SECOND PART: Algorithmic Mechanism Design. Implementation theory Imagine a “planner” who develops criteria for social welfare, but cannot enforce the.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Combinatorial Auction
Advertisements

6.896: Topics in Algorithmic Game Theory Lecture 21 Yang Cai.
Algorithmic mechanism design Vincent Conitzer
6.896: Topics in Algorithmic Game Theory Lecture 20 Yang Cai.
Collaboration Mechanisms in SOA based MANETs. Introduction Collaboration implies the cooperation between the nodes to support the proper functioning of.
CPS Bayesian games and their use in auctions Vincent Conitzer
An Approximate Truthful Mechanism for Combinatorial Auctions An Internet Mathematics paper by Aaron Archer, Christos Papadimitriou, Kunal Talwar and Éva.
Multi-item auctions with identical items limited supply: M items (M smaller than number of bidders, n). Three possible bidder types: –Unit-demand bidders.
Optimal auction design Roger Myerson Mathematics of Operations research 1981.
A Prior-Free Revenue Maximizing Auction for Secondary Spectrum Access Ajay Gopinathan and Zongpeng Li IEEE INFOCOM 2011, Shanghai, China.
Sep. 8, 2014 Lirong Xia Introduction to MD (mooncake design or mechanism design)
The selfish-edges Shortest-Path problem. The selfish-edges SP problem Input: an undirected graph G=(V,E) such that each edge is owned by a distinct selfish.
Preference Elicitation Partial-revelation VCG mechanism for Combinatorial Auctions and Eliciting Non-price Preferences in Combinatorial Auctions.
A Sufficient Condition for Truthfulness with Single Parameter Agents Michael Zuckerman, Hebrew University 2006 Based on paper by Nir Andelman and Yishay.
Seminar In Game Theory Algorithms, TAU, Agenda  Introduction  Computational Complexity  Incentive Compatible Mechanism  LP Relaxation & Walrasian.
6.853: Topics in Algorithmic Game Theory Fall 2011 Matt Weinberg Lecture 24.
Bundling Equilibrium in Combinatorial Auctions Written by: Presented by: Ron Holzman Rica Gonen Noa Kfir-Dahav Dov Monderer Moshe Tennenholtz.
Algorithmic Applications of Game Theory Lecture 8 1.
Mechanism Design and the VCG mechanism The concept of a “mechanism”. A general (abstract) solution for welfare maximization: the VCG mechanism. –This is.
Lecture 1 - Introduction 1.  Introduction to Game Theory  Basic Game Theory Examples  Strategic Games  More Game Theory Examples  Equilibrium  Mixed.
Mechanism Design. Overview Incentives in teams (T. Groves (1973)) Algorithmic mechanism design (Nisan and Ronen (2000)) - Shortest Path - Task Scheduling.
Agent Technology for e-Commerce Chapter 10: Mechanism Design Maria Fasli
Beyond selfish routing: Network Formation Games. Network Formation Games NFGs model the various ways in which selfish agents might create/use networks.
SECOND PART: Algorithmic Mechanism Design. Mechanism Design MD is a subfield of economic theory It has a engineering perspective Designs economic mechanisms.
The selfish-edges Minimum Spanning Tree (MST) problem.
Combinatorial Auction. Conbinatorial auction t 1 =20 t 2 =15 t 3 =6 f(t): the set X  F with the highest total value the mechanism decides the set of.
Frugal Path Mechanisms by Aaron Archer and Eva Tardos Presented by Ron Lavi at the seminar: “Topics on the border of CS, Game theory, and Economics” CS.
A Truthful 2-approximation Mechanism for the Steiner Tree Problem.
Near-Optimal Network Design with Selfish Agents By Elliot Anshelevich, Anirban Dasgupta, Eva Tardos, Tom Wexler STOC’03 Presented by Mustafa Suleyman CIFTCI.
SECOND PART: Algorithmic Mechanism Design. Implementation theory Imagine a “planner” who develops criteria for social welfare, but cannot enforce the.
SECOND PART: Algorithmic Mechanism Design. Mechanism Design MD is a subfield of economic theory It has a engineering perspective Designs economic mechanisms.
Mechanism Design Traditional Algorithmic Setting Mechanism Design Setting.
SECOND PART: Algorithmic Mechanism Design. Suggested readings Algorithmic Game Theory, Edited by Noam Nisan, Tim Roughgarden, Eva Tardos, and Vijay V.
SECOND PART on AGT: Algorithmic Mechanism Design.
Yang Cai Sep 8, An overview of the class Broad View: Mechanism Design and Auctions First Price Auction Second Price/Vickrey Auction Case Study:
SECOND PART: Algorithmic Mechanism Design. Mechanism Design Find correct rules/incentives.
CPS 173 Mechanism design Vincent Conitzer
Introduction 1 TexPoint fonts used in EMF. Read the TexPoint manual before you delete this box.: AAA A.
VCG Computational game theory Fall 2010 by Inna Kalp and Yosef Heskia.
Auction Seminar Optimal Mechanism Presentation by: Alon Resler Supervised by: Amos Fiat.
More on Social choice and implementations 1 TexPoint fonts used in EMF. Read the TexPoint manual before you delete this box.: AAA A Using slides by Uri.
6.853: Topics in Algorithmic Game Theory Fall 2011 Constantinos Daskalakis Lecture 21.
Mechanism Design CS 886 Electronic Market Design University of Waterloo.
Auction Theory תכנון מכרזים ומכירות פומביות Topic 7 – VCG mechanisms 1.
By: Amir Ronen, Department of CS Stanford University Presented By: Oren Mizrahi Matan Protter Issues on border of economics & computation, 2002.
Yang Cai Oct 08, An overview of today’s class Basic LP Formulation for Multiple Bidders Succinct LP: Reduced Form of an Auction The Structure of.
SECOND PART on AGT: Algorithmic Mechanism Design.
Algorithmic Mechanism Design: an Introduction Approximate (one-parameter) mechanisms, with an application to combinatorial auctions Guido Proietti Dipartimento.
The Minimum Spanning Tree (MST) problem in graphs with selfish edges.
Automated Mechanism Design Tuomas Sandholm Presented by Dimitri Mostinski November 17, 2004.
Beyond selfish routing: Network Games. Network Games NGs model the various ways in which selfish agents strategically interact in using a network They.
Beyond selfish routing: Network Games. Network Games NGs model the various ways in which selfish users (i.e., players) strategically interact in using.
Algorithmic Mechanism Design: an Introduction (with an eye to some basic network optimization problems) Guido Proietti Dipartimento di Ingegneria e Scienze.
The Shortest Path problem in graphs with selfish edges.
The Shortest-Path problem in graphs with selfish-edges.
SECOND PART on AGT: Algorithmic Mechanism Design.
6.853: Topics in Algorithmic Game Theory Fall 2011 Constantinos Daskalakis Lecture 22.
Algorithmic Mechanism Design Shuchi Chawla 11/7/2001.
Combinatorial Auction. A single item auction t 1 =10 t 2 =12 t 3 =7 r 1 =11 r 2 =10 Social-choice function: the winner should be the guy having in mind.
One-parameter mechanisms, with an application to the SPT problem.
Bayesian Algorithmic Mechanism Design Jason Hartline Northwestern University Brendan Lucier University of Toronto.
Network Formation Games. NFGs model distinct ways in which selfish agents might create and evaluate networks We’ll see two models: Global Connection Game.
Comp/Math 553: Algorithmic Game Theory Lecture 08
SECOND PART: Algorithmic Mechanism Design.
The Shortest-Path problem in graphs with selfish-edges
Combinatorial Auction
Combinatorial Auction
Combinatorial Auction
Combinatorial Auction
Presentation transcript:

SECOND PART: Algorithmic Mechanism Design

Implementation theory Imagine a “planner” who develops criteria for social welfare, but cannot enforce the desirable allocation directly, as he lacks information about several parameters of the situation. A mean then has to be found to “implement” such criteria. Subfield of economic theory with an engineering perspective: Designs economic mechanisms like computer scientists design algorithms, protocols, systems, …

The implementation problem Given: An economic system comprising of self- interested, rational agents, which hold some private preferences A system-wide goal (social-choice function) Question: Does there exist a mechanism that can enforce (through suitable economic incentives) the selfish agents to behave in such a way that the desired goal is implemented?

An example: auctions t 1 =10 t 2 =12 t 3 =7 r 1 =11 r 2 =10 Social-choice function: the winner should be the guy having in mind the highest value for the painting The mechanism tells to players: (1)How the item will be allocated (i.e., who will be the winner) (2) The payment the winner has to return, as a function of the received bids t i : is the maximum amount of money player i is willing to pay for the painting If player i wins and has to pay p his utility is u i =t i -p r i : is the amount of money player i bids (in a sealed envelope) for the painting r 3 =7

A simple mechanism: no payment t 1 =10 t 2 =12 t 3 =7 r 1 =+  r2=+r2=+ r3=+r3=+ …it doesn’t work… ?!? Mechanism: The highest bid wins and the price of the item is 0

Another simple mechanism: pay your bid t 1 =10 t 2 =12 t 3 =7 r 1 =9 r 2 =8 r 3 =6 Is it the right choice? Mechanism: The highest bid wins and the winner will pay his bid The winner is player 1 and he’ll pay 9 Player i may bid r i < t i (in this way he is guaranteed not to incur a negative utility) …and so the winner could be the wrong one… …it doesn’t work…

An elegant solution: Vickrey’s second price auction t 1 =10 t 2 =12 t 3 =7 r 1 =10 r 2 =12 r 3 =7 every player has convenience to declare the truth! (we prove it in the next slide) I know they are not lying Mechanism: The highest bid wins and the winner will pay the second highest bid The winner is player 2 and he’ll pay 10

Theorem In the Vickrey auction, for every player i, r i =t i is a dominant strategy proof Fix i, t i, r -i, and look at strategies for player i. Let R= max j  i {r j } Case: t i ≥ R Declaring r i =t i gives utility u i = t i -R ≥ 0 (player wins) declaring r i > t i ≥ R gives the same utility (player wins) declaring R < r i < t i gives the same utility (player wins) Case: t i < R Declaring r i =t i gives utility u i = 0 (player loses) declaring r i < t i < R gives the same utility (player loses) declaring r i > R > t i yields u i = t i -R < 0 (player wins) declaring r i < R ≤ t i yields u i =0 (player loses) declaring t i < r i < R gives the same utility (player loses)

Mechanism Design Problem: ingredients N agents; each agent i, i=1,..,N, has some private information t i  T i (actually, the only private info) called type Vickrey’s auction: the type is the painting value the agents have in mind, and so T i is the set of positive reals A set of feasible outcomes X Vickrey’s auction: X is the set of agents (bidders)

Mechanism Design Problem: ingredients (2) For each vector of types t=(t 1, t 2, …, t N ), and for each feasible outcome x  X, a social-choice function f(t,x) measures the quality of x as a function of t. This is the function that the mechanism aims to implement (i.e., it aims to select an outcome x* that minimizes/maximizes it), but the problem is that types are unknown! Vickrey’s auction: f(t,x) is the type associated with x (namely, a bidder x), and the objective is to maximize f, i.e., allocate to the bidder with highest type Each agent has a strategy space S i and performs a strategic action; we restrict ourself to direct revelation mechanisms, in which the action is reporting a value r i from the type space (with possibly r i  t i ), i.e., S i = T i Vickrey’s auction: the action is to bid a value r i

Mechanism Design Problem: ingredients (3) For each feasible outcome x  X, each agent makes a valuation v i (t i,x) (in terms of some common currency), expressing its preference about that output x Vickrey’s auction: if agent i wins the auction then its valuation is equal to its type t i, otherwise it is 0 For each feasible outcome x  X, each agent receives/gives (this depends on the problem) a payment p i (x) in terms of the common currency; payments are used by the system to incentive agents to be collaborative. Vickrey’s auction: if agent i wins the auction then he returns a payment equal to -r j, where r j is the second highest bid, otherwise it is 0 Then, for each feasible outcome x  X, the utility of agent i coming from outcome x will be: u i (t i,x) = p i (x) + v i (t i,x) Vickrey’s auction: if agent i wins the auction then its utility is equal to u i = -r j +t i ≥ 0, where r j is the second highest bid, otherwise it is u i = 0+0=0

Mechanism Design Problem: the goal Given all the above ingredients, design a mechanism M=, where: g(r) is an algorithm which computes an outcome x=x(r)  X as a function of the reported types r p(x) =(p 1,…,p N ) is a payment scheme w.r.t. outcome x specifying a payment value for each player which implements the social-choice function f in equilibrium (according to a given solution concept, e.g., dominant strategy equilibrium, Nash equilibrium, etc.), w.r.t. players’ utilities. (In other words, there exists a reported type vector r * for which the mechanism provides a solution x(r * ) and a payment scheme p(x(r * )) such that players’ utilities u i (t i, x(r * )) = p i (x(r * )) + v i (t i, x(r * )) are in equilibrium, and f(t, x(r * )) is optimal (either minimum or maximum))

Mechanism Design: a picture System Agent 1 Agent N “I propose to you the following mechanism M= ” p1p1 pNpN tNtN t 1t 1 r 1r 1 r Nr N Private “types” Reported types Payments Output which should implement the social choice function in equilibrium w.r.t. agents’ utilities Each agent reports strategically to maximize its well-being… …in response to a payment which is a function of the output!

Implementation with dominant strategies Def.: A mechanism is an implementation with dominant strategies if the s.c.f. f is implemented in dominant strategy equilibrium, i.e., there exists a reported type vector r * =(r 1 *, r 2 *, …, r N * ) such that for each agent i and for each reported type vector r =(r 1, r 2, …, r N ), it holds: u i (t i,x(r -i,r i * )) ≥ u i (t i,x(r)) where x(r -i,r i * )=x(r 1, …, r i-1, r i *, r i+1,…, r N ), and f(t,x(r*)) is optimized.

Strategy-Proof Mechanisms If truth telling is the dominant strategy in a mechanism then it is called Strategy-Proof or truthful  r * =t.  Agents report their true types instead of strategically manipulating it  The algorithm of the mechanism runs on the true input

Truthful Mechanism Design: Economics Issues QUESTION: How to design a truthful mechanism? Or, in other words: 1. How to design g(r), and 2. How to define the payment scheme in such a way that the underlying social- choice function is implemented truthfully? Under which conditions can this be done?

Utilitarian problems: A problem is utilitarian if its social-choice function is such that f(t,x) =  i v i (t i,x) notice: the auction problem is utilitarian, and so they are all problems where the s.c.f. is separately-additive w.r.t. agents’ valuations, as in many network optimization problems… Good news: for utilitarian problems there is a class of truthful mechanisms A prominent class of problems

Vickrey-Clarke-Groves (VCG) Mechanisms A VCG-mechanism is (the only) strategy-proof mechanism for utilitarian problems: Algorithm g(r) computes: x = arg max y  X  i v i (r i,y) Payment function for player i: p i (x) = h i (r -i ) +  j≠i v j (r j,x) where h i (r -i ) is an arbitrary function of the reported types of players other than player i. What about non-utilitarian problems? Strategy- proof mechanisms are known only when the type is a single parameter.

Theorem VCG-mechanisms are truthful for utilitarian problems proof Fix i, r -i, t i. Let ř=(r -i,t i ) and consider a strategy r i  t i x=g(r -i,t i ) =g(ř) x’=g(r -i,r i ) u i (t i,x) = u i (t i,x’) = [h i (r -i )+  j  i v j (r j,x)] + v i (t i,x) [h i (r -i )+  j  i v j (r j,x’)] + v i (t i,x’) = h i (r -i ) +  j v j (ř j,x) +  j v j (ř j,x’) but x is an optimal solution w.r.t. ř =(r -i,t i ), i.e., x = arg max y  X  i v i (ř,y)  j v j (ř j,x) ≥  j v j (ř j,x’) u i (t i,x)  u i (t i,x’).

How to define h i (r -i )? Remark: not all functions make sense. For instance, what happens in our example of the Vickrey auction if we set for every agent h i (r -i )=-1000 (notice this is independent of reported value r i of agent i, and so it obeys the definition)? Answer: It happens that players’ utility become negative; more precisely, the winner’s utility is u i (t i,x) = p i (x) + v i (t i,x) = h i (r -i ) +  j≠i v j (r j,x) + v i (t i,x) = = -988 while utility of losers is u i (t i,x) = p i (x) + v i (t i,x) = h i (r -i ) +  j≠i v j (r j,x) + v i (t i,x) = = -988  This is undesirable in reality, since with such perspective agents would not partecipate to the auction!

The Clarke payments This is a special VCG-mechanism in which h i (r - i )=-  j≠i v j (r j,x(r - i ))  p i (x) = -  j≠i v j (r j,x(r - i )) +  j≠i v j (r j,x) With Clarke payments, one can prove that agents’ utility are always non-negative  agents are interested in playing the game solution maximizing the sum of valuations when i doesn’t play

The Vickrey’s auction is a VCG mechanism with Clarke payments Observe that auctions are utilitarian problem. Then, the VCG-mechanism associated with the Vickrey’s auction is: x=arg max y  X  i v i (r i,y) …this is equivalent to allocate to the bidder with highest reported cost (in the end, the highest type, since it is strategy-proof) p i = -  j≠i v j (r j,x(r - i )) +  j≠i v j (r j,x) …this is equivalent to say that the winner pays the second highest offer, and the losers pay 0, respectively Remark: the difference between the second highest offer and the highest offer is unbounded (frugality issue)

VCG-Mechanisms: Advantages For System Designer: The goal, i.e., the optimization of the social-choice function, is achieved with certainty For Agents: Agents have truth telling as the dominant strategy, so they need not require any computational systems to deliberate about other agents strategies

VCG-Mechanisms: Disadvantages For System Designer: The payments may be sub-optimal (frugality) Apparently, the system may need to run the mechanism’s algorithm N+1 times: once with all agents (for computing the outcome x), and once for every agent (for the associated payment)  If the problem is hard to solve then the computational cost may be very heavy For Agents: Agents may not like to tell the truth to the system designer as it can be used in other ways.

Mechanism Design: Algorithmic Issues QUESTION: What is the time complexity of the mechanism? Or, in other words: What is the time complexity of g(r)? What is the time complexity to calculate the N payment functions? What does it happen if it is NP-hard to implement the underlying social-choice function? Question: What is the time complexity of the Vickrey auction? Answer: Θ(N), where N is the number of players. Indeed, it suffices to check all the offers, by keeping track of the lowest and second lowest one.

Algorithmic mechanism design and network protocols Large networks (e.g., Internet) are built and controlled by diverse and competitive entities: Entities own different components of the network and hold private information Entities are selfish and have different preferences  MD is a useful tool to design protocols working in such an environment, but time complexity is an important issue due to the massive network size

Algorithmic mechanism design for network optimization problems Simplifying the Internet model, we assume that each agent owns a single edge of a graph G=(V,E), and establishes the cost for using it  Classic optimization problems on G become mechanism design optimization problems in which the agent’s type is the weight of the edge! Many basic network design problems have been faced: shortest path (SP), single-source shortest paths tree (SPT), minimum spanning tree (MST), and many others

Some remarks In general, network optimization problems are minimization problems (the Vickrey’s auction was instead a maximization problem) However, we have: for each x  X, the valuation function v i (t i,x) represents a cost incurred by player i in the solution x (and so it is a negative function of its types) the social-choice function f(t,x) is negative (since it is the sum of negative functions), and so its maximization (as computed by the algorithm of the VCG-mechanism) corresponds to a minimization of the sum of absolute values of the valuation functions payments are from the mechanism to agents

Summary of main results Centralized algorithm Selfish-edge mechanism SPO(m+n log n) SPTO(m+n log n) MSTO(m  (m,n))  For all these basic problems, the time complexity of the mechanism equals that of the canonical centralized algorithm!

Exercise: redefine the Vickrey auction in the minimization version t 1 =10 t 2 =12 t 3 =7 r 1 =10 r 2 =12 r 3 =7 I want to allocate the job to the true cheapest machine Once again, the second price auction works: the cheapest bid wins and the winner will get the second cheapest bid The winner is machine 3 and it will receive 10 job to be allocated to machines t i : cost incurred by i if he does the job if machine i is selected and receives a payment of p its utility is p-t i