Tastes/Preferences Indifference Curves.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Preferences. Rationality in Economics u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker always chooses its most preferred alternative from its set of available.
Advertisements

Choice.
Chapter Four Utility. Preferences - A Reminder u x y: x is preferred strictly to y.  x  y: x and y are equally preferred. u x y: x is preferred at least.
Chapter 3 Preferences Choose the “best” thing one can “afford” Start with consumption bundles (a complete list of the goods that is involved in consumer’s.
Chapter 3. * Prerequisite: A binary relation R on X is said to be Complete if xRy or yRx for any pair of x and y in X; Reflexive if xRx for any x in X;
Utilities Indifference curves
UNIT I: Theory of the Consumer
Combinations (X1, Y1) and (X2, Y2) provide the same level of utility
Intermediate Microeconomics
Chapter Five Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those.
PREFERENCES AND UTILITY
Axioms of Rational Choice
Utility.
Chapter Three Preferences.
Chapter Seven Revealed Preference. Revealed Preference Analysis u Suppose we observe the demands (consumption choices) that a consumer makes for different.
Axioms of Rational Choice
Chapter Three Preferences. Rationality in Economics u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker always chooses its most preferred alternative from its set.
Utility.
Chapter Three Preferences. Rationality in Economics u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker always chooses its most preferred alternative from its set.
Preferences. Preference Relation The consumer strictly prefers bundle X to bundle Y: The consumer is indifferent between X and Y:
1 Chapter 3 PREFERENCES AND UTILITY Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
1 Intermediate Microeconomics Preferences. 2 Consumer Behavior Budget Set organizes information about possible choices available to a given consumer.
Chapter Three Preferences. Rationality in Economics u Behavioral Postulate: An economic decisionmaker always chooses her most preferred alternative from.
Chapter Three Preferences 偏好. Structure 3.1 Preference relations 3.2 Assumptions about preferences 3.3 Graphical representation of preferences—indifference.
Consumer Theory Introduction Budget Set/line Study of Preferences Maximizing Utility.
Chapter 5 Choice.
The Theory of Individual Behavior. Overview I. Consumer Behavior n Indifference Curve Analysis n Consumer Preference Ordering II. Constraints n The Budget.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 4 Utility. © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 2 Preferences - A Reminder u x y: x is preferred strictly to y.  x.
Rationality in Economics Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker always chooses its most preferred alternative from its set of available alternatives. So.
Course: Microeconomics Text: Varian’s Intermediate Microeconomics 1.
Chapter 3: Consumer Preferences and the Concept of Utility
Econ 201 May 7, 2009 Indifference Curves Budget Lines and Demand Curves 1.
Fundamentals of Microeconomics
Consumer Preferences and the Concept of Utility
1 Chapter 3 PREFERENCES AND UTILITY Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
Chapter 3 Preferences.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 3 Preferences.
1 Preferences Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 – Spring 2009.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 4 Utility. © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 2 Preferences - A Reminder u x y: x is preferred strictly to y.  x.
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada 2/1 Chapter 2 A Theory of Preferences.
Chapter Three Preferences. u Consumer behavior is best understood in three distinct steps: 1. Consumer Preferences: The first step is to find a practical.
CHAPTER 2 UTILITY AND CHOICE. Objective Build a model to understand how a consumer makes decisions under scarcity. To understand his choice we need to.
L03 Utility. Big picture u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from the set of affordable alternatives. u Budget.
Budgetary and Other Constraints on Choice
L04 Choice. Big picture u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from the set of affordable alternatives. u Budget.
L02 Preferences. Rationality in Economics u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from the set of affordable alternatives.
Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 – Spring 2009
L03 Utility. Quiz How much do you like microeconomics A: I love it (unconditionally) B: I cannot live without it C: I would die for it D: All of the above.
Recall: Consumer behavior Why are we interested? –New good in the market. What price should be charged? How much more for a premium brand? –Subsidy program:
 This will explain how consumers allocate their income over many goods.  This looks at individual’s decision making when faced with limited income and.
UTILITY. Chapter 11 What is Utility? A way of representing preferences Utility is not money (but it is a useful analogy) Typical relationship between.
PREFERENCES. Rationality in Economics Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker always chooses its most preferred alternative from its set of available alternatives.
L02 Preferences.
Chapter 3 Preferences Intermediate Microeconomics:
Choice.
3 Preferences.
Chapter Three Preferences.
PREFERENCES.
L02 Preferences.
L03 Utility.
L03 Utility.
L02 Preferences.
Choice.
Chapter 3 Preferences.
Chapter 3 Preferences Key Concept: characterize preferences by a binary comparison measuring at least as good as. Derive the indifference curves for a.
L02 Preferences.
L02 Preferences.
L02 Preferences.
Chapter 2 A Theory of Preferences
Presentation transcript:

Tastes/Preferences Indifference Curves

Rationality in Economics Rationality Behavioral Postulate: “Rational Economic Man” The decision-maker chooses the most preferred bundle from the set of available bundles. We must model: Set of available bundles; and The decision-maker’s preferences.

PREFERENCES  Weakly preferred ~ Indifferent  Strictly preferred X is the bundle (x1,x2) and Y is the bundle (y1,y2)  Weakly preferred Bundle X is as least as good as bundle Y (X  Y) ~ Indifferent Bundle X is equivalent to bundle Y (X ~ Y)  Strictly preferred Bundle X is preferred to bundle Y (X > Y)

PREFERENCES: Axioms 1. Completeness {A  B or B  A or A ~ B} Any two bundles can be compared. 2. Reflexive {A  A } Any bundle is at least as good as itself. 3. Transitivity {If A  B and B  C then A  C} Non-satiation assumption (I.e. goods, not bads)

Axioms Transitivity: If x is at least as preferred as y, and y is at least as preferred as z, then x is at least as preferred as z; i.e. x y and y z x z. ~ f ~ f ~ f

PREFERENCES A>B B>C C>A Intransitivity? Starting at C Willing to pay to get to B Willing to pay to get to A Willing to pay to get to C Willing to pay to get to B … “Money Pump” Argument (I.e. proof by contradiction)

INDIFFERENCE CURVES x2 x1 x2 x3 I(x’) x1 ~ x2 ~ x3 x1 The indifference curve through any particular consumption bundle consists of all bundles of products that leave the consumer indifferent to the given bundle. x2 x1 x2 I(x’) x3 x1 ~ x2 ~ x3 x1

INDIFFERENCE CURVES x2 z x y p p x z y x1

INDIFFERENCE CURVES I1 All bundles in I1 are strictly preferred to all in I2. x2 x z I2 All bundles in I2 are strictly preferred to all in I3. y I3 x1

INDIFFERENCE CURVES x2 x I(x’) x1 WP(x), the set of bundles weakly preferred to x. x I(x’) x1

INTERSECTING INDIFFERENCE CURVES? From I1, x ~ y From I2, x ~ z Therefore y ~ z? I2 x2 I1 x y z x1

INTERSECTING INDIFFERENCE CURVES? But from I1 and I2 we see y > z. There is a contradiction. x2 I1 x y z x1

SLOPES OF INDIFFERENCE CURVES? When more of a product is always preferred, the product is a good. If every product is a good then indifference curves are negatively sloped.

SLOPES OF INDIFFERENCE CURVES? Good 2 Two “goods” therefore a negatively sloped indifference curve. Better Worse Good 1

SLOPES OF INDIFFERENCE CURVES? If less of a product is always preferred then the product is a “bad”.

SLOPES OF INDIFFERENCE CURVES? Good 2 One “good” and one “bad” therefore a positively sloped indifference curve. Better Worse Bad 1

PERFECT SUBSITIUTES If a consumer always regards units of products 1 and 2 as equivalent, then the products are perfect substitutes and only the total amount of the two products matters.

PERFECT SUBSITIUTES x2 Slopes are constant at - 1. Examples? I2 I1 x1

PERFECT COMPLEMENTS If a consumer always consumes products 1 and 2 in fixed proportion (e.g. one-to-one), then the products are perfect complements and only the number of pairs of units of the two products matters.

PERFECT COMPLEMENTS x2 45o 9 5 I1 x1 5 9 Example: Each of (5,5), (5,9) and (9,5) is equally preferred 9 5 I1 x1 5 9

PERFECT COMPLEMENTS x2 45o 9 I2 5 I1 x1 5 9 Each of (5,5), (5,9) and (9,5) is less preferred than the bundle (9,9). 9 I2 5 I1 x1 5 9

WELL BEHAVED PREFERENCES A preference relation is “well-behaved” if it is monotonic and convex. Monotonicity: More of any product is always preferred (i.e. every product is a good, no satiation). Convexity: Mixtures of bundles are (at least weakly) preferred to the bundles themselves. For example, the 50-50 mixture of the bundles x and y is z = (0.5)x + (0.5)y. z is at least as preferred as x or y.

WELL BEHAVED PREFERENCES Monotonicity more of either product is better indifference curves have negative slopes Convexity averages are preferred to extremes slopes get flatter as you move further to the right (not obvious yet)

WELL BEHAVED PREFERENCES Convexity z is strictly preferred to both x and y x+y x2+y2 z = 2 2 y y2 x1 x1+y1 y1 2

WELL BEHAVED PREFERENCES Convexity z =(tx1+(1-t)y1, tx2+(1-t)y2) is preferred to x and y for all 0 < t < 1. y y2 x1 y1

WELL BEHAVED PREFERENCES Convexity. Preferences are strictly convex when all mixtures z are strictly preferred to their component bundles x and y. x x2 z y y2 x1 y1

WELL BEHAVED PREFERENCES Weak Convexity Preferences are weakly convex if at least one mixture z is equally preferred to a component bundle, e.g. perfect substitutes. x’ z’ x z y y’

NON-CONVEX PREFERENCES Better The mixture z is less preferred than x or y. Examples? z y2 x1 y1

NON CONVEX PREFERENCES Better The mixture z is less preferred than x or y z y2 x1 y1

SLOPES OF INDIFFERENCE CURVES The slope of an indifference curve is referred to as the marginal rate-of-substitution (MRS). How can a MRS be calculated?

MARGINAL RATE OF SUBSITITUTION (MRS) x2 MRS at x* is the slope of the indifference curve at x* x* x1

MRS at x* is lim {Dx2/Dx1} as Dx1  0 = dx2/dx1 at x*

MRS MRS is the amount of product 2 an individual is willing to exchange for an extra unit of product 1 x2 x* dx2 dx1 x1

MRS Two “goods” have a negatively sloped indifference curve Good 2 Better  MRS < 0 Worse Good 1

MRS Good 2 One “good” and one “bad” therefore a positively sloped indifference curve Better  MRS > 0 Worse Bad 1

MRS MRS decreases (in absolute terms) as x1 increases if and only if preferences are strictly convex. Intuition? Good 2 MRS = (-) 5 MRS = (-) 0.5 Good 1

MRS x2 If MRS increases (in absolute terms) as x1 increases  non-convex preferences MRS = (-) 0.5 MRS = (-) 5 x1

MRS MRS is not always decreasing as x1 increases x2 - non- convex preferences. x2 MRS = - 1 MRS = - 0.5 MRS = - 2 x1