Chapter 16: Bargaining Ordering Information: Betty Jung

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
8 Potential GDP and the Natural Unemployment Rate CHAPTER.
Advertisements

1 The Economics of Unions Giorgio Brunello. 2 Unions cross-country (Visser, 2006, Mon Lab Rev) 2 things to note: 1. Large cross-country variation in prevalence.
Any Questions from Last Class?. Chapter 14 Bargaining COPYRIGHT © 2008 Thomson South-Western, a part of The Thomson Corporation. Thomson, the Star logo,
Games With No Pure Strategy Nash Equilibrium Player 2 Player
Game Theory: Inside Oligopoly
Chapter 20: The Problem of Moral Hazzard
Fehr and Falk Wage Rigidity in a Competitive Incomplete Contract Market Economics 328 Spring 2005.
© 2003 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Dividends and Dividend Policy Chapter Seventeen.
© 2003 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Dividends and Dividend Policy Chapter Seventeen Prepared by Anne Inglis, Ryerson University.
Chapter Outline Cash Dividends and Dividend Payment
Chapter 23: Managing Vertical Relationships COPYRIGHT © 2008 Thomson South-Western, a part of The Thomson Corporation. Thomson, the Star logo, and South-Western.
Game Theory “Necessity never made a good bargain.” - Benjamin Franklin Mike Shor Lecture 13.
1 Unless otherwise noted, the content of this course material is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution – Non-Commercial 3.0 License.
Game Theory The study of rational behavior among interdependent agents Agents have a common interest to make the pie as large as possible, but Agents have.
Any Questions from Last Class?. Chapter 13 Strategic Games COPYRIGHT © 2008 Thomson South-Western, a part of The Thomson Corporation. Thomson, the Star.
Simultaneous games with continuous strategies Suppose two players have to choose a number between 0 and 100. They can choose any real number (i.e. any.
A camper awakens to the growl of a hungry bear and sees his friend putting on a pair of running shoes, “You can’t outrun a bear,” scoffs the camper. His.
WHY DO SOME FIRMS SUCCEED? Why do some firms succeed and others fail? Possible explanations include- Luck. How does this help us understand decision-making?
Chapter 11 Game Theory and Asymmetric Information
Accessing Resources for Growth from External Sources
The United States Federal Reserve By Dr. Paul Lockard Professor Black Hawk College.
1 1 Lesson overview BA 592 Lesson I.10 Sequential and Simultaneous Move Theory Chapter 6 Combining Simultaneous and Sequential Moves Lesson I.10 Sequential.
Managerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 5e Chapter 9: Economics of Strategy: Game Theory McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2009 by The McGraw-Hill.
David Bryce © Adapted from Baye © 2002 Game Theory: The Competitive Dynamics of Strategy MANEC 387 Economics of Strategy MANEC 387 Economics.
8 PART 3 Potential GDP and the Natural Unemployment Rate
Corporate Taxes Value of the firm and WACC
Labor Union Ideas 1. Intro You and I have seen that firms that want to hire labor take a good look at the marginal revenue product of labor and consider.
Introduction to Labor Economics
Chapter Fourteen Strategy. © 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.14–2 Strategic Behavior A set of actions a firm takes to increase its profit,
Potential GDP and the Natural Unemployment Rate CHAPTER 24.
Basic Tools of Finance Finance is the field that studies how people make decisions regarding the allocation of resources over time and the handling of.
This Week’s Topics  Review Class Concepts -Sequential Games -Simultaneous Games -Bertrand Trap -Auctions  Review Homework  Practice Problems.
Introduction to Labor Economics
Chapter 22: Getting Divisions to Work in the Firm’s Best Interest COPYRIGHT © 2008 Thomson South-Western, a part of The Thomson Corporation. Thomson, the.
Chapter 9 Labor Economics. Copyright © 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.9-2 Learning Objectives Determine why the demand curve for labor.
Chapter 21: Getting Employees to Work in the Firm’s Best Interest
Any Questions from Last Class?. Chapter 18 Getting Employees to Work in the Best Interests of the Firm COPYRIGHT © 2008 Thomson South-Western, a part.
Chapter 2 The One Lesson of Business
Managerial Economics: A Problem-solving Approach
Introduction to Game Theory and Strategic Interactions.
Accessing Resources for Growth from External Sources
ENTR 452 Chapter 14: Accessing Resources for Growth
Chapter 7 Economies of Scale and Scope
Collaborating with Competitors
Any Questions from Last Class?. Chapter 17 The Problem of Moral Hazard COPYRIGHT © 2008 Thomson South-Western, a part of The Thomson Corporation. Thomson,
Chapter 4 Extent (How Much) Decisions
Any Questions from Last Class?. Chapter 15 Making Decisions with Uncertainty COPYRIGHT © 2008 Thomson South-Western, a part of The Thomson Corporation.
Unions and Collective Bargaining Topic 4 Part I. Topic Outline Bargaining Models under Complete Information Applied to Collective Bargaining Nash’s Cooperative.
Cengage Webinar: Managerial Economics: A Problem-solving Approach (2 nd Edition) Managerial Economics: A Problem Solving Appraoch (2 nd Edition) Luke M.
MICROECONOMICS: Theory & Applications By Edgar K. Browning & Mark A. Zupan John Wiley & Sons, Inc. 10 th Edition, Copyright 2009 PowerPoint prepared by.
Chapter 4 Why Do Interest Rates Change?. Copyright © 2009 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved. 4-2 Chapter Preview In the early 1950s, short-term.
Economic Policymaking
Chapter ElevenCopyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall. 1 Chapter 11 Game Theory and Asymmetric Information.
Chapter 1 Introduction: What This Book is About Managerial Economics: A Problem Solving Appraoch (2 nd Edition) Luke M. Froeb,
Lecture 5 Financial Incentives This lecture is paired with our previous one that discussed employee benefits. Here we focus on the reasons why monetary.
제 10 장 게임이론 Game Theory: Inside Oligopoly
Lecture 5B Complete Information Games This lecture analyzes complete information games, before turning to a discussion of Home Depot.
Chapter 1 Introduction to Labor Economics Copyright © 2010 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
Labor-Management Relations
Review Monopoly Summary A monopoly is a firm that is the sole seller in its market. It faces a downward-sloping demand curve for its product. A.
Oligopoly and Game Theory Topic Students should be able to: Use simple game theory to illustrate the interdependence that exists in oligopolistic.
Copyright ©2014 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly accessible website, in whole or.
Types of Business Structures
Management support systems II
Game Theory: The Competitive Dynamics of Strategy
Chapter 1 Introduction: What This Book is About
Chapter 7 Economies of Scale and Scope
Chapter 4 Extent (How Much) Decisions
Chapter 16: Bargaining Ordering Information: Betty Jung
Lecture 10 Coordination and Reputation
Presentation transcript:

Chapter 16: Bargaining Ordering Information: Betty Jung Marketing Specialist, Finance/Economics/Decision Sciences South-Western | Cengage Learning 5191 Natorp Boulevard, Mason, OH 45040 The ISBN for your 2e book alone is:  1439077983   The Bundle ISBN for your 2e book + the printed access card for MBA Primer is: 0538771240 Managerial Economics: A Problem Solving Appraoch (2nd Edition) Luke M. Froeb, luke.froeb@owen.vanderbilt.edu Brian T. McCann, brian.mccann@owen.vanderbilt.edu Website, managerialecon.com COPYRIGHT © 2008 Thomson South-Western, a part of The Thomson Corporation. Thomson, the Star logo, and South-Western are trademarks used herein under license. Slides prepared by Lily Alberts for Professor Froeb

Summary of main points Strategic view of bargaining: model as either a simultaneous-move or sequential-move game. A player can gain bigger share of the \“pie” by 1) changing a simultaneous-move game into a sequential- move game with a first-mover advantage; or by 2) committing to a position. Credible commitments (threats) are difficult to make because they require players to commit to a course of action against their self-interest. Thus, the best threat is one you never have to use.

Summary of main points (cont.) The strategic view of bargaining focuses on how the outcome of bargaining games depends on who moves first and who can commit to a bargaining position, as well as whether the other player can make a counteroffer. The non-strategic view of bargaining focuses on the gains and alternatives to agreement to determine the outcome of barganing. Main insight: The gains from agreement relative to the alternatives to agreement determine the terms of any agreement. Anything you can do to increase your opponent’s relative gains from reaching agreement or to decrease your own will improve your bargaining position.

Introductory anecdote 1: Bear Stearns In March of 2007, Bear Stearns (on the verge of bankruptcy and under pressure from the Treasury Dept.) accepted an acquisition offer from JP Morgan: to sell at just $2 per share. Bear’s shareholders were unhappy with the deal, and threatened to declare bankruptcy instead. In following two days Bear’s stock was up to $6 per share. Bargaining ended when JP Morgan offered to pay $10 per share and Bear shareholders accepted the offer.

Introductory anecdote 2: Texaco In 1985, Texaco was found guilty by a Texas jury for interfering with Pennzoil’s attempt to buy Getty Oil. Texaco was fined $10.5 billion, but appealed the verdict and began negotiating with Pennzoil. In 1987, Texaco filed for bankruptcy. Pennzoil was then unable to seize control of Texaco’s assets. Texaco was also freed from the responsibility to pay interest and dividends. One year later Texaco and Pennzoil settled the case, with Texaco having to pay only $3 billion. Texaco successfully used bankruptcy to reduce its liability by over 70% This chapter examines bargaining, and strategies to improve your bargaining position, like those used by Bear Stearns and Texaco .

Introduction: Bargaining There are two complementary ways to look at bargaining: the strategic view analyzes bargaining using the tools of game theory (ch 15). Bargaining can be viewed as either a simultaneous-move game with two equilibria or a sequential- move game, where one player gains an advantage by committing to a position. the non-strategic view acknowledges that real life negotiations don’t have fixed rules as formal games do. This view postulates that the alternatives to agreement determine the terms of agreement, regardless of the rules of the negotiating game. If you can increase your opponent’s relative gain, or decrease your own, you can gain a bigger share of the pie. By declaring (or threatening) bankruptcy, Bear Stearns and Texaco were able to improve their bargaining “position”, i.e., by changing the alternatives to agreement, they changed the terms of agreement. By improving their outside option by declaring bankruptcy, Bear Stearns and Texaco both reduced their own gain to reaching agreement and this allowed them to get a bigger share of the proverbial “pie” In Texaco’s case, bankruptcy also increased Pennzoil’s relative gain because they could suspend paying dividends.

Bargaining: a simultaneous-move game Example: Wage negotiations Management and labor are bargaining over a fixed sum of $200 million Two possible strategies are available to each player: “bargain hard” or “accommodate.” If both bargain hard, no deal is reached. Neither side gains. If both accommodate, they split the gains from trade. If one player bargains hard and the other accommodates, then the player who bargains hard takes 75% of the “pie”

Bargaining: a simultaneous game (cont.) There are two equilibria for this game Management prefers the lower-left equilibrium Labor prefers the upper-right. This bargaining game has the same structure as a game of “chicken” Each party can gain by committing to a position, which turns it into a sequential game

Bargaining: a sequential-move game In sequential-move bargaining the first “player” makes an offer that the second “player” can accept or refuse. Again to analyze a sequential-move game look ahead and reason back. The first-mover “looks ahead and reasons back” to determine the how her rival will react to each possible move. Then the first-mover can determine the consequences of each possible move. In this case, the sequential-move games present a “first- mover advantage,” i.e., by moving first a player can gain an advantage. Using the same wage negotiation example, we can look at sequential-move bargaining and first-mover advantage.

Bargaining game: first-mover advantage Management “wins” by moving first and making a low offer

Bargaining game: first-mover advantage Union can change the outcome by credibly committing to strike if a low offer is made

Sequential-move bargaining (cont.) Because the management has the first-mover advantage, it is in their best interest to make a low offer, and it is in the union’s best interest to accept that offer. However, if the union can effectively threaten to strike (in such a way that the management believes them) they can change the outcome of the game despite management’s first-mover advantage. Credible threats are hard to make because they require the union act against its self interest. If management doesn’t believe the threat, the union might actually have to follow through on the threat. So, again, the best threat is one you never have to use.

Non-strategic View of Bargaining The outcome in strategic bargaining “games” is dependent on the rules of the game, but in real life, the rules are not always clear. John Nash proved that any reasonable outcome to a bargain would maximize the product of the bargainers’ surplus. This is known as an “axiomatic” or “non-strategic” view of bargaining. In this view, the gains from bargaining relative to the alternatives to bargaining, determine the terms of any bargain. This view also teaches that to increase your bargaining power, you can increase your opponent’s gain from reaching agreement or decrease your own. If your rival has more to gain by agreeing, he becomes more eager to reach agreement, and accepts a smaller share of the surplus.

Non-strategic view (cont.) Nash’s axiomatic approach: [ S1(z) – D1 ] x [ (S2(z) – D2 ] , where: z is the agreement S1(z) is the value of the agreement to player 1 (sub 2 for player two) D1 is “disagreement value,” or pay-off if no agreement is reached, for player 1 (sub 2 for player two) So player 1’s gain from agreement is (S1(z) – D1)

Non-strategic view (cont.) For example, two brothers are bargaining over a dollar. If no agreement is reached, neither participant gains. If they reach an agreement (z) Player one, the older brother, has a surplus of z Player two, the younger brother, has a surplus of 1 – z Nash’s solution is for them to “split” the gains from trade, i.e., {½, ½} is the axiomatic solution. But, now the older brother receives a $0.50 bonus for “sharing nicely,” and the total gain rises from $1.00 to $1.50 The Nash bargaining outcome is for the brothers to split to total gains – each receiving $0.75, meaning the older brother effectively shares half of his bonus. By increasing the first player’s gain to reaching agreement, he becomes more eager to reach agreement, and “shares” his gain with his brother.

Bonuses for agreement Giving a bonus for reaching agreement is similar to incentive compensation schemes used by many companies. When salespeople are offered bonuses it increases their eagerness to reach agreement and this induces them to accept “weaker” agreements. So giving salespeople such a bonus driven incentive will lead to lower prices when they negotiate with customers. (This concept will be further addressed in chapter 20)

Alternatives to agreement Nash’s bargaining solution incorporates the effect of alternatives to agreement on the agreement itself. This creates some sound bargaining advice: To improve your own bargaining position, increase your opponent’s gain from reaching agreement, S2(z) – D2, or reduce your own gain from reaching agreement, S1(z) – D1. When you increase your opponent’s gain in agreement, you make him more willing to agree. Reducing your own gain makes you less willing to compromise and helps to improve your position.

How Nash’s view differs from strategic The strategic view of bargaining places a greater emphasis on timing and commitment in determining the outcome of the game. With the labor/management example, the union’s commitment to strike, or management making the first move, changes the equilibrium of the game. But neither action changes the gains of the agreement so neither would affect the Nash bargaining outcome. The Nash bargaining outcome incorporates the idea that if you decrease your own gain to agreement you become a better bargainer. EXAMPLE: the best time to ask for a raise is when you have another attractive offer waiting for you, you have less to gain by reaching agreement. Your bargaining position improves. This is similar to the idea of “opportunity cost.” The opportunity cost of staying at your current job is giving up the new offer; if the new job pays more, you’re costs (bottom line) go up.

Improving a Bargaining Position Discussion Question: When is the best time to buy a car? Hint: Remember, car salesmen are generally paid a commission for the sales they make. Discussion Question: How can mergers or acquisitions improve bargaining power? Buying a Car: Remember that sales commissions are typically paid at the end of the month, so shopping for a car near the end of the month means that the sales person can earn an immediate commission for any sale. This raises the gain to reaching agreement (remember sales people have very high discount rates) and makes it more likely that you will receive a better offer. You can also shop for cars at unpopular times, like Christmas Eve, when there are no other customers around. If selling to you is the foregone opportunity to sell to someone else, then the sales person’s gains from reaching agreement with you are higher if there is no one else around. Mergers: By merging, you can make the gains from reaching agreement HIGHER for your opponent versus bargaining with you and your merger partner separately. Since they have higher gains from reaching agreement, they will be in a weaker bargaining position.

Merger bargaining example A Managed Care Organization (MCO) markets its network to an employer Network value is $100 if it contains either one of two local hospitals But the value rises to $120 if it contains both And there is no value without at least one of the hospitals The gain to the MCO from adding either of the hospitals to its network when it already has the other is $20 Nash bargaining solution predicts this is evenly split So, each hospital gets $10 for joining the MCO But if the hospitals merge and bargain together, The MCO can no longer drop one of the hospitals, so the gain from striking a bargain with the merged hospital is the full $120 The gain is evenly split in the Nash bargaining solution The merged hospitals thus receive $60, a post-merger gain of $40

Health care mergers In Rhode Island in 2003, Blue Cross Blue Shield (BCBS, the health insurance company covering state employees) hired PharmaCare to provide pharmaceutical services. PharmaCare created a network of retail pharmacies willing to sell drugs to state employees at discounted rates. The previous contract had allowed employees to buy from any pharmacy but was considerably more expensive. In the new PharmaCare contract, 4 retail pharmacies were excluded from the plan. These 4 firms lobbied RI legislature to include them in the new plan and offered to provide the same discounted price but PharmCare declined their request to join. Pharmacare maintained that allowing the other stores to join would eliminate the savings generated by having a restricted network. PharmaCare’s bargaining position would deteriorate. Many politicians, though, like “freedom-of-choice” bills that would open any pharmacy willing to meet the negotiated prices.

Alternate Intro Anecdote Under the 2002 CHAOS (Create Havoc Around Our System) plan, flight attendants threatened to either stage a mass walkout for several days or to strike individual flights of Midwest Express, with no advance warning to either customers or management. Midwest Express reacted by cancelling all flight attendant vacation, and threatened to lock out any employee who participated in the strike Flight attendant union promised funding from its strike fund to support any attendant who ended up locked out. The biggest strength of the union’s threat was that it could be effective without full implementation. The threat of random strikes was enough to push passengers to other airlines. After 30 days of CHAOS, the union successfully negotiated a new contract. Mastering tactics like effective threats backed by credible commitments, one of the subjects of this chapter, allowed the flight attendants to successfully negotiate a favorable labor agreement.

Managerial Economics - Table of contents 1. Introduction: What this book is about 2. The one lesson of business Benefits, costs and decisions 4. Extent (how much) decisions 5. Investment decisions: Look ahead and reason back 6. Simple pricing Economies of scale and scope 8. Understanding markets and industry changes 9. Relationships between industries: The forces moving us towards long-run equilibrium 10. Strategy, the quest to slow profit erosion 11. Using supply and demand: Trade, bubbles, market making 12. More realistic and complex pricing 13. Direct price discrimination 14. Indirect price discrimination 15. Strategic games 16. Bargaining 17. Making decisions with uncertainty 18. Auctions The problem of adverse selection The problem of moral hazard 21. Getting employees to work in the best interests of the firm 22. Getting divisions to work in the best interests of the firm 23. Managing vertical relationships 24. You be the consultant EPILOG: Can those who teach, do? Managerial Economics - Table of contents