Selfridge-Conway Fair Division Procedure An Envy-Free Cake Division Procedure.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Arrow’s Conditions and Approval Voting
Advertisements

3.1 Fair Division: To divide S into shares (one for each player) in such a way that each player gets a fair share. Fair Division: To divide S into shares.
Homework p. 103 (2, 4, 8, 10, 11, 16, 20) 2. a) $ a) $ a) s2, s3 ($7 is fair) b) $4.80 b) $4.50 b) s1, s2 ($6 is fair) c) $6.40 c) $5.40.
Chapter 13: Fair Division Lesson Plan
Fair division. Fair division is the concept of dividing something among 2 or more people in such a way that each person finds his/her share to be fair.
Better Ways to Cut a Cake Steven Brams – NYU Mike Jones – Montclair State University Christian Klamler – Graz University Paris, October 2006.
Copyright © Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.
Online Cake Cutting Toby Walsh NICTA and UNSW Sydney, Australia.
§ 3.1 Fair-Division.
Dividing a Cake Fairly among n players Thomas Yeo
Chapter 13: Fair Division Lesson Plan
Lau Ting Sum Samson Suen Wai.  Discuss what fairness is  Describe some methods for fair division: 1. Divide-and-choose 2. Last Diminisher 3. Selfridge-Conway.
NOT JUST A CHILD’S PLAY CAKE CUTTING. How does one fairly divide goods among several people?
Fractions.
1-1 Copyright © 2015, 2010, 2007 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 18, Slide 1 Chapter 18 Confidence Intervals for Proportions.
By the end of the lesson, you will be able to…
Chapter 14: Fair Division
Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 19 Confidence Intervals for Proportions.
Introduction Solving inequalities is similar to solving equations. To find the solution to an inequality, use methods similar to those used in solving.
Chapter 19: Confidence Intervals for Proportions
Key Stone Problem… Key Stone Problem… next Set 22 © 2007 Herbert I. Gross.
Chapter 13: Weighted Voting Banzhaf Power Index Shapley-Shubik Power Index Equivalent Systems Examples.
Adding and Subtracting Fractions Do not train children to learning by force and harshness, but direct them to it by what amuses their minds, so that.
Chapter 14: Fair Division Part 4 – Divide and Choose for more than two players.
Copyright © Cengage Learning. All rights reserved. 4 Quadratic Functions.
Simplest Form Fraction Leonardo Estrella Assignment 7 Period 1.
Chapter 14: Fair Division Part 5 – Defining Fairness.
Ways to Check for Divisibility Dividing By 1 All numbers are divisible by 1.
Algebra Problems… Solutions Algebra Problems… Solutions © 2007 Herbert I. Gross Set 10 By Herbert I. Gross and Richard A. Medeiros next.
Fair Division Ch. 13 Finite Math. Fair division There are about 1.2 million divorces every year in the U.S. alone. International disputes redefine borders.
Chapter 3 Fair Division.
THE DOT Classical Voice Conservatory- Theory I. REVIEW: DOTTED HALF NOTE.
Ways to Check for Divisibility Dividing By 1 All numbers are divisible by 1.
Fair Division Lone Divider Method.
Adding and Subtracting Decimals © Math As A Second Language All Rights Reserved next #8 Taking the Fear out of Math 8.25 – 3.5.
Fair Shares.
Multiplication of Common Fractions © Math As A Second Language All Rights Reserved next #6 Taking the Fear out of Math 1 3 ×1 3 Applying.
§ 3.4 The Lone-Chooser Method
Excursions in Modern Mathematics, 7e: Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc. 3 The Mathematics of Sharing 3.1Fair-Division Games 3.2Two Players:
Fraction Review!. Just for fun…Which is your favorite fraction? 1.1/2 2.1/3 3.1/4 4.1/8.
Island Division: Lone-divider Method G G G G G G G G S S G S S S S S S S S S S ABC Gold123 Silver212 Total Fair division
Instructor: Shengyu Zhang 1. Resource allocation General goals:  Maximize social welfare.  Fairness.  Stability. 2.
Fair Division Algorithms
MTH 231 Section 4.1 Divisibility of Natural Numbers.
Our Lesson Simplify and Equivalent Fractions Confidential 2 Warm up 1) Is 8 a factor of 2832? Yes 2) List all factors of 49 1, 7 and 49 3) Solve 4x –
Ways to Check for Divisibility Dividing by 2 All even numbers are divisible by 2 Even numbers are numbers that end with either 2, 4, 6, 8, or 0.
Copyright © 2010, 2007, 2004 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 19 Confidence Intervals for Proportions.
Finally!!!.  Prime Number – a number that has only two factors, itself and is prime because the only numbers that will divide into it evenly are.
EXAMPLE 3 Write an indirect proof Write an indirect proof that an odd number is not divisible by 4. GIVEN : x is an odd number. PROVE : x is not divisible.
Y9 Transition KS3 to KS4 What you will be doing. Why the change? Over the past few years, the content of KS3 has been reduced, but that of KS4 has been.
Statistics 19 Confidence Intervals for Proportions.
DATA COLLECTION SURVEY CEREAL. QUESTION1 EXPLANATION My first question was to find out which brand of breakfast cereal was most liked from the people.
COUNTING Discrete Math Team KS MATEMATIKA DISKRIT (DISCRETE MATHEMATICS ) 1.
Confidence Intervals for Proportions
How can we tell which portions are the same amount?
Confidence Intervals for Proportions
Fair Division Lone Divider Method.
Intro to the Fair Allocation
Fair Division: the Continuous Case
Island Division: Lone-divider Method
Review for Fractions Test
Introduction Solving inequalities is similar to solving equations. To find the solution to an inequality, use methods similar to those used in solving.
Continuity Alex Karassev.
Equivalent Fractions One Whole 1.
Confidence Intervals for Proportions
Island Division: Lone-divider Method
(c) Project Maths Development Team 2011
Audience.
Audience.
Confidence Intervals for Proportions
Presentation transcript:

Selfridge-Conway Fair Division Procedure An Envy-Free Cake Division Procedure

The Selfridge-Conway Procedure We consider the case where there are exactly 3 participants. Suppose the participants are Alex (A), Barry (B) and Charles (C). Suppose A, B and C will divide a cake. Suppose all three have equal rights to a fair share of the cake. We follow the Selfridge-Conway procedure to divide the cake so that none of the participants will envy what the other receives.

The Selfridge-Conway Procedure - Outline The basic outline of the procedure is as follows: A will cut the cake into three pieces that he considers equally fair. B will have a chance to examine all three pieces and determine if there are at least two pieces that are tied for “best” – at least in B’s point of view. Assuming B agrees that there are at least two pieces tied for best, then C will be the first to choose a piece. C chooses any piece, then B choose one (there is still at least one remaining of those tied for best) and finally A chooses.

The Selfridge-Conway Procedure – Outline Continued However, it is possible that when B has the opportunity to examine all three pieces of the cake, B might decide that there is really only one piece that is the best (at least from B’s point of view). If C were given first choice, B might not get that best piece. Therefore, if B believes there is only one “best” piece, then B has the opportunity to trim that best piece to make sure that there are then at least two that would be tied for “best piece”. The trimmings that B cuts from the best piece are set aside for stage 2 of the process. (So there is a stage 2 only if B trims one piece). To finish stage 1, C will choose first from the 3 pieces (not counting the trimmings). Then B will choose. A requirement of the procedure is that if B did trim a piece, and if that piece is still available after C chooses, then B must take that trimmed piece. Finally, A will take the remaining piece.

The Selfridge-Conway Procedure – Outline Continued Stage 2 – assuming that B trimmed a piece Now there are two possibilities: 1. B trimmed a piece and C takes it. 2. B trimmed a piece, C does not take it, and therefore B must take it. In the first case – Suppose C takes the piece that B trimmed. Then B will divide up the trimmings and the order of selection is C chooses first, then A and finally B takes what remains. In the second case – Suppose B takes the trimmed piece. Then C will divide up the trimmings and the order of selection is B chooses first, then A and finally C takes what remains.

Envy-Free Selfridge-Conway cake division procedure is designed to be envy-free. This means when the division is completed, no participant will envy what another receives. To prove this is true, we show that no participant experiences envy in either of the two stages of the process and therefore at no time in the process.

Stage 1 A does not experience envy because A was able to divide the cake in a way that he thought all pieces were fair. B will not envy either of the others because B was able to make sure that there were at least two pieces that were tied for best, and B is able to choose one of those. C will not envy either of the others because C is able to choose first in stage 1

Stage 2 Stage 2 only occurs if B cut some trimmings from one of the pieces originally cut by A in stage 1. We show that no participant will envy what another receives in this stage. To be complete, we need to show that this is true in both of the two possible cases that can occur in stage 2

Stage 2 Consider A first: The two cases in this stage are: –1. If C took the trimmed piece in stage 1, then B will divide the trimmings and C selects first, then A and then B –2. If C did not take the trimmed piece in stage 1, then B must take it, so therefore C will divide the trimmings, B selects first, then A and finally B. To see A will not experience envy in this stage, we see that A will not experience envy in either case. First, A had cut all three pieces in stage 1 and therefore will not envy the one who took the trimmed piece. A would not have envied anyone who had gotten the whole piece, much less, that piece plus only some of what had been trimmed from that piece. Furthermore, A will select before the other participant that did not take the trimmed piece and so won’t envy that participant either.

Stage 2 Next, consider B: Again, the two cases in this stage are: –1. If C took the trimmed piece in stage 1, then B will divide the trimmings and C selects first, then A and then B –2. If C did not take the trimmed piece in stage 1, then B must take it, so therefore C will divide the trimmings, B selects first, then A and finally C. In case 1, B will not envy the others in this stage because B will divide the trimmings to ensure that each piece is sufficiently appealing. In this case B is dividing the trimmings but choosing last so must divide fairly so as not to envy what the others select. In case 2, B will not envy the others because B is selecting first from the trimmings.

Stage 2 Finally, consider C: For reference, the two cases in this stage are: –1. If C took the trimmed piece in stage 1, then B will divide the trimmings and C selects first, then A and then B –2. If C did not take the trimmed piece in stage 1, then B must take it, so therefore C will divide the trimmings, B selects first, then A and finally C. The argument is equivalent to what was just presented for B In case 1, C will not envy the others because C can choose first. In case 2, C will have the opportunity to divide the trimmings to ensure that each piece is equally attractive. C must do this because C will select last in this stage. So C divides the trimmings so that each piece is equally good and will not envy what the others choose.