1 Inflation Dynamics’ Micro Foundations: How Important is Imperfect Competition Really? Sara G. Castellanos and José A. Murillo Banco de México September.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
INTRA-INDUSTRY TRADE AND THE SCALE EFFECTS OF ECONOMIC INTEGRATION Elisa Riihimäki Statistics Finland, Business Structures September
Advertisements

Cointegration and Error Correction Models
Discussion of Michael Ehrmann’s “Targeting Inflation from Below: How Do Inflation Expectations Behave?” Reflections on 25 Years of Inflation Targeting.
Relationships Between Inflation, Interest Rates, and Exchange Rates 8 8 Chapter South-Western/Thomson Learning © 2003.
Chapter 18. Explaining business cycles: Aggregate demand and supply in action ECON320 Prof Mike Kennedy.
Macroeconomics fifth edition N. Gregory Mankiw PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich macro © 2002 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved Topic 11: Aggregate.
1 Empirical Evaluation of the Degree of Price Transmission from the Border to the Consumers in Mozambique Xavier Cirera and Virgulino Nhate.
CHAPTER 9 © 2006 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Macroeconomics, 4/e Olivier Blanchard Inflation, Activity, and Nominal Money Growth Prepared by: Fernando.
Slide 15-1Copyright © 2003 Pearson Education, Inc. Exchange rates and the Foreign Exchange Market Money, Interest Rates and Exchange Rates  Price Levels.
Estimating price rigidity in coffee markets: A cross country comparison Ph.D candidate: Iqbal Syed Supervisor: Prof. Kevin Fox UNSW.
1 Why Demand Uncertainty Curbs Investment: Evidence from a Panel of Italian Manufacturing Firms Maria Elena Bontempi (University of Ferrara) Roberto Golinelli.
1 Chapter 4 Sources of Macroeconomic Fluctuations © Pierre-Richard Agénor and Peter J. Montiel.
© 2003 Prentice Hall Business PublishingMacroeconomics, 3/eOlivier Blanchard Prepared by: Fernando Quijano and Yvonn Quijano 9 C H A P T E R Inflation,
Simple Linear Regression
26 Prepared by: Fernando Quijano and Yvonn Quijano © 2004 Prentice Hall Business PublishingPrinciples of Economics, 7/eKarl Case, Ray Fair The Labor Market,
Chapter 17 Unemployment, Inflation, and Growth. 2 Introduction In Chapter 4, 5, 6, we have studied a classical model of the complete economy, but said.
CHAPTER 2 A Tour of The Book CHAPTER 2 Prepared by: Fernando Quijano and Yvonn Quijano Copyright © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice.
International Fixed Income Topic IVC: International Fixed Income Pricing - The Predictability of Returns.
Chapter 9: Inflation, Activity, and Nominal Money Growth Copyright © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Macroeconomics, 5/e Olivier.
Economics 282 University of Alberta
Macroeconomic Facts Chapter 3. 2 Introduction Two kinds of regularities in economic data: -Relationships between the growth components in different variables.
Chapter 12 Keynesian Business Cycle Analysis: Non–Market-Clearing Macroeconomics Copyright © 2012 Pearson Education Inc.
Chapter 21. Stabilization policy with rational expectations
Economics 215 Intermediate Macroeconomics Introduction.
Risk Premium Puzzle in Real Estate: Are real estate investors overly risk averse? James D. Shilling DePaul University Tien Foo Sing National University.
Money, Output, and Prices Classical vs. Keynesians.
© Copyright IBM Corporation 2007 Disclaimer (Optional location for any required disclaimer copy. To set disclaimer, or delete, go to View | Master | Slide.
Chapter 17 Basic Theories of the Balance of Payments.
Copyright © 2002 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved CHAPTER 12 The Phillips Curve and Expectations.
Inference for regression - Simple linear regression
Chapter 17. Inflation, unemployment and aggregate supply
PRESENTED BY: ASMA’A ALAJMI THE COLLAPSE OF “PPP” DURING THE 1970’S.
Chapter 2 – Business Forecasting Takesh Luckho. What is Business Forecasting?  Forecasting is about predicting the future as accurately as possible,
Begin $100 $200 $300 $400 $500 GraphsSupplyAndDemandPoliciesAndMarkets Economies ImportantKeyTermsGDP.
Monetary Policy Responses to Food and Fuel Price Volatility Eswar Prasad Cornell University, Brookings Institution and NBER.
 Circular Flow of Income is a simplified model of the economy that shows the flow of money through the economy.
Monetary Policy and Exchange Rate Pass-through: Theory and Evidence Michael B. Devereux and James Yetman.
Macroeconomics Chapter 151 Money and Business Cycles I: The Price-Misperceptions Model C h a p t e r 1 5.
Comments on Gali’s “Hysteresis and the European Unemployment Problem Revised” Robert J. Gordon Northwestern University, NBER, CEPR ECB Forum on Central.
DETERMINANTS OF INFLATION IN ROMANIA Student: COVRIG NICOLAE Supervisor: Prof. MOISĂ ALTĂR.
Copyright © 2015 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written consent of McGraw-Hill Education.
Determinants of Credit Default Swap Spread: Evidence from the Japanese Credit Derivative Market.
MODELLING INFLATION IN CROATIA TANJA BROZ & MARUŠKA VIZEK.
BANCO DE MEXICO Mexico’s Underlying Inflation. IntroductionIntroduction Methodology for calculating Underlying Inflation in México The Mexican Experience.
1 Taylor Rule and the Term Structure Objectives: 1.To understand the relation between central bank policy and long term interest rates. 2.Understand “news”
Lecture 10 Aggregate Supply. slide 1 Three models of aggregate supply 1.The sticky-wage model 2.The imperfect-information model 3.The sticky-price model.
Answers to Review Questions  1.Explain the difference between aggregate demand and the aggregate quantity demanded of real output. Ceteris paribus, how.
 Stabilization policies (fiscal and monetary) are applied to affect inflation and unemployment  The difficulty in stabilization is that inflation and.
Outline 4: Exchange Rates and Monetary Economics: How Changes in the Money Supply Affect Exchange Rates and Forecasting Exchange Rates in the Short Run.
Why Do Countries Use Capital Controls? Prepared by R. Barry Johnston and Natalia T. Tamirisa - December 1998 Presented by: Alyaa Ezzat.
Discussion of time series and panel models
Slide 0 CHAPTER 13 Aggregate Supply In Chapter 13, you will learn…  three models of aggregate supply in which output depends positively on the price level.
Ifo Institute for Economic Research at the University of Munich Employment Effects of Innovation at the Firm Level Stefan Lachenmaier *, Horst Rottmann.
Strategies for Implementing Monetary Policy in the Americas: The Role of Inflation Targeting Federal Reserve Bank – Atlanta, October 2004 Inflation Dynamics’
Review of the previous lecture 1. IS-LM model  a theory of aggregate demand  exogenous: M, G, T, P exogenous in short run, Y in long run  endogenous:
Review of the previous lecture Exchange rates nominal: the price of a country’s currency in terms of another country’s currency real: the price of a country’s.
Expectations and Macroeconomic Stabilization Policies Adaptive and Rational Expectations.
Relationships Between Inflation, Interest Rates, and Exchange Rates 8 8 Chapter South-Western/Thomson Learning © 2003.
Copyright  2006 McGraw-Hill Australia Pty Ltd PPTs t/a Macroeconomics 2e by Dornbusch, Bodman, Crosby, Fischer, Startz Slides prepared by Dr Monica Keneley.
Pantelis Pantelidis, University of Piraeus Dimitrios Kyrkilis, University of Macedonia Efthymios Nikolopoulos, University of Macedonia February 2011 The.
Determining How Costs Behave
Basic Theories of the Balance of Payments
Relationships Between Inflation, Interest Rates, and Exchange Rates
Relationships Between Inflation, Interest Rates, and Exchange Rates
Sven Blank (University of Tübingen)
Economics 332 Spring 2013 © copyright by Casey B. Mulligan
The Determinants of FDI Inflows to Greece
Chapter 4 Sources of Macroeconomic Fluctuations
Relationships among Inflation, Interest Rates and Exchange Rates
Presentation transcript:

1 Inflation Dynamics’ Micro Foundations: How Important is Imperfect Competition Really? Sara G. Castellanos and José A. Murillo Banco de México September 2004

2 The TRUE Motivation Why we are not inside those bands yet? One possibility is that prices in less than perfectly competitive sectors (e.g. tobacco, gas, pharmaceutics, movie theaters, bread, air transportation, etc.) be deflating more slowly than others.

3 Motivation On one hand: Macroeconomic models increasingly rely on imperfect competition to explain monetary policy’s effectiveness, staggered prices, and inflation inertia (Blanchard and Fischer, 1989; Calvo, 1983, Mankiw, 2000). Calibrations of this type of GE models reproduce well the dynamics of United States’ business cycle (Chari, Kehoe and McGrattan, 2000; Christiano, Eichenbaum and Evans, 2001). Merits of different stabilization strategies have also been discussed with these building blocks (Calvo and Vegh, 1999).

4 On the other one: With few exceptions (Hall, 1988, or Basu and Fernald, 1997 for the case of the United States), empirical evidence regarding the extent of imperfectly competitive markets is lacking. Evidence on whether inflation dynamics are substantially affected by this feature is even more lacking (De Brouwer and Ericsson, 1995; Mehra, 2000; Bertocco et al, 2002, and Faruquee, 2004 are based on aggregate data). The deepening of international flows of trade, in view of imperfectly competitive domestic markets, may be a crucial factor behind several successful disinflation stories (Rogoff, 2003). Empirical evidence about this issue is pending as well.

5 Objective These developments suggest that it is a good time to assess this fruitful micro foundation with the data and ask: 1.Is imperfect competition pervasive? 2.How does it affect price formation and dynamics? In this paper we use the data of the Mexican economy to provide an answer to these two questions. 1.We determine the extent of imperfect competition in the manufacturing sector, using the method proposed by Panzar and Rosse (1987). 2. We build consumer price indexes of manufactures by perfectly and imperfectly competitive industries and examine their dynamics using error correction models that relate these prices to labor and imported input costs.

6 Main Findings Imperfect competition is a widespread market structure in manufacturing. Price adjustment to labor and foreign input cost shocks differs across perfectly and imperfectly competitive industries in the way that theory predicts: –prices of perfectly competitive sectors respond to changes on the exchange rate only, –prices imperfectly competitive sectors respond to changes on the exchange rate and on wages.

7 Main Findings Price adjustment is estimated to be faster in the former case than in the latter. Therefore, even if in the long run industries where firms enjoy market power do not produce higher inflation, they may slow down the speed of convergence to a given target. Lower inertia of perfectly competitive industries together with higher exchange rate pass-through also implies that the inflation rate of perfectly competitive industries is more volatile than the inflation of imperfectly competitive industries. Variations in the perfectly competitive manufactures price index precede those of the imperfectly competitive price index.

8 Related literature: Recent contributions on the relevance of heterogeneous price setting behavior (Ohanian, Stockman and Kilian, 1995, Chari, Kehoe and McGrattan, 2000, or Bils and Klenow, 2002) Bils and Klenow find a significant negative correlation between the frequency of price changes the four-firm concentration ratios, the wholesale markup, or the rate of product substitution in the other. Caucutt et al (1999) document price rigidity in US manufacturing industries and relate it to industry concentration, good durability and the economic cycle.

9 Classifying Perfectly and Imperfectly Competitive Industries The Panzar-Rosse Statistic is based on a reduced form revenue equation. Although it is less powerful than structural models used for single industry studies, it has less stringent data requirements and lower risk of model misspecification in a study of several industries. For Mexico’s case this method seems preferable to alternatives based on the cycle properties of the Solow residual (Hall, 1988 or Roeger, 1995): –those methods assume constant price markups and their estimation needs long quarterly time series of value added data. –the effects observed on Mexican manufacturing sector after GATT (1984) and NAFTA (1994) undermine the validity of this assumption.

10 The Panzar-Rosse statistic is defined as: where R* is the revenue function, the w i are the components of the vector w, so that w i denotes the price of the ith input factor. This expression describes a restriction imposed on a profit-maximizing monopoly. Panzar and Rosse describe other two models so the following industry classification can be obtained:  Long-run competitive equilibrium. 0<  ≤1 Symmetric monopolistic competition equilibrium 0>  Monopoly or cartel

11 Estimation Method and Data We use a log linear revenue equation (Shaffer and Disalvo, 1994 and Fischer and Kamerschen, 2003): in which the vector of input prices includes the industry wage, the exchange rate, the price of gas, the price of electricity, and a domestic interest rate. Output quantity endogeneity is taken care of through two stage least squares estimation (using a lag of output as instrumental variable). Data set: 71 manufacturing industries of Monthly Industrial Survey (MIS) that can be matched with generic products of Mexico’s Consumer Price Index (47 percent of the manufacturing sector sales on average within January 1994-December 2003).

12 Results We find:  12 perfectly competitive industries;  56 imperfectly competitive industries (43 monopolistically competitive and 13 monopolies).  3 industries with no statistically significant input prices (classified into the imperfect competitive group, assuming that the list is complete). During the analysis period, sales of the perfectly competitive industries account for 20.6 percent of all manufacturing sales, while those of imperfectly competitive industries for 26.7 percent.

13 A sample of our results: ::::

14 Price Formation and Dynamics in Perfectly and Imperfectly Competitive Industries Industries are grouped into “competitive” and “imperfectly competitive” ones to build price indexes. The generics contained in the indexes have a weight of 25.8 percent in the CPI and percent of the core merchandise price index. The price index of imperfectly competitive industries has a larger weight in the CPI than the one for the perfectly competitive ones (18.7 percent and 7.1 percent, respectively). Also, the weight of automobiles in the perfectly competitive price index is 3.3 percent. Annual inflation of perfectly and imperfectly competitive price indexes display a wide gap between them in several episodes.

15 Graph 1 Annual Inflation Rate: Perfectly Competitive vs. Imperfectly Competitive Price Index, Panzar-Rosse Classification (percentage)

16 Also, the volatility of the perfectly competitive annual inflation rate is higher than that of imperfectly competitive manufactures. Graph 2 Rolling Variation Coefficient Gap of Perfectly and Imperfectly Competitive Annual Inflation (24 month window) Jan-80Jan-81Jan-82 Jan-83Jan-84 Jan-85Jan-86Jan-87Jan-88Jan-89Jan-90 Jan-91 Jan-92Jan-93Jan-94 Jan-95Jan-96 Jan-97Jan-98 Jan-99 Jan-00Jan-01 Jan-02 Jan-03

17 The correlation coefficient of perfectly and imperfectly competitive inflation first differences according to the Panzar-Rosse classification in periods t and t-I suggests that the first one moves before the second one. Graph 3 Correlation Coefficient: First Difference of Perfectly Competitive Manufactures Inflation in t and Imperfectly Competitive Manufactures Inflation in t-i, January November 2003

18 Price Formation and Dynamics For each price index we estimate the following equation (see Garcés, 2001 and Baillieu et al, 2003): where p t is the log price index, w t is the log nominal wage cost (measured with the average wage quotation of the IMSS), and e t is log foreign input cost (measured through the real exchange rate, peso-dollar exchange rate times United States CPI). p t-1, w t-1 and e t-1 constitute the error correction term depicting the long run relationship among the variables (De Brouwer and Ericsson, 1998). Appropriate Johansen cointegration tests indicate that this relationship is stationary. We report the estimations of this equation for the CPI, the core merchandise price index, the core services price index, and our industry structure price indexes.

19  c 2, c 3 and c 4, are statistically significant and have the expected sign: inflation rises as a response to either wage or exchange rate increases. Price disturbances have a transitory nature and converge to the long term equilibrium level. c 5, c 6 and c 7 that account for the short term effects also have the expected signs, but their statistical significance varies across regressions.  Price indexes of manufactures produced in imperfectly competitive industries show smaller coefficients of lagged exchange rate and lagged price level and a larger coefficient associated to the lagged wage.  Due to the core services component and the fact that perfectly competitive manufactures have a low share in the merchandise component, the CPI dynamics are closer to those of the imperfectly competitive price index.  The adjusted-R 2 and the F-statistic respectively suggest good data fit and overall statistical significance. Recursive and rolling regression estimations also show that the coefficients are stable.  Price formation in perfectly competitive industries relies less on past inflation than in imperfectly competitive industries.

20 Table 2 Estimation Results of Price Error Correction Models of Perfectly and Imperfectly Competitive Manufactures

21 Table 3 Pass-Through Coefficients of Wage and Exchange Rate of Perfectly and Imperfectly Competitive Manufactures Long run pass through coefficients of the CPI coincide with the previous studies. Those for the inflation rate in the perfectly competitive industries show that price dynamics depend mostly on the exchange rate. For imperfectly competitive industries there is both exchange rate and wage pass-through The pass-through coefficients are similar whether a threshold of import to domestic sales is used and for different specifications of the Panzar-Rosse revenue equation.

22 For both wages and the exchange rate periods in which the prices of one sector show a higher pass-through than the other are observed. After 2002, it seems that the exchange rate pass through has been higher for the perfectly competitive index and lower for the imperfectly competitive index, while the wage pass through has had the opposite pattern. Graph 4 Rolling Regression Estimates of the Exchange Rate Pass Through Graph 5 Rolling Regression Estimates of the Wage Pass-Through

23 Some Policy Implications The inflation dynamics of perfectly competitive manufactures is consistent with the law of one price, while in imperfectly competitive manufactures wage variations also affect prices, consistent with a cost push. However, further analysis does not support the cost push view: the only weakly exogenous variable of the system is the price level. Thus, the central bank’s policy does matter in determining firms’ ability to pass forward higher wage costs into higher product prices. That perfectly competitive manufactures have a lower degree of inflationary inertia than imperfectly competitive industries may imply different employment responses. Also, that an inflationary bout could produce a significant relative price misalignment between the goods produced in perfectly and imperfectly competitive industries (Ohanian, Stockman and Kilian, 1995 or Bils and Klenow, 2002).

24 Table A7 Pass-Through Coefficients of Wage and Exchange Rate of Manufactures with Import Penetration Rate above and below 30 Percent Some robustness checks: Are the price formation processes described solely explained by foreign competition? We find that both among manufactures with a high and low import penetration rate, the perfectly competitive ones again exhibit higher exchange rate coefficients and lower wage coefficients than the imperfectly competitive ones. This suggests an affirmative answer to Rogoff (2003).

25 Table A9 Pass-Through Coefficients of Wage and Exchange Rate of Manufactures with Concentration Ratio CR4 above and below 18 Percent Some robustness checks: Does the Panzar-Rosse Index add tell something different or additional to seller concentration (C4)?

26 Price flexibility, durability, industry concentration, degree of competition and import penetration. Extensions: If competition degree, import penetration and seller concentration affect price dynamics, which matters most? Caucutt et al (1999) define price change amplitude (PA) as the average over a time period of |  P t |=|log(P t /P t-1 )|

27 Why we are not inside those bands anymore?