M. Bayes D. Kovenock C. de Vries The Economic Journal 115, 583-601(2005)

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
(Single-item) auctions Vincent Conitzer v() = $5 v() = $3.
Advertisements

Auction Theory Class 5 – single-parameter implementation and risk aversion 1.
Nash Equilibrium: Illustrations
Class 4 – Some applications of revenue equivalence
Approximating optimal combinatorial auctions for complements using restricted welfare maximization Pingzhong Tang and Tuomas Sandholm Computer Science.
EC941 - Game Theory Prof. Francesco Squintani Lecture 4 1.
CPS Bayesian games and their use in auctions Vincent Conitzer
ECON 100 Tutorial: Week 9 office: LUMS C85.
Bank Competition and Financial Stability: A General Equilibrium Expositi on Gianni De Nicolò International Monetary Fund and CESifo Marcella Lucchetta.
Auctions. Strategic Situation You are bidding for an object in an auction. The object has a value to you of $20. How much should you bid? Depends on auction.
An Approximate Truthful Mechanism for Combinatorial Auctions An Internet Mathematics paper by Aaron Archer, Christos Papadimitriou, Kunal Talwar and Éva.
Michael R. Baye, Managerial Economics and Business Strategy, 3e. ©The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., 1999 Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter.
Federal Communications Commission NSMA Spectrum Management Conference May 20, 2008 Market Based Forces and the Radio Spectrum By Mark Bykowsky, Kenneth.
The Economics of Information
Economics of the Legal Process. Car Accident  I hit you with my car and cause $10,000 in damages  We both believe that there’s an 80% chance I’ll be.
Auction with aftermarket for budget constrained bidders Departament d’Economia i d’Història Econòmica - IDEA Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Gustavo.
MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION, OLIGOPOLY, & GAME THEORY
Imperfect commitment Santiago Truffa. Agenda 1.“Authority and communication in Organizations” Wouter Dessein, RES “Contracting for information.
1 Chapter 12 Value of Information. 2 Chapter 12, Value of information Learning Objectives: Probability and Perfect Information The Expected Value of Information.
Contests with Reimbursements Alexander Matros and Daniel Armanios University of Pittsburgh.
Bundling Equilibrium in Combinatorial Auctions Written by: Presented by: Ron Holzman Rica Gonen Noa Kfir-Dahav Dov Monderer Moshe Tennenholtz.
Slide 1 of 13 So... What’s Game Theory? Game theory refers to a branch of applied math that deals with the strategic interactions between various ‘agents’,
A camper awakens to the growl of a hungry bear and sees his friend putting on a pair of running shoes, “You can’t outrun a bear,” scoffs the camper. His.
Mechanism Design and the VCG mechanism The concept of a “mechanism”. A general (abstract) solution for welfare maximization: the VCG mechanism. –This is.
Endogenous Coalition Formation in Contests Santiago Sánchez-Pagés Review of Economic Design 2007.
Lecture 4 on Individual Optimization Risk Aversion
1 “ Pumpkin pies and public goods: The raffle fundraising strategy ” BRIAN DUNCAN (2002) Sandra Orozco Contest and Tournaments November, 2007.
Chapter 14 – Efficient and Equitable Taxation
Incomplete Contracts Renegotiation, Communications and Theory December 10, 2007.
Communication and Cooperation General Game PlayingLecture 8 Michael Genesereth / Nat Love Spring 2006.
Adverse Selection & Renegotiation in Procurement (The Review of Economic Studies 1990) work of: Jean-Jacques Laffont & Jean Tirole presented by: Deepak.
Anonymizing Web Services Through a Club Mechanism With Economic Incentives Mamata Jenamani Leszek Lilien Bharat Bhargava Department of Computer Sciences.
Chapter 16 Unemployment: Search and Efficiency Wages.
Taxation and Income Distribution
Chapter 19 Equivalence Types of Auctions Strategic Equivalence
Environmental Economics Class 7. Incentive Based Regulation: Basic Concepts Up to this point, the focus has been on resource allocation. Since the use.
Fair Value Measurement By: Associate Professor Dr. GholamReza Zandi
Law and economics: game theory N.J. Philipsen Associate Professor of Law and Economics Faculty of Law, Research Institute METRO Shandong University, Jinan,
Auction Seminar Optimal Mechanism Presentation by: Alon Resler Supervised by: Amos Fiat.
6.1 Chapter 7 – The Theory of Consumer Behavior  The Theory of Consumer behavior provides the theoretical basis for buyer decision- making and the foundation.
The Moral Hazard Problem Stefan P. Schleicher University of Graz
1 Sampling Distributions Lecture 9. 2 Background  We want to learn about the feature of a population (parameter)  In many situations, it is impossible.
Prediction Markets and Business Forecasts Opportunities and Challenges in the New Information Era Professor: Andrew B. Whinston McCombs School of Business.
1 Self-government and Impossibility Theorem: How to find a good allocation mechanism? Anita Gantner Wolfgang Höchtl Rupert Sausgruber University of Innsbruck.
Auction Theory תכנון מכרזים ומכירות פומביות Topic 7 – VCG mechanisms 1.
Automated Design of Multistage Mechanisms Tuomas Sandholm (Carnegie Mellon) Vincent Conitzer (Carnegie Mellon) Craig Boutilier (Toronto)
Topic 2: Designing the “optimal auction” Reminder of previous classes: Discussed 1st price and 2nd price auctions. Found equilibrium strategies. Saw that.
Paul Milgrom and Nancy Stokey Journal of Economic Thoery,1982.
Static Games of Incomplete Information
Lecture 2 Auction Design This lecture derives bidding rules for some auctions where there is incomplete information, and discusses the the virtues and.
Contracting Under Imperfect Commitment PhD 279B December 3, 2007.
Auctions serve the dual purpose of eliciting preferences and allocating resources between competing uses. A less fundamental but more practical reason.
Auctions serve the dual purpose of eliciting preferences and allocating resources between competing uses. A less fundamental but more practical reason.
Introduction Many organizations use decision rules to alleviate incentive problems as opposed to incentive contracts The principal typically retains some.
6.853: Topics in Algorithmic Game Theory Fall 2011 Constantinos Daskalakis Lecture 22.
Auctions serve the dual purpose of eliciting preferences and allocating resources between competing uses. A less fundamental but more practical reason.
A Supplier’s Optimal Quantity Discount Policy Under Asymmetric Information Charles J. Corbett Xavier de Groote Presented by Jing Zhou.
1 Plaintiphobia in State Courts ? An Empirical Study of State Court Trials on Appeal Theodore Eisenberg and Michael Heise Journal of Legal Studies 報告人:高培儒.
Quick summary One-dimensional vertical (quality) differentiation model is extended to two dimensions Use to analyze product and price competition Two.
Incomplete Information and Bayes-Nash Equilibrium.
Risk Aversion and Optimal Reserve Prices in First and Second-Price Auctions Audrey Hu University of Amsterdam Stephen A. Matthews University of Pennsylvania.
Global sourcing Pol Antràs – Elhanan Helpman (2004)
Advanced Subjects in GT Prepared by Rina Talisman Introduction Revenue Equivalence The Optimal Auction (Myerson 1981) Auctions.
 This will explain how consumers allocate their income over many goods.  This looks at individual’s decision making when faced with limited income and.
Lecture 4 on Auctions Multiunit Auctions We begin this lecture by comparing auctions with monopolies. We then discuss different pricing schemes for selling.
RUPAYAN GUPTA ROGER WILLIAMS UNIVERSITY November 8, 2012 Designing Institutions for Global Security.
Information Design: A unified Perspective Prior information
Part A-I The Economic Theory of Legal Process
Information, Incentives, and Mechanism Design
Presentation transcript:

M. Bayes D. Kovenock C. de Vries The Economic Journal 115, (2005)

Motivation Difference in suits filed and expenditures between different legal systems. The US is generally viewed as having an excessive number of lawsuits compared to other nations

Motivation What design features lead to lower legal expenditures and fewer lawsuits? Does reducing legal expenditures reduce the social cost of litigation?

Tort Reform in the US In 1991 VP Quayle proposed a modification to the legal system Loser required to pay winner’s legal costs up to own cost level.

Tort Reform in the US 2004 Economic Report of the President Americans spend twice as much on torts than on new automobiles

Figure 1: Tort Expenditures as a Percentage of GDP

Previous Literature Spier (1992) Reinganum and Wilde (1986) Schweizer (1989) Hughes and Snyder (1995)

Previous Literature Spier (1992) Costly for plaintiff to go to court These costs do not influence court decision Plaintiff always wins Amount won is randomly assigned

Previous Literature Reinganum and Wilde (1986) Schweizer (1989) Probability of winning is exogenous Independent of legal expenditures

Previous Literature Reinganum and Wilde (1986) Schweizer (1989) Model is useful for determining incentives to go to court instead of settling out of court

Previous Literature Reinganum and Wilde (1986) Schweizer (1989) Model does not allow comparisons to situations where parties can improve probability of winning Hiring better attorneys Use of expert witnesses

Previous Literature Hughes and Snyder (1995) Optimism Model Exogenous beliefs concerning merit of case These beliefs determine whether parties settle Expected payoffs from trial can be determined

Legal Systems Across the world, variations in legal systems create different contests These contests differ in the costs associated with winning and losing the court case

Legal Systems American Litigants pay own expenses British Loser pays own expenses and all of winner’s Continental Loser pays own expenses and a fraction of the winner’s

Legal Systems Qualye – Loser pays own costs and reimburses winner up to loser’s cost level Marshall – Winner pays own costs and reimburses loser for all of loser’s costs Matthew – Winner pays own expenses and transfers an amount the is proportional to own expenses to loser

Two views of the justice system Winning is determined solely be expenditures Winning is independent of expenditures and is determined solely by the merit of the case presented.

The Model An auction-theoretic model of litigation Each party i has a private valuation v i Valuation is an independent random draw from a distribution function with continuous density Distribution of valuations is common knowledge

The Model

Legal ownership of an asset is in dispute Role of court is to examine evidence and award the asset to the party presenting the best case

The Model Each party has costs for gathering and presenting evidence Legal expenditures of party i are e i e i ≥ 0

The Model The court’s only observation is of the quality of the cases presented. Quality (q i ) is a continuous, strictly increasing function of legal expenditure

The Model Note:

The Model Underlying Assumptions: Symmetric production technologies Both parties have similar claim to asset

The Model Payoff depends on: Outcome of trial Fee shifting rules

The Model Payoff function for agent i are fee shifting parameters

The Model Best case wins Independent of ‘truth’. Truth is unobservable to the court. (The only observation of the court is of the quality of the case)

The Model Court cases are neither taxed nor subsidized

The Model Implications of A3: due to internalized costs and therefore:

The Model Using the relations from A1, A2, and A3 and substituting into this payoff function:

The Model Proposition 1: The payoff function

Legal Systems Revisited American Litigants pay own expenses British Loser pays own expenses and all of winner’s Continental Loser pays own expenses and a fraction of the winner’s

Legal Systems Revisited Note that the British System is the limit of the Continental System as beta goes to zero

Legal Systems Revisited Qualye – Loser pays own costs and reimburses winner up to loser’s cost level Marshall – Winner pays own costs and reimburses loser for all of loser’s costs Matthew – Winner pays own expenses and transfers an amount the is proportional to own expenses to loser

Legal Systems Revisited Summary

Legal Outlays at Trial Characterize closed-form expressions for equilibrium expenditures Uses the auction-theoretic model

Legal Outlays at Trial Expected payoff expression

Legal Outlays at Trial Value from winning Value from losing Thus

Legal Outlays at Trial Differentiation with respect to e i yields F.O.C.

Comparative Statics Equilibrium expenditures are decreasing in beta. Higher beta requires winner to pay more Which reduces the benefit of spending Leading to less vigorous court battles

Comparative Statics Which is an incomplete ordering of the legal systems in question

Crossing Functions Equilibrium spending under the American and Marshall functions cross As do American and Quayle functions Because these functions cross expenditure rankings are not possible

Revenue Equivalence Theorem Let U(v) be expected utility in the unique SE Let P(v) be the corresponding probability of winning

Revenue Equivalence Theorem Internalization of legal costs implies that net payments across types are E[e(v)] Noting that in SE: P(v) = F(v)

Revenue Equivalence Theorem Using results standard in the mechanism design literature (Klemperer, 1999):

Revenue Equivalence Theorem But since the litigant with the highest value always wins, the utility of a litigant with the lowest valuation U(0) =

Revenue Equivalence Theorem Substitution and taking expectations yields:

Revenue Equivalence Theorem Equating these two expressions and integrating yields:

Revenue Equivalence Theorem To summarize:

Proposition 4 While actual expenditures depend on both alpha and beta, expected expenditures are independent of alpha and strictly decreasing in beta. Expected total expenditure (TC) is thus also independent of alpha and decreasing in beta.

Total Expected Expenditures which can be used to create a full ranking of expected total expenditure by legal system

Ranking by total expected expenditure In systems with lower expected total cost, the expected payoff is higher, leading to:

Ranking by expected payoff This ranking is dependent on beta, the amount of his or her own legal expenditures the winner pays.

Tradeoffs in Beta Higher betas result in lower equilibrium expenditures. Higher betas results in higher payoffs, increasing incentive to file lawsuits.

“… systems which generate lower expected expenditures result in higher expected payoffs from litigation, and, therefore, result in more cases being brought to trial”

Incentives to Litigate Modeled as a Prisoner’s Dilemma

American System Litigation dominates conceding for any player with a positive valuation. Ex ante legal outlays are maximized when beta = 1

Ex Ante Legal Outlays Take into account both: Ex post expenditures per trial Incentive to litigate

Maximum at beta = 1, the American System

Conclusions Litigation systems with lower equilibrium legal expenditures per trial provide a greater incentive for parties to file lawsuits than systems with higher equilibrium expenditures

Future Directions Lack of statistics comparing different systems Future research can generate this data Difficulties in cross-cultural comparisons

Future Directions Capture difference in merit of suits: by allowing for asymmetric legal production functions

Future Directions Incorporate work by Che and Gale (1998) on budget constrained players to analyze a more complex type of problem.

Future Directions In any case, there are many ways in which this model can be extended to provide a more detailed picture of the incentives to litigate and the equilibrium characteristics of court cases.

Comments

Imperfectly Discriminating Courts What are differences in equilibrium of this model and a model wherein the court is not perfectly discriminating?

Imperfectly Discriminating Courts Do the perceptions of a nation’s citizens as to the efficiency of the court system alter how they approach the filing of lawsuits in a systematic way?