AGEC 640 – Agricultural Policy Thursday, September 18 th, 2014 Nutrition and Food Markets Today: Imperfect information & food demand Reading: Masters and.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
What Is Perfect Competition? Perfect competition is an industry in which Many firms sell identical products to many buyers. There are no restrictions.
Advertisements

RESOURCE ALLOCATION & THE MARKET Demand, supply and the market Sources of failure in the market for health care The insurance system of funding health.
Perfect Competition 12.
8 Application: The Costs of Taxation. CHAPTER 8 APPLICATION: THE COSTS OF TAXATION 2 The Effects of Taxation We saw in Chapter 6 how taxesChapter 6 –reduce.
Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 5 The Standard Trade Model.
Consumer Equilibrium and Market Demand Chapter 4.
Copyright©2004 South-Western 8 Application: The Costs of Taxation.
The Standard Trade Model
© 2010 Pearson Education Canada. Airlines and automobile producers are facing tough times: Prices are being slashed to drive sales and profits are turning.
11 PERFECT COMPETITION CHAPTER.
Supply, Demand, and Equilibrium Today: An introduction to supply and demand, and how they relate to equilibrium.
Elasticity and Its Application
Chapter-5 The Demand for Goods.
EC 355 International Economics and Finance
Elasticity and Its Application
© 2007 Thomson South-Western. Application: The Costs of Taxation Welfare economics is the study of how the allocation of resources affects economic well-
Chapter 2 Supply and Demand McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Changes in Income An increase in income will cause the budget constraint out in a parallel manner An increase in income will cause the budget constraint.
PERFECT COMPETITION 11 CHAPTER. Objectives After studying this chapter, you will able to  Define perfect competition  Explain how price and output are.
The Standard Trade Model
Principles of Micro Chapter 8: “Application: The Cost of Taxation” by Tanya Molodtsova, Fall 2005.
Chapter 4 Individual and Market Demand. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 42 Topics to be Discussed Individual Demand Income and Substitution Effects.
Elasticity of Demand and Supply
LEARNING OUTCOME 2 & 3 DEMAND AND SUPPLY DEMAND EFFECTIVE DEMAND desire to purchase backed by the ability to pay DETERMINANTS OF DEMAND: Price Tastes.
ECO1000 Economics Semester One, 2004 Lecture Four.
THE THEORY OF DEMAND & SUPPLY
MICROECONOMICS TOPIC 2 Economics DEMAND.
ECON 101: Introduction to Economics - I Lecture 3 – Demand and Supply.
Chapter 4 Understanding Demand Yoliann Pons Period.5
Lecture 4Slide 1 Topics to be Discussed Individual Demand Income and Substitution Effects Market Demand Consumer Surplus Empirical Estimation of Demand.
Chapter 2: The Basics of Supply and Demand
Introduction: Economic Issues Introduction: Economic Issues.
1 Intermediate Microeconomic Theory Demand. 2 Demand Analysis In analyzing individual’s behavior regarding a given good, we start with a consumer’s demand.
1 Individual Choice Principles of Microeconomics Professor Dalton ECON 202 – Fall 2013.
Individual and Market Demand
3 DEMAND AND SUPPLY.
PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University Demand and Revenue Management 1 © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved.
Slide 1 AGEC 640 – Agricultural Development and Policy Nutrition and Food Markets September 18 th, 2014 Today: Nutrition, health and human capital (Reading:
Elasticity of Demand Chapter 5. Slope of Demand Curves Demand curves do not all have the same slope Slope indicates response of buyers to a change in.
Chapter 2 Theoretical Tools of Public Finance © 2007 Worth Publishers Public Finance and Public Policy, 2/e, Jonathan Gruber 1 of 43 Theoretical Tools.
How Markets Work Demand. Introduction Economics is about choices that people make to face scarcity and how those choices are affected by incentives. Prices.
Copyright©2004 South-Western 8 Application: The Costs of Taxation.
7 Perfect Competition CHAPTER
12 PERFECT COMPETITION © 2012 Pearson Addison-Wesley.
Climbing the Economic Mountain! Section 1 Twelve Key Elements of Economics Supply and Demand Supply and Demand: Applications and Extensions Supply and.
PERFECT COMPETITION 11 CHAPTER. Objectives After studying this chapter, you will able to  Define perfect competition  Explain how price and output are.
Chapter 8 The Costs of Taxation. Objectives 1. Understand how taxes reduce consumer and producer surplus 2. Learn the causes and significance of the deadweight.
Demand and Consumer Theory International Managerial Economics.
Session 1 Demand Analysis Managerial Economics Professor Changqi Wu.
Elasticity and Its Application
3 Demand and Supply © 2013 Pearson Australia After studying this chapter, you will be able to ■Describe a competitive market and think about a price.
QR 24 Economics Review Session 12/3/2009. Agenda Demand curves Supply curves Equilibrium Market failures – Moral hazard – Adverse selection Net Present.
Individual & Market Demand Chapter 4. 4 main topics related to Individual & Market Demand 1. Use the Rational Choice model Derive an individual’s demand.
Lecture 2: The Basics of Supply and DemandSlide 1 Topics to Be Discussed Supply and Demand The Market Mechanism Changes in Market Equilibrium Elasticities.
Copyright © 2004 South-Western/Thomson Learning Application: The Costs of Taxation Welfare economicsWelfare economics is the study of how the allocation.
Copyright © 2006 Nelson, a division of Thomson Canada Ltd. 8 Application: The Costs of Taxation.
CHAPTERS 4-6 SUPPLY & DEMAND Unit III Review. 4.1 Understanding Demand Demand: the desire to own something and the ability to pay for it. The law of demand:
1 Chapter 3 Lecture DEMAND AND SUPPLY. 2 Market and Prices A market is any arrangement that enables buyers and sellers to get information and do business.
11 CHAPTER Perfect Competition.
Introduction to Economics of Water Resources. Public or private Excludability (E): the degree to which users can be excluded Subtractability (S): the.
A Primer on Demand Analysis and Market Equilibrium
Perfect Competition CHAPTER 11. What Is Perfect Competition? Perfect competition is an industry in which  Many firms sell identical products to many.
CHAPTER 5 Elasticity l.
19-1 Consumer Choice  Prices are important in determining consumer behavior.  New products have to be priced correctly. The price could be set too high.
12 PERFECT COMPETITION. © 2012 Pearson Education.
AGEC 640 – Agricultural Policy September 12, 2017 Nutrition and Food Markets Extra slides on imperfect information & food demand – not delivered in.
Today: Nutrition, health and human capital
Intermediate Microeconomic Theory
Chapter 9 A Two-Period Model: The Consumption-Savings Decision and Credit Markets Macroeconomics 6th Edition Stephen D. Williamson Copyright © 2018, 2015,
Reading: Masters and Sanogo, 2002 in AJAE
Presentation transcript:

AGEC 640 – Agricultural Policy Thursday, September 18 th, 2014 Nutrition and Food Markets Today: Imperfect information & food demand Reading: Masters and Sanogo, 2002 in AJAE Homework #2 on food choices due Thr., 9/25

What’s behind consumers’ price and income response? Slide 2 Price of food Quantity of food consumed P1P1 P2P2 Q1Q1 Q2Q2 Consumers’ income Quantity of food consumed Q2Q2 Q1Q1 Y1Y1 Y2Y2 “demand curve”“Engel curve” (=income-consumption curve) price elasticity of demand: %∆Q/ %∆P income elasticity of demand: %∆Q/ %∆Y …we need to think very carefully about what generates these curves!

To understand food demand, we’ll want to consider… consumers’ optimization (“Econ 101” effects) –preferences: indifference curves and welfare –price effects: demand curves and elasticity –income effects: Engel curves and elasticity really constrained optimization (Econ 102, 103…) –what else might be useful to understand food intake? –benefits are delayed, and often not observable credit/insurance constraints (poor can’t borrow to buy food) “behavioral” effects (predictable violations of rationality) –weak self-discipline (addiction, obesity, etc.) –distorted perceptions (anxiety, obsession, etc.) information asymmetries (role of 3 rd party quality assurance)

Quantity of “b” goods Optimization and consumer preferences Qb Quantity of “a”, all other goods Qa Initial observed point “O” The points in this quadrant offer less of both goods, so any optimizing consumer would prefer “O” to them The points in this quadrant offer more of both goods, so any optimizing consumer would prefer them to “O” All combinations amongst which the consumer is indifferent must fall along a downward sloping line.

Quantity of “b” goods Optimization and substitution possibilities The “indifference curve” QbQb QaQa Eventually, one becomes less willing to reduce all other things in exchange for more of “b”, so the indifference curve becomes flatter here Eventually, one becomes less willing to reduce “b” in exchange for more of all other things, so the indifference curve becomes steeper here There is an indifference curve, drawn smooth for simplicity. Quantity of “a”, all other goods

Quantity of “b” goods Constrained optimization: Indifference curves and the “expenditure line” Qb Qa higher indifference levels lower indiff. levels Indifference curve through initial point Exp. = PaQa + PbQb Qa = Exp./Qa – (Pb/Pa)Qb Slope of expenditure line = -Pb/Pa Expenditure level at the initial point Quantity of “a”, all other goods

Quantity of “b” goods Indifference level at the initial point The new indifference level is lower The new expenditure line is steeper slope = -Pb’/Pa Constrained optimization: When the price of “b” rises, how do consumers adjust? Slope of expenditure line = -Pb/Pa Quantity of “a”, all other goods the price of b has no effect on this point higher prices induce substitution and reduce “real income”

Price effects The Demand Curve Price Quantity Consumed When price changes, consumers move along their demand curve. Welfare is lower at higher prices (later, we’ll see this as “consumer surplus”)

When income rises, consumers’ demand curve shifts (usually to the right, as consumers buy larger quantities at each price) Income effects The Demand Curve Price Quantity Consumed

Price Elasticity of Demand Price ($/lb) Quantity Consumed (lbs/yr) To measure the “steepness” of demand curves in a more useful way than with its slope, we use the elasticity of demand (ε): = percentage change in quantity for a percentage change in price = %ΔQ / %ΔP = 5/10 / -.25/1.25 = -.5 / -.2 = - 2.5

Elasticity and expenditure: “Price-elastic” vs. “price-inelastic” demand Price ($/lb) Quantity Consumed (lbs/yr) “Elastic demand” : demand curve is relatively flat when price rises, expenditure (P×Q) falls | ε | > 1 “Inelastic demand” : demand curve is relatively steep when price rises, expenditure (P×Q) rises | ε | < 1 “Unit-elastic demand” : demand curve is such that when price rises, expenditure (P×Q) stays constant: | ε | = 1

Income Effects on Food Consumption Price ($/lb) Quantity Consumed (lbs/yr) Remember that when income rises, consumers’ demand curve shifts (usually to the right) It’s helpful to draw a curve of consumption on income, for a given price

Quantity Consumed (lbs/yr/pers) Income ($/yr/pers) , Engel curve for food use only Engel curve for all uses Income Effects on Food Consumption A hypothetical “Engel” curve

Quantity Consumed (lbs/yr/pers) Income ($/yr/pers) , Income elasticity (e) : % change in Q / % change in Y varies widely by income level, and by type of use Income Elasticity of Demand (see slide 31a)

Income ($/year) Qty. Consumed (kg/year) Elasticity along the Engel Curve no effect elastic or “luxury” inelastic or “normal” negative or “inferior” Income elasticity (e=%ΔQ/ %ΔY) is closely linked to income level : income-elastic (“luxury”) goods: e > 1 income-inelastic (“normal”) goods: 0 < e < 1 negative-elasticity (“inferior”) goods: e < 0 “necessary”

Average income and price elasticities of demand in Indonesia (estimated in the 1970s) “inelastic” “elastic” “inelastic” “elastic” Reminder: elasticity is %ΔQ/%ΔY (income) or %ΔQ/%ΔP (price). An extreme case: can price elasticity ever go positive? Such “Giffen” goods have finally been documented, by Jensen & Miller (2007)

Effect of income growth among the poorest 30% in Brazil, Income elasticities by income group, rural Brazil, (“luxuries” for the poor) (“inferior” for everyone)

Calorie intake by nutrient group and income level income level in 1962 (log scale) calories from each nutrient group (percent of total) The poorest eat mainly carbohydrates; income growth permits an increase in fats and proteins

Macronutrient intake by U.S. children aged 6 to 11 years ,98 Girls Energy(kcal)1,8061,8321,825 Protein(g) Fat(g) Carbohydrate(g) Carbohydrate(% kcal) Boys Energy(kcal)1,9501,8912,050 Protein(g) Fat(g) Carbohydrate(g) Carbohydrate(% kcal) Source: Enns, Mickle and Goldman (2002), Table 5. At high (U.S.-level) incomes, we’ve been switching back to more carbohydrates.

Now… what else might be useful to understand food intake? Food is a public concern, but it is not a “public good” Food demand generate subtle kinds of market failures One reason is that its benefits are important but often delayed and often not observable, so we have: –credit and insurance constraints (the poor can’t borrow) –“behavioral” effects (people are predictably irrational) weak self-discipline (addiction, obesity, etc.) distorted perceptions (anxiety, obsession, etc.) –asymmetric information (need quality assurance) example of Masters and Sanogo (2002) study of infant foods in Bamako, Mali

Weight-for-height (WHZ) and height-for-age (HAZ) of children in Mali, relative to international norms The most severe nutritional deficits occur in a relatively brief period

Child mortality is closely linked to their weight-for-height Source: Reprinted from Fawzi, W.W., M.G. Herrera, D.L. Spiegelman, A.E. Amin, P. Nestel, and K.A. Mohamed “A Prospective Study of Malnutrition in Relation to Child Mortality in the Sudan.” The American Journal of Clinical Nutrition 65(4):

Why are nutritional deficits so severe between 4 and 24 months of age? exposure to disease –due to initial introduction of water and solids, or –perhaps also more mobility and contact with others; deficits in nutrient intake –due to differences between infant and family foods, –and failure to provide enough infant-quality foods.

Characteristics of infant foods Infants need foods of higher nutrient density than the family diet, from when they outgrow the nutrients in breastmilk to when they can digest enough of the family diet. High density is obtained from high-cost ingredients (oilseeds or animal products), mixed with low-cost staples (cereal grains, etc.) but parents cannot observe an infant food’s ingredient ratios and density, even after consumption, because other factors affect growth

Economics of credence goods Akerlof (1970) and others: If quality is unobservable, quantity will be… zero! optimizing people will not respond to price …except as remedied by trust in a brand. ==> sellers use advertising and high prices as visible commitments to quality, so –buyers must pay a premium over known costs, to buy guaranteed quality, –e.g. premiums paid for “brand-name” lawyers, pharmacists, auto mechanics, etc.

Table 1. Infant foods for sale in Bamako, Mali (1999) Brand namePackagingRetail Prices (FCFA/unit)* Mkt.StoresPharmacy Cérélac (wheat)400 g. can Cérélac (wheat)200 g. box Cérélac (rice)400 g. can1600 Cérélac (wheat/Banana)400 g. can1750 Cérélac (wheat +3 fruits)400 g. can2240 Blédilac** (wheat)250 g. can1270 Blédina** lactée fruits250 g. box1830 Farinor** (maize/soy)400 g. box Source: Masters and Sanogo, MISOLA500 g. bag 300 UCODAL (e.g. Sinba)200 g. bag 200

Akerlof (1970) saw an alternative remedy to lower the cost of credence goods: third-party certification –mandatory testing => complete coverage examples: FDA, USDA limitations: tax-funded, incentive for fraud –fee-for-service => self-sustaining, self-policing examples: ISO, UL limitations: scale economies, may not emerge spontaneously Economics of credence goods (continued)

Benefits and Costs of Certification in Mali 1.benefits of certification –what is food-quality information really worth? –do some mothers value information more than others? 2.costs of certification –what are set-up and marginal costs? –what volume would be certified? 3.net gains from certification –do they justify the investment risks? –would the program be sustainable?

To detect what certification is worth, we need a experimental economics.. Vickrey (1961) and others: Preference-revealing auctions mimic real markets: price is fixed by others; choice is to accept or decline M&S experiment is aimed at very, very low-income people -- avoids using money, so choice is among infant foods only; avoids calculations, so choice is easy and natural: give mothers a can of Cerelac offer to swap for increasing quantities of substitute products record whether they accept or decline each choice give them one of their choices, selected at random The design is not quite strategy-proof; respondents may hold out for slightly more of each substitute than in ideal auction.

Summary statistics for willingness-to-pay results WTP (FCFA per 400 g.) ave.s.d.min.max. WTP by product 1. Cerelac (market price) 2. Certilac Anonymous product Raw ingredients WTP for premium for 2 over 3: Certification for 3 over 4: Processing

So certification has large benefits… but what would be its cost? 10 million FCFA/month for advertising 1 m. FCFA/mo. per 50 tests/mo. for staffing 0.6 m FCFA/mo. per 20 tests/mo. for transport 3,520 FCFA/mo. per test for consumables 1,000 x 400g. sold per test done => cost falls below ave. WTP at 30,000 bags/mo. => cost falls below 100 FCFA at 215,000 /mo.

How much food would be certified? 50,000 children aged 6-24 months in Bamako 100 g./day average consumption per child => 8 bags of 400 g. per month low scenario: 39% use (now using Cerelac) high scenario: 89% use (now using any food) => total potential is 155,000 – 350,000 bags/mo.

Would certification’s benefits exceed its costs? Two ways to estimate: (1) Each respondent has a different WTP –Some respondents’ WTP below cost –Construct demand curves & optimal quantity –Find economic surplus (2s) All respondents have identical WTP –Average WTP is way above cost –Full market size is certified –Find total benefits - costs

Estimated certification demand and average-cost curves

Table 3. Consumer surplus and net benefit from certification Case 1 Case 2 Consumer surplus approach Equilibrium qty. certified(400 g. bags/mo.)150,000345,000 Net economic surplus gain(FCFA/month)51,543,984134,029,438 Net economic surplus gain(US$/year)951,5812,474,390 Cost-benefit analysis approach Total estimated market size(400 g. bags/mo.)154,746353,138 Net economic benefit/month(FCFA/month)51,713,454132,138,264 Net economic surplus gain(US$/year)954,7102,439,476

OK, so quality information is needed… should testing be voluntary or mandatory? Private solutions work if a “certifier” can –force users to pay (that is, exclude free-riders), e.g.: Underwriters’ Laboratories (sellers pay for label) Consumer Reports, CarFax (buyers pay each time) –and thereby capture enough revenue to pay the cost of obtaining the information; while maintaining a credible quality signal of their own! Often it’s cheaper to use the government: –“ value capture” from consumers can occur through taxation (e.g. USDA grades) or user fees (e.g. air traffic) –quality-destroying competition can be barred by mandatory standards and licensing –but the “quality” being upheld may not be valued by consumers; standards may be just an entry barrier to protect insiders

…Some conclusions Food intake decisions involve –not only observable attributes (taste, texture, color), –but also unobservable qualities and delayed effects. Food choices can be hard to understand using economics on observable prices and quantities only –so sometimes we need inferences and experiments –but much of the “irrationality” in food consumption can be understood as constrained optimization –this allows us to plan public interventions that raise welfare, even though food is not a public good.