an additional deadweight loss of around 25 cents per dollar of extra tax revenue raised. Implications of the marginal cost of public funds for social benefit- cost analysis: All flows of public funds resulting from a project should be shadow-priced (at around 1.25 in Australia). This increases the cost of outflows and increases the benefits of inflows of funds as a result of a project.

The Value of Information Suppose that you have undertaken a social benefit-cost analysis and find that NPV>0. Is there any reason (other than a budget constraint) why you would recommend that the project should not go ahead immediately? There might be uncertainty about the values of some of the variables used to calculate the NPV e.g. future prices. Delaying the project might resolve these uncertainties.

To investigate the value of delaying the project we compare the NPV (at time 0) of undertaking the project immediately (at time 0) with the NPV (at time 0) of delaying the start of the project until time 1. In the example considered, it is assumed that, while we know the present price of output (at time 0), we don’t know whether the price of the project output is going to be high or low from time period 1 onwards. If we delay the project until time 1 we will get this information prior to deciding on whether to undertake the project.

In the example: K is the project cost R 0 is net benefit in year 0 (known with certainty) R H is net benefit from year 1 onwards if the high price prevails R L is net benefit from year 1 onwards if the low price prevails q is the probability of the high price prevailing (1-q) is the probability of the low price prevailing r is the rate of interest

The expected value of information is: The expected project NPV (at time 0) if we delay the project for 1 year minus the expected project NPV (at time 0) if we undertake the project at time 0. Figure 10.2 illustrates the expected NPVs of the two options. R H /r – K/(1+r) (1-q) q 0 [since {R I /r) – K/(1+r)}<0] R 0 +(qR H /r + (1-q)R I /r) - K Inves t Wait Figure 10.2 The benefit and cost of delaying an investment

When we subtract the expected NPV of undertaking the project immediately from the expected NPV if the project is delayed for one year, we get an estimate of the value of information. The value of information rises as: the initial capital cost, K, rises; the return in the low price environment, R L, falls; the probability of a low price, (1-q), rises; the return in the current period, R 0, falls; the interest rate falls. The ‘bad news principle’ - the level of the return in the high price environment, R H, does not affect the value of information.

The NPV Rule If there is no additional information to be obtained by delaying the project, the NPV rule is to undertake the project immediately if: NPV = E(R) + R 0 - K > 0, r where E(R) = q R H + (1-q) R L. If additional information can be obtained by delay, the NPV rule is to undertake the project immediately only if: E(R) + R 0 - K > b, where b > 0. r

The NPV rule when additional information can be obtained says that the project should be undertaken only when the option of delay is worthless. The condition which makes the option of delay (the value of waiting) worthless is the revised NPV rule: NPV = E(R) + R 0 - K > b, r where b = q{R H - K } r (1+r)