1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Option Valuation The Black-Scholes-Merton Option Pricing Model
Advertisements

Chapter 12: Basic option theory
CHAPTER NINETEEN OPTIONS. TYPES OF OPTION CONTRACTS n WHAT IS AN OPTION? Definition: a type of contract between two investors where one grants the other.
Futures Options Chapter 16 1 Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 7th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2008.
Options on stock indices, currencies, and futures.
Valuation of Financial Options Ahmad Alanani Canadian Undergraduate Mathematics Conference 2005.
Fi8000 Option Valuation II Milind Shrikhande. Valuation of Options ☺Arbitrage Restrictions on the Values of Options ☺Quantitative Pricing Models ☺Binomial.
© Paul Koch 1-1 Chapter 10. Basic Properties of Options I. Notation and Assumptions: A. Notation: S:current stock price; K:exercise price of option; T:time.
Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6 th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull The Black-Scholes- Merton Model Chapter 13.
Chapter 14 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model
Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model.
By: Piet Nova The Binomial Tree Model.  Important problem in financial markets today  Computation of a particular integral  Methods of valuation 
Options Week 7. What is a derivative asset? Any asset that “derives” its value from another underlying asset is called a derivative asset. The underlying.
Basic Numerical Procedures Chapter 19 1 資管所 柯婷瑱 2009/07/17.
Spreads  A spread is a combination of a put and a call with different exercise prices.  Suppose that an investor buys simultaneously a 3-month put option.
1 16-Option Valuation. 2 Pricing Options Simple example of no arbitrage pricing: Stock with known price: S 0 =$3 Consider a derivative contract on S:
4.1 Option Prices: numerical approach Lecture Pricing: 1.Binomial Trees.
Financial options1 From financial options to real options 2. Financial options Prof. André Farber Solvay Business School ESCP March 10,2000.
Ch. 19 J. Hull, Options, Futures and Other Derivatives Zvi Wiener Framework for pricing derivatives.
Pricing an Option The Binomial Tree. Review of last class Use of arbitrage pricing: if two portfolios give the same payoff at some future date, then they.
Drake DRAKE UNIVERSITY Fin 288 Valuing Options Using Binomial Trees.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2002 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. 8-0 Finance Chapter Eight Properties of Stock Options.
5.1 Option pricing: pre-analytics Lecture Notation c : European call option price p :European put option price S 0 :Stock price today X :Strike.
Chapter 14 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 8th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull
Zvi WienerContTimeFin - 9 slide 1 Financial Engineering Risk Neutral Pricing Zvi Wiener tel:
Estimation and Hypothesis Testing. The Investment Decision What would you like to know? What will be the return on my investment? Not possible PDF for.
Valuing Stock Options:The Black-Scholes Model
11.1 Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th Edition © 1999 by John C. Hull The Black-Scholes Model Chapter 11.
1 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model MGT 821/ECON 873 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model.
Put/Call Parity and Binomial Model (McDonald, Chapters 3, 5, 10)
Measuring Returns Converting Dollar Returns to Percentage Returns
18.1 Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 5th edition © 2002 by John C. Hull Numerical Procedures Chapter 18.
Option Valuation. Intrinsic value - profit that could be made if the option was immediately exercised –Call: stock price - exercise price –Put: exercise.
The Pricing of Stock Options Using Black- Scholes Chapter 12.
Properties of Stock Options
Introduction Terminology Valuation-SimpleValuation-ActualSensitivity What is a financial option? It is the right, but not the obligation, to buy (in the.
Properties of Stock Option Prices Chapter 9
Chapter 3 Discrete Time and State Models. Discount Functions.
Chapter 10: Options Markets Tuesday March 22, 2011 By Josh Pickrell.
INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS Copyright © 2011 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin CHAPTER 18 Option Valuation.
Black Scholes Option Pricing Model Finance (Derivative Securities) 312 Tuesday, 10 October 2006 Readings: Chapter 12.
1 Derivatives & Risk Management: Part II Models, valuation and risk management.
Computational Finance Lecture 2 Markets and Products.
Valuing Stock Options: The Black- Scholes Model Chapter 11.
Properties of Stock Option Prices Chapter 9
Fundamentals of Futures and Options Markets, 7th Ed, Ch 13, Copyright © John C. Hull 2010 Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model Chapter.
Copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. All rights reserved.1 Chapter 4: Option Pricing Models: The Binomial Model Models are like cars: you can have the best.
Introduction Finance is sometimes called “the study of arbitrage”
© Prentice Hall, Corporate Financial Management 3e Emery Finnerty Stowe Derivatives Applications.
Index, Currency and Futures Options Finance (Derivative Securities) 312 Tuesday, 24 October 2006 Readings: Chapters 13 & 14.
Option Valuation.
13.1 Valuing Stock Options : The Black-Scholes-Merton Model Chapter 13.
The Black-Scholes-Merton Model Chapter 13 Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 7th International Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull
The Black-Scholes-Merton Model Chapter B-S-M model is used to determine the option price of any underlying stock. They believed that stock follow.
Chapter 16 Option Valuation Copyright © 2010 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
Valuing Stock Options:The Black-Scholes Model
CHAPTER NINETEEN OPTIONS. TYPES OF OPTION CONTRACTS n WHAT IS AN OPTION? Definition: a type of contract between two investors where one grants the other.
Chapter 14 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model 1. The Stock Price Assumption Consider a stock whose price is S In a short period of time of length  t, the.
Structural Models. 2 Source: Moody’s-KMV What do we learn from these plots? The volatility of a firm’s assets is a major determinant of its.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc., publishing as Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.10-1 The Binomial Solution How do we find a replicating portfolio consisting.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc., publishing as Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.10-1 Properties of Option Prices (cont’d) Early exercise for American.
Introduction to Options. Option – Definition An option is a contract that gives the holder the right but not the obligation to buy or sell a defined asset.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc., publishing as Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.10-1 American Options The value of the option if it is left “alive” (i.e.,
Chapter 14 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model
The Black-Scholes-Merton Model
Chapter 15 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model
Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model
Chapter 15 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model
Valuing Stock Options:The Black-Scholes Model
Presentation transcript:

1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II

2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call option, the option holder receives the stock and thus receives dividends, pays the strike price prior to expiration (this has an interest cost), loses the insurance/flexibility implicit in the call.

3 Understanding Early Exercise By exercising a Put option, the option holder receives the strike price and thus collects interest on it going forward, gives the stock away and thus stops receiving dividends loses the insurance/flexibility implicit in the put.

4 Call Option Without Dividends Put-Call Parity says: C=P+S-Ke -rT Since P>0, C>S-Ke -rT And since K>Ke -rT, we have C>S-K Therefore the Call price C is always greater than the intrinsic value S-K (which is what you would get if you exercised). Thus it is never optimal to exercise an American Call option on a non-dividend paying stock!!!

5 Call Option With Dividends Put-Call Parity says: C=P+S-Ke -rT -D (where D is the present value of all future dividends to be received) So C = S-K + P + K-Ke -rT – D Thus C = S-K + P + K(1-e -rT ) – D Therefore, when S is high and thus P close to zero, the Call price C can be greater or lower than the intrinsic value S-K (which is what you would get if you exercised) depending on whether K(1-e -rT ) is greater or lower than D, i.e. whether the interest saved by delaying the payment K is greater or lower than the lost dividends. Thus it can be optimal to exercise an American Call option on a dividend-paying stock.

6 Put Option Without Dividends Put-Call Parity says: P=C+Ke -rT -S Thus P = K-S + C-K(1-e -rT ) Therefore the Put price P can be greater or lower than the intrinsic value K-S depending on whether C is greater or lower than K(1-e -rT ). Thus even on a non-dividend paying stock, it may be optimal to exercise a Put option ! (It usually happens for low values of S, when C is very small)

7 Understanding Risk-Neutral Pricing A risk-neutral investor is indifferent between a sure thing and a risky bet with an expected payoff equal to the value of the sure thing. p* is the risk-neutral probability that the stock price will go up. The option pricing formula can be said to price options as if investors are risk-neutral. Note that we are not assuming that investors are actually risk-neutral, and that risky assets are actually expected to earn the risk-free rate of return.

8 Pricing an option using risk-neutral probabilities Consider a world populated by risk-neutral investors. Investors would only be concerned with expected returns, and not about the level of risk. Hence investors would not “charge” or require a premium for risky securities. Therefore risky securities would have the same expected rate of return as riskless securities. In other words, every security is returning the risk-free rate.

9 Fine point to think about: Now consider the following scenario: suppose a risky security is expected to achieve great growth and great future profits. (You can even assume that the security actually delivers on its promises later, if you wish.) Even though risk-neutral investors might only usually require the risk-free rate of return, doesn’t this mean that the expected rate of return on this security will be much higher than the risk-free rate? And if yes, doesn’t that invalidate what we’ve just discussed? WHAT IS GOING ON HERE ? ANY POSSIBLE RECONCILIATION OF THE TWO IDEAS?

10 Pricing an option using risk-neutral probabilities If the stock is thus expected to earn the risk-free rate r and pays out a continuous dividend yield , then the risk-neutral probability p* that the stock will go up must satisfy: p*u e  h S + (1 – p*)d e  h S = e rh S Solving for p* gives us

11 Pricing an option using real probabilities Is option pricing consistent with standard discounted cash flow calculations? Yes. However, discounted cash flow is not used in practice to price options. This is because it is necessary to compute the option price in order to compute the correct discount rate.

12 Pricing an option using real probabilities Suppose that the continuously compounded expected return on the stock is  and that the stock does not pay dividends. If p is the true probability of the stock going up, p must be consistent with u, d, and  : puS + (1 – p)dS = e  h S (11.3) Solving for p gives us (11.4)

13 Pricing an option using real probabilities Using p, the actual expected payoff to the option one period hence is (11.5) At what rate do we discount this expected payoff? It is not correct to discount the option at the expected return on the stock, , because the option is equivalent to a leveraged investment in the stock and hence is riskier than the stock.

14 Pricing an option using real probabilities Let us denote the appropriate per-period discount rate for the option as . Since an option is equivalent to holding a portfolio consisting of  shares of stock and B bonds, the expected return on this portfolio is (11.6) And since an option is equivalent to holding a portfolio consisting of  shares of stock and B bonds, the denominator is indeed the option price. This confirms that in order to compute the discount rate , one needs to have the price of the option first.

15 Pricing an option using real probabilities We can nevertheless now compute the option price as the expected option payoff, discounted at the appropriate discount rate, given by equation (11.6). We thus need to compute: (11.7) It turns out that this gives us the same option price as performing the risk-neutral calculation.

16 Application: one-period example Assume the following information:  =15%, S=$41, K=$40, S=0.30, r=8%, T=1, h=1, and  =0. The “up-price” for the stock is $ and the “down-price” is $ Compute the price of a European call option by using: True probabilities Risk-neutral probabilities Are the results identical?

17 Application: one-period example The true up probability is (with u = / 41 = and d = / 41 = ): p = [e ] / [ ] = The expected option payoff therefore is: ($19.954) + ( )($0) = $ We now need to compute the discount rate  in order to get the option price today.

18 Application: one-period example For , we need the values of  and B.  = ( )/( ) = B is the present value of loan needed to match cash flows of  S and option (pick the case where stock goes down, since easier – but works for both): B = -e [(0.738)(32.903)-0] = - $ We thus have: Or  = ln(1.386) = 32.64%

19 Application: one-period example Finally, armed with , we can compute the discounted expected option value as: C = e (10.867) = $ 7.839

20 Application: one-period example The risk-neutral probability of the stock going up is: p* = [e ] / [ ] = The call option price therefore is: C = e [(0.4256)(19.954)+( )(0)] = $ This is exactly the price we obtained before.

21 The Binomial Tree and Lognormality The usefulness of the binomial pricing model hinges on the binomial tree providing a reasonable representation of the stock price distribution. The binomial tree approximates a lognormal distribution.

22 The random walk model It is often said that stock prices follow a random walk. Imagine that we flip a coin repeatedly. Let the random variable Y denote the outcome of the flip. If the coin lands displaying a head, Y = 1; otherwise, Y = – 1. If the probability of a head is 50%, we say the coin is fair. After n flips, with the i th flip denoted Y i, the cumulative total, Z n, is (11.8) It turns out that the more times we flip, on average the farther we will move from where we started.

23 The random walk model We can represent the process followed by Z n in term of the change in Z n : Z n – Z n-1 = Y n or Heads: Z n – Z n-1 = +1 Tails: Z n – Z n-1 = –1

24 The random walk model A random walk, where with heads, the change in Z is 1, and with tails, the change in Z is – 1:

25 The random walk model The idea that asset prices should follow a random walk was articulated in Samuelson (1965). In efficient markets, an asset price should reflect all available information. In response to new information the price is equally likely to move up or down, as with the coin flip. The price after a period of time is the initial price plus the cumulative up and down movements due to new information.

26 Modeling prices as a random walk. The above description of a random walk is not a satisfactory description of stock price movements. There are at least three problems with this model: 1. If by chance we get enough cumulative down movements, the stock price will become negative. 2. The magnitude of the move ($1) should depend upon how quickly the coin flips occur and the level of the stock price. 3. The stock, on average, should have a positive return. However, the random walk model taken literally does not permit this. The binomial model is a variant of the random walk model that solves all of these problems.

27 Continuously compounded returns The binomial model assumes that continuously compounded returns are a random walk. Some important properties of continuously compounded returns: The logarithmic function computes returns from prices. The exponential function computes prices from returns. Continuously compounded returns are additive. Continuously compounded returns can be less than –100%.

28 The standard deviation of returns Suppose the continuously compounded return over month i is r monthly, i. The annual return is The variance of the annual return is (11.14)

29 The standard deviation of returns Suppose that returns are uncorrelated over time and that each month has the same variance of returns. Then from equation (11.14) we have  2 = 12   2 monthly, where  2 is the annual variance. The annual standard deviation is If we split the year into n periods of length h (so that h = 1/n), the standard deviation over the period of length h is (11.15)

30 The binomial model The binomial model is Taking logs, we obtain (11.16) Since ln (S t+h /S t ) is the continuously compounded return from t to t+h, the binomial model is simply a particular way to model the continuously compounded return. That return has two parts, one of which is certain, (r–  )h, and the other of which is uncertain,  h.

31 The binomial model Equation (11.6) solves the three problems in the random walk: 1. The stock price cannot become negative. 2. As h gets smaller, up and down moves get smaller. 3. There is a (r –  )h term, and we can choose the probability of an up move, so we can guarantee that the expected change in the stock price is positive.

32 Lognormality and the binomial model The binomial tree approximates a lognormal distribution, which is commonly used to model stock prices. The lognormal distribution is the probability distribution that arises from the assumption that continuously compounded returns on the stock are normally distributed. With the lognormal distribution, the stock price is positive, and the distribution is skewed to the right, that is, there is a chance of extremely high stock prices.

33 Lognormality and the binomial model The binomial model implicitly assigns probabilities to the various nodes.

34 Lognormality and the binomial model The following information is used to draw the graphs on the next slides: initial stock price S = 100, volatility=30%, E(R S )=10%, T=1year, and we divide the 1-year period into 25 periods (h=1/25). Note that n=25. The probability of the stock going up from one period to the next is p=[e Rh -d]/[u-d] Use u=e  sqrt(h) and d=e  sqrt(h). Proba of reaching i th node =(number of ways to reach i th node) p n-i (1-p) i where number of ways to reach i th node = n!/[(n-i)!i!]

35 Lognormality and the binomial model The following graph compares the probability distribution for a 25-period binomial tree with the corresponding lognormal distribution:

36 Lognormality and the binomial model

37 Lognormality and the binomial model: Exercise Use the following information to draw a probability distribution graph: initial stock price S = 100, volatility=30%, E(R S )=10%, T=1year, and we divide the 1-year period into 3 periods (h=1/3). Note that n=3. The probability of the stock going up from one period to the next is p=[e Rh -d]/[u-d] Use u=e  sqrt(h) and d=e  sqrt(h). Proba of reaching i th node =(number of ways to reach i th node) x p n-i (1-p) i where number of ways to reach i th node = n!/[(n-i)!i!]

38 Lognormality and the binomial model: Solution

39 Alternative binomial trees There are other ways besides equation (11.6) to construct a binomial tree that approximates a lognormal distribution. An acceptable tree must match the standard deviation of the continuously compounded return on the asset and must generate an appropriate distribution as h  0. Different methods of constructing the binomial tree will result in different u and d stock movements. No matter how we construct the tree, to determine the risk-neutral probability, we use and to determine the option value, we use C = e –rh [p* C u + (1 – p*) C d ]

40 Alternative binomial trees The Cox-Ross-Rubinstein binomial tree: The tree is constructed as (11.18) A problem with this approach is that if h is large or  is small, it is possible that e rh > e  h. In this case, the binomial tree violates the restriction of u > e (r–  )h > d. In practice, h is usually small, so the above problem does not occur.

41 Alternative binomial trees The lognormal tree: The tree is constructed as (11.19) Although the three different binomial models give different option prices for finite n, as n   all three binomial trees approach the same price.

42 Is the binomial model realistic? The binomial model is a form of the random walk model, adapted to modeling stock prices. The lognormal random walk model here assumes that volatility is constant, “large” stock price movements do not occur, returns are independent over time. All of these assumptions appear to be violated in the data.

43 Estimated Volatility We need to decide what value to assign to , which we cannot observe directly. One possibility is to measure  by computing the standard deviation of continuously compounded historical returns. Volatility computed from historical stock returns is historical volatility. This is a reasonable way to estimate volatility when continuously compounded returns are independent and identically distributed. If returns are not independent—as with some commodities— volatility estimation becomes more complicated.

44 Stock Paying Discrete Dividends Suppose that a dividend will be paid between times t and t+h and that its future value at time t+h is D. The time t forward price for delivery at t+h is F t,t+h = S t e rh – D Since the stock price at time t+h will be ex-dividend, we create the up and down moves based on the ex-dividend stock price: (11.20)

45 Stock Paying Discrete Dividends When a dividend is paid, we have to account for the fact that the stock earns the dividend. (S u t + D)  + e rh B = C u (S d t + D)  + e rh B = C d The solution is Because the dividend is known, we decrease the bond position by the PV of the certain dividend.

46 Problems with the discrete dividend tree 1. The conceptual problem with equation (11.20) is that the stock price could in principle become negative if there have been large downward moves in the stock prior to the dividend. 2. The practical problem is that the tree does not completely recombine after a discrete dividend. The following tree, where a $5 dividend is paid between periods 1 and 2, demonstrates that with a discrete dividend, the order of up and down movements affects the price. In the third binomial period, there are six rather than four possible stock prices.

47 Problems with the discrete dividend tree

48 A binomial tree using the prepaid forward Hull (1997) presents a method of constructing a tree for a dividend-paying stock that solves both problems. If we know for certain that a stock will pay a fixed dividend, then we can view the stock price as being the sum of two components: 1. the dividend, which is like a zero-coupon bond with zero volatility, and 2. the PV of the ex-dividend value of the stock, i.e., the prepaid forward price.

49 A binomial tree using the prepaid forward Suppose we know that a stock will pay a dividend D at time T D < T, where T is the expiration date of the option. We base stock price movements on the prepaid forward price The one-period forward price for the prepaid forward is This gives us up and down movements of However, the actual stock price at each node is given by

50 A binomial tree using the prepaid forward A binomial tree constructed using the prepaid-forward method: