Economics of Tort Law. CBO Study. The Economics of U.S. Tort Liability: A Primer, October 2003.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
DutyCausation DamagesBreach of Duty Elements of Negligence.
Advertisements

Q3 LAW NOTES 1 TORTS.
ECON 1450 – Professor Berkowitz Lectures on Chapter 2 Tort Law Area of Common Law concerned with accidental injuries Potential defendant engages in activity.
Problem of people being injured by “defective products.”
What You’ll Learn How to define negligence (p. 88)
4Chapter SECTION OPENER / CLOSER: INSERT BOOK COVER ART Negligence and Strict Liability Section 4.2.
Q UINCY COLLEGE Paralegal Studies Program Paralegal Studies Program Litigation and Procedure Negligence and Strict Liability Litigation and Procedure Negligence.
{ Chapter 10 TORTS: Negligence and Strict Liability.
Chapter 18: Torts A Civil Wrong
Law I Chapter 18.
Tort Law Part 2 Negligence and Liability. Negligence Most common tort Accidental or Unintentional Tort Failure to show a degree of care that a “reasonable”
Chapter 3 Tort Law.
© 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license.
Copyright © 2004 by Prentice-Hall. All rights reserved. © 2007 Prentice Hall, Business Law, sixth edition, Henry R. Cheeseman Chapter 5 Negligence Chapter.
Tort – injury to person or property We are interested in unintentional torts, inadvertent accidents. Injuries sustained by breach of contract are covered.
BELL QUIZ ON CHAPTER 3 1. List two felony crimes. 2
Regulatory due care standard Statutory due care standard Common law due care standard  Reasonable man  Custom  Hand rule.
Private Wrongs: Torts Negligence and Strict Liability Chapter 14.
Tort Law – Unintentional torts
Hazards Liability and Tort Lecture 8. Outline Another economic role for the government is regulating hazards and risks Factory producing explosives (location.
Torts: Negligence and Strict Liability OBE 118, Section 3, Fall 2004 Professor McKinsey When a wrong was not intended but creates liability nonetheless.
Professor Charles H. Smith Negligence, Product Liability and Damages (Chapter 15) Summer 2009.
Strict Liability and Torts and Public Policy Mrs. Weigl.
Negligence and Unintentional Torts
By Monika, Max, Vanja, Nicole KEY PRINCIPLES OF NEGLIGENCE.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2013 Lecture 19.
Copyright © 2004 by Prentice-Hall. All rights reserved. © 2007 Prentice Hall, Business Law, sixth edition, Henry R. Cheeseman Chapter 5 Intentional Torts.
4Chapter SECTION OPENER / CLOSER: INSERT BOOK COVER ART Intentional Torts Section 4.1.
© 2004 West Legal Studies in Business A Division of Thomson Learning 1 Chapter 6 Strict Liability and Product Liability Chapter 6 Strict Liability and.
 1. Duty-The accused wrongdoer owed a duty of care to the injured person  2. Breach of Duty- the defendant’s conduct breached that duty  3. Causation-defendant’s.
Business Law. Your neighbor Shana is using a multipurpose woodcutting machine in her basement hobby shop. Suddenly, because of a defect in the two-year.
Chapter 14 Negligence and Unintentional Torts LAW 120.
Chapter 6.  A tort is a wrong  There are three categories of torts  Intentional torts  Unintentional torts (negligence)  Strict liability 6-2Copyright.
NEGLIGENCE (Unintentional Torts). The elements of negligence: * Negligence * Duty of Care * Standard of Care * Foreseeability * “reasonable person” *
TORTS A tort is committed when……… (1) a duty owing by one person to another, is… (2) breached and (3) proximately causes (4) injury or damage to the owner.
Unit 6 – Civil Law.
Torts in a Health care setting. What is a Tort? A tort is an infringement of a person’s rights that constitutes grounds for a lawsuit. This may be in.
CHAPTER 7 Negligence And Strict Liability.
Tort Law Summary. Entitles you to sue for damages in a civil court of law Entitles you to sue for damages in a civil court of law It is a “wrong” which.
7-1 Copyright © 2013 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
PE 254. Negligence The legal claim that a person failed to act as a reasonable and prudent person should, thereby resulting in injury to another person.
Chapter 7: Negligence and Strict Liability Copyright © 2009 South-Western Legal Studies in Business, a part of South-Western Cengage Learning. Jentz Miller.
Negligence and Strict Liability. Products Liability The liability of manufacturers, sellers, and others for the injuries caused by defective products.
Negligence. Homework 20.1 and 20.2 – read Chapter and 20.2 – read Chapter 20.
Chapter 20 Negligence. The failure to exercise a reasonable amount of care in either doing or not doing something resulting in harm or injury.
Contract Law for Paralegals: Traditional and E-Contracts © 2009 Pearson Education, Upper Saddle River, NJ All rights reserved Relationship of Tort.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 16.
 Development of Strict Liability.  Defendant’s liability for strict liability is without regard to: Fault, Foreseeability, Standard of Care or Causation.
American Public School Law Torts n Definition of a tort – Intentional interference – Strict Liability – Negligence – Elements of Negligence – Defenses.
Chapter 6 Torts and Strict Liability. Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.6-2 Three Kinds of Torts A tort is a wrong.
Chapter 09 Negligence and Strict Liability Copyright © 2012 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
Strict Liability and Product Liability Chapter 7.
4Chapter SECTION OPENER / CLOSER: INSERT BOOK COVER ART Intentional Torts Section 4.1.
Personal Injury Laws Objective: Define negligence and strict liability Bellwork: What was conversion? How do you think the name came about?
Chapter 20. Conduct that falls below the standard established by law for protecting others against unreasonable risks of harm Surgeon forgets to remove.
TORTS: A CIVIL WRONG Chapter 18. TORTS: A CIVIL WRONG Under criminal law, wrongs committed are called crimes. Under civil law, wrongs committed are called.
CHAPTER 18 PART I Torts: A Civil Wrong. A Civil Wrong In criminal law, when someone commits a wrong, we call it a crime. In civil law, when someone commits.
Negligence. Definition Negligence in an unintentional Tort This occurs when a person fails to use reasonable care and it causes harm to another person.
Understanding Business and Personal Law Negligence and Strict Liability Section 4.2 The Law of Torts A person can commit an unintentional tort, when he.
4Chapter SECTION OPENER / CLOSER: INSERT BOOK COVER ART Negligence and Strict Liability Section 4.2.
Negligence Tort law establishes standards for the care that people must show to one another. Negligence is the conduct that falls below this standard.
Section 4.2.
Neglect Torts Chapter 20.
The Law of Torts I’m going to sue you!.
Bell-work 1/27/17 Read one of the two quotes under World Government and give a brief meaning.
Negligence.
Section Outline Unintentional Torts Negligence Strict Liability
Negligence Ms. Weigl.
Lesson 6-1 Civil Law (Tort Law).
CIVIL LAW Unintentional Torts.
Presentation transcript:

Economics of Tort Law

CBO Study. The Economics of U.S. Tort Liability: A Primer, October 2003

U.S. Department of Justice, Civil Justice Survey of State Courts, 2001

Tort Law Tort – injury to person or property We are interested in unintentional torts, inadvertent accidents. Injuries sustained by breach of contract are covered under contract law

Tort liability A court imposed obligation on the tortfeasor to pay for a victim’s losses.

An efficient system would minimize these elements of cost Cost of injuries Cost of precaution Cost of administration Indirect costs to economy An efficient system would internalize externalities

Traditional tort liability requires three elements 1.Breach of Duty - The defendant’s act or failure to act must constitute the breach of a duty owed to the plaintiff by the defendant 2.Harm - The plaintiff must have suffered a harm 3.Cause - The defendant’s act or failure to act must cause the harm

Breach of duty Strict liability rule - only harm and cause are required for a tort –any harm is a breach of due care Negligence rules require a minimum duty of care

Duty of care  A legal standard prescribing the minimum acceptable level of precaution –Violation of the due care standard represents negligence –Due care standard is based upon a reasonable person

Harm There typically must be an actual harm. –Liability law does not compensate for exposure to risk Perfect compensation would compensate for both property losses and intangible harm. –Should reimbursement occur for intangible harms? –How do we determine the value of intangible harms? (The death of a child.)

Cause “But for” test (cause in fact) –Problem when there are multiple causes (ambiguous causation) Ex., Medical malpractice cases Proximity in the law is imprecise –“But for” test does not distinguish between proximate causes and remote causes –Proximate cause satisfies the “but for” test and is sufficiently direct to be the determined the legal cause of the injury

The economic purpose of tort law is to minimize the social cost of accidents. We will assume only cost of injury and cost of precaution x = precaution w = cost of a unit of precaution A = monetary value of the harm p(x) = probability of harm

Minimize social cost

Precaution Unilateral precaution –Only the injurer or only the victim can influence the probability or severity of injury Bilateral precaution –Both the injurer and the victim can influence the probability or severity of injury

Tort law incentives Strict liability with perfect compensatory damages gives the victim no incentive to take precaution No liability gives the injurer no incentive to take precaution

Strict liability Appropriate when only unilateral precaution by the injurer is possible –Injurer has incentive to minimize total social cost –Assumes costs can be accurately measured and injurer will be found liable for all harms he caused

Bilateral precaution When bilateral precaution is possible neither rule causes both to take the optimal level of precaution

Negligence standard Negligence rule with perfect compensation and the legal standard set to the efficient level of care gives the injurer incentives for efficient precaution. Victim responds as if there is no liability, therefore victim has efficient incentive for precaution

 Negligence rules give the victim and the injurer efficient incentives for precaution  Negligence rule is preferred when there is bilateral precaution

Negligence rules Simple negligence Negligence with defense of contributory negligence Comparative negligence Strict liability with defense of contributory negligence

Simple negligence –Injurer at fault => injurer liable –Injurer faultless => injurer not liable Negligence with defense of contributory negligence –Injurer at fault and victim faultless => injurer liable –Injurer faultless or victim at fault => injurer not liable

Comparative negligence –Injurer at fault and victim faultless => injurer bears 100% –Injurer faultless and victim at fault => victim bears 100% –Injurer at fault and victim at fault => bear cost in proportion to negligence Strict liability with defense of contributory negligence –Victim at fault => injurer not liable –Victim faultless => Injurer liable

Activity vs. Precaution With simple negligence the carnival operator is relieved of all liability as long as he adheres to the due standard. However, even with inspections, mishaps can occur, passengers can be injured. There is no incentive to limit the passengers on the ride or the number of carnivals.

Activity vs. Precaution Passengers, however, may take this into consideration. This may limit the number of passengers (the activity level.) When they do get on the ride they might also take some precaution. They will make sure restraints are functioning and will keep their hands and feet in.

Activity levels Under a negligence rule the marginal risk of harm to others by engaging in the activity is externalized. Under strict liability, the social cost of accidents is internalized. Induces efficient precaution and efficient activity by injurers. The party who escapes bearing the cost has an incentive for an inefficient activity level. Efficiency requires choosing a liability rule so that the party whose activity level most affects accidents bears the residual cost of accidental harm. Liability rules cannot provide an efficient incentive for bilateral activity levels

No single rule can create efficient incentives for both bilateral precaution and bilateral activity levels.

The Hand Rule for identifying efficient precaution United States v. Carroll Towing Co., (2d Cir. 1947) –Defendant hired to move barge –The mooring lines were not correctly adjusted –A barge broke loose and sank –The tug owner argued that barge owner was also negligent because there was no bargee

The Hand Rule for identifying efficient precaution “Since there are occasions when every vessel will break from her moorings, and since, if she does, she becomes a menace to those about her; the owner's duty, as in other similar situations, to provide against resulting injuries is a function of three variables: (1) The probability that she will break away; (2) the gravity of the resulting injury, if she does; (3) the burden of adequate precautions.” … it in algebraic terms: if the probability be called P; the injury, L; and the burden, B; liability depends upon whether B is less than L multiplied by P: i.e., whether B less than PL.

The Hand Rule for identifying efficient precaution Optimal precaution If the marginal cost of precaution is less than the marginal benefit from precaution, the party is negligent. When B < PL, the party is negligent

Potential errors Errors in setting due care standard Errors in damage award

Errors – Strict Liability Errors in setting damages under a rule of strict liability cause the injurer’s precaution to respond in the same direction as the error Errors in failing to hold injurers liable under a rule of strict liability causes them to take less precaution

Errors - Negligence Injurer’s negligence does not respond to modest errors in setting damages under the negligence rule Injurer’s precaution responds exactly to court errors in setting the legal standard under a negligence rule

Exceptions in tort liability Firefighter rule Good Samaritan protection Public policy rule

Firefighter rule Precludes a firefighter from recovering from one whose negligence causes or contributes to a fire that in turn causes injury or death to the firefighter –There is an assumption of risk –May be limited to premises liability and ordinary negligence

Good Samaritan protection Provides protection from ordinary negligence when providing emergency assistance There may be no general duty to render assistance

Public policy rule Damages would run counter to public policy goals A victim should not benefit from their own criminal behavior –A bomb maker sued those who sold him the gunpowder –A suit by a burglar against the homeowner for faulty stairs

Alcohol related liabilities An injured person can sue those who contributed to the injurer’s intoxication –Dram shop laws –Social host laws There was a special duty of care because the injurer was invited to drink

You’ll shoot your eye out Swix v Daisy Manufacturing, US District Court F.3d 678

Swix v Daisy Manufacturing After losing the use of his eye, Aaron, a minor, and his parents brought a product liability action against the manufacturer of the air rifle that his 11- year-old friend used to shoot him. The case claimed that the air rifle was defectively designed. The lower court dismissed the claim a gun is a “simple tool” under Michigan law and the dangers of pointing it at another person are “open and obvious.” –There is no need to warn of a danger where the danger is obvious –The product itself telegraphs the precise warnings the plaintiffs claim is lacking

Swix v Daisy Manufacturing The appeals court found that gun was a simple tool. However, the lower court failed to apply the reasonable child standard. A manufacturer who bypasses adults, upon whom the law ordinarily places responsibility, and markets a simple, but dangerous, tool directly to children may not avoid liability on the ground that the child should have known better The fact that Daisy intended that its air rifle be used under the direct supervision of an adult and that Swix’s grandfather had the same rule does not alter the “reasonable child standard”