Competition Policy in Two-Sided Markets - Some brief remarks Dr Amelia Fletcher Chief Economist Office of Fair Trading LEAR Conference 7th June 2007 NB.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Economics Unit Four PRICES AND MARKETS. PRICES What is the role of the price system? The price system is the language that guides producers and consumers.
Advertisements

Why is cost oriented pricing important Consumer Access to Services Efficient Network Access for Competitors and Service Providers Sustainable Market Expansion.
Gender Perspectives in Introduction to Tariffs Gender Module #5 ITU Workshops on Sustainability in Telecommunication Through Gender & Social Equality.
Price discrimination Definition: charging different prices for the same product to different consumers Examples –senior citizen discounts –airfares: business.
Economics: Principles in Action
Copyright©2004 South-Western 15 Monopoly. Copyright © 2004 South-Western While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker.
22 August 2012 Regulating for productive efficiency – an assessment of the regulatory framework faced by Eskom Presented at the South African Economic.
12 Prepared by: Fernando Quijano and Yvonn Quijano © 2004 Prentice Hall Business PublishingPrinciples of Economics, 7/eKarl Case, Ray Fair Monopoly.
The Role and Regulation of Interchange Fees in European Payments Cards The Role and Regulation of Interchange Fees in European Payments Cards Wilko Bolt.
A SSNIP Test for Two-Sided Markets: some theoretical considerations Lapo Filistrucchi Tilburg University, CentER & TILEC & Univeristy of Siena “The Economics.
Competition Policy Market definition and the Assesment of Market Power.
Chapter 7, Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets
Monopoly - Characteristics
Departures from perfect competition
Monopoly While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker. A firm is considered a monopoly if it is the sole seller of.
I. A Simple Model. Players: Sellers, I and E, and a consumer Period 1: Seller I and the buyer can make an exclusive contract. Period 2: Seller E decides.
7.1 Perfect Competition After studying this section, you will be able to: Describe the four conditions that are in place in a perfectly competitive market.
Examination of the dynamics of perfect markets with the aid of cost and revenue curves. Perfect competition Individual business and industry Market structure.
Economics: Principles in Action
MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION
Imperfect Competition and Market Power: Core Concepts Defining Industry Boundaries Barriers to Entry Price: The Fourth Decision Variable Price and Output.
Oligopoly in Practice. 1. Legal Frame work ▫Antitrust policy  This involves the efforts by the government to prevent oligopolistic industries from becoming.
The Marketing Mix Price
Monopolies & Regulation Chapter 24 & 26. Monopoly  A firm that produces the entire market supply of a particular good or service. Chapter 24 & 26 2.
Market Power: Monopoly
Perfect Competition, Monopoly, Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition in Seller Markers Allan Fels, Professor of Government The Australia and New Zealand.
Economics Chapter 7 Market Structures
PERFECT COMPETITION 7.1.
The Four Conditions for Perfect Competition
More Economics of Competition and Competitive Strategies
Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly 1 PUBLIC POLICY AND COMPETITION  Government Anti-Trust Policy Schizophrenic government policy toward monopolistic.
Copyright©2004 South-Western Monopoly. Copyright © 2004 South-Western While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker.
The CFI Microsoft Judgment: Abuse 1 - Interoperability Dr Amelia Fletcher Chief Economist Office of Fair Trading NB The views expressed here are my own,
Are Monopolies Desirable?
1 Monopoly and Antitrust Policy Chapter IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND MARKET POWER imperfectly competitive industry An industry in which single firms.
Chapter 14: Monopoly Economics In this chapter, you will :  Learn why some markets have one seller  Analyze how a monopolist determines the quantity.
MONOPOLY Why do monopolies arise? Why is MR < P for a monopolist?
Monopoly. Learning Objectives: What is a Monopoly? What are the sources of Monopoly power? How does a Monopoly choose how much to produce and what price.
Price determined by S & D Price taker Won’t charge higher or lower than market price Horizontal (perfectly elastic) at market price.
 How firms compete Easy as PIE: Presenting in English 09/03/2011.
The Four Conditions for Perfect Competition
Review of the previous lecture A monopoly is a firm that is the sole seller in its market. It faces a downward-sloping demand curve for its product. A.
LECTURE #13: MICROECONOMICS CHAPTER 15
Monopolies Definition, Causes & Pricing. Monopoly Market Characteristics One Seller Unique Product—no substitutes Difficult/Impossible to enter or leave.
Law Antitrust - Instructor: Dwight Drake United States v. E.I. Du Pont De Nemours & Co (1956) Basic Facts: During period , Dupont controlled.
Claudia Gonzalez David Tran What is Market Failures?
The Modernization of Article 82 : an Economic Perspective Dr Valérie RABASSA* Chief Economist Office DG COMPETITION EUROPEAN COMMISSION *The views expressed.
Facoltà di Giurisprudenza -ECONOMICS- Anno accademico 2011/2012 -ECONOMICS- Anno accademico 2011/2012 Nicola Bruni.
Chapter 12 Monopoly. Basic Definitions Imperfect Competition: Occurs when firms in a market or industry have some control over the price of their output.
ECON 201: Principles of Microeconomics Chapter 9 of McEachern: Monopoly What is Monopoly? A Single Seller is the Sole Supplier in a Market where the Product.
The dominance concept: new wine in old bottles Miguel de la Mano * Member of the Chief Economist’s Office DG COMP, European Commission FTC/DOJ Hearings.
Copyright©2004 South-Western 15 Monopoly. Copyright © 2004 South-Western Monopoly While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price.
1.4.5 Monopoly and the allocation of resources What is the objective in a game of monopoly? Use your knowledge of economics to explain why a hotel on Old.
Chapter 5: The Public Sector. Economic and technical efficiency Technical efficiency – no unemployed or underemployed resources (i.e., operating on PPC).
Economics ch. 7 Perfect Competition  A large number of buyers and sellers exchange identical products under the following five conditions. ___________.
University of Papua New Guinea Principles of Microeconomics Lecture 11: Monopoly.
Monopoly 15. Monopoly A firm is considered a monopoly if... it is the sole seller of its product. it is the sole seller of its product. its product does.
I. A Simple Model. Players: Sellers, I and E, and a consumer Period 1: Seller I and the buyer can make an exclusive contract. Period 2: Seller E decides.
Chapter 4 Consumer and Producer Surplus >> ©2011  Worth Publishers.
Chapter 7SectionMain Menu Perfect Competition What conditions must exist for perfect competition? What are barriers to entry and how do they affect the.
Government intervention and competition policy 3.
CASE FAIR OSTER ECONOMICS P R I N C I P L E S O F
Monopoly 12-1.
African Competition Forum
Monopoly A firm is considered a monopoly if . . .
Access and Termination Charges in Telecoms: Antitrust considerations
Bellwork What is the difference between a perfectly competitive firm, monopoly and oligopoly? Give examples of each.
Economics: Principles in Action
Perfect Competition What conditions must exist for perfect competition? What are barriers to entry and how do they affect the marketplace? What are prices.
Perfect Competition What conditions must exist for perfect competition? What are barriers to entry and how do they affect the marketplace? What are prices.
Presentation transcript:

Competition Policy in Two-Sided Markets - Some brief remarks Dr Amelia Fletcher Chief Economist Office of Fair Trading LEAR Conference 7th June 2007 NB The views expressed here are my own, and not necessarily those of the OFT

What do certain key factors of 2- sided markets mean for:  Market definition?  Predation?  Collusion?  Exclusive contracts?  Media regulation and mergers?

2-sided markets: First key factor  In a typical 2-sided market:  D A is function not only of p A but also of q B  D B is function not only of p B but also of q A  What does this mean for market definition?

Market definition  SSNIP test:  Could a hypothetical monopolist profitably sustain a small but significant and non-transitory increase in price?  If no, the relevant antitrust market must be wider  If yes, the market is not any wider (but could be narrower)  Key question for 2-sided markets:  Which feedback loops should be taken into account?

Market definition: Feedback loops pA↑pA↑ qA↓qA↓ πA↑πA↑πA↓πA↓ πA↑πA↑ Normal Market: Does total π A ↑? If yes, market no wider ?

Market definition: Feedback loops pA↑pA↑ qA↓qA↓DB↓DB↓qB↓qB↓ πA↑πA↑πA↓πA↓ πB↓πB↓ For given p B πA↑πA↑ Normal Market: Does total π A ↑? If yes, market no wider Feedback to market B

Market definition: Feedback loops pA↑pA↑ qA↓qA↓DB↓DB↓qB↓qB↓ πA↑πA↑πA↓πA↓ πB↓πB↓ For given p B πA↑πA↑ Normal Market: Does total π A ↑? If yes, market no wider Feedback to market B Should we take this into account?

Market definition: Feedback loops pA↑pA↑ qA↓qA↓DB↓DB↓qB↓qB↓DA↓DA↓qA↓qA↓ πA↑πA↑πA↓πA↓ πB↓πB↓ πA↓πA↓ For given p B For given p A πA↑πA↑ Normal Market: Does total π A ↑? If yes, market no wider Feedback to market A Feedback to market B

Market definition: Feedback loops pA↑pA↑ qA↓qA↓DB↓DB↓qB↓qB↓DA↓DA↓qA↓qA↓ πA↑πA↑πA↓πA↓ πB↓πB↓ πA↓πA↓ For given p B For given p A πA↑πA↑ Normal Market: Does total π A ↑? If yes, market no wider Feedback to market A Feedback to market B Should we take this into account?

Market definition: Feedback loops pA↑pA↑ qA↓qA↓DB↓DB↓qB↓qB↓DA↓DA↓qA↓qA↓ πA↑πA↑πA↓πA↓ πB↓πB↓ πA↓πA↓ For given p B For given p A πA↑πA↑ Normal Market: Does total π A ↑? If yes, market no wider pB↓pB↓qB↑qB↑ πB↓πB↓ Profits dissipated in market B Feedback to market A Feedback to market B Should we take this into account?

Market definition: Feedback loops pA↑pA↑ qA↓qA↓DB↓DB↓qB↓qB↓DA↓DA↓qA↓qA↓ πA↑πA↑πA↓πA↓ πB↓πB↓ πA↓πA↓ For given p B For given p A πA↑πA↑ Normal Market: Does total π A ↑? If yes, market no wider pB↓pB↓qB↑qB↑ πB↓πB↓ DA↑DA↑qA↑qA↑ πA↑πA↑ Profits dissipated in market B Feedback to market A Feedback to market A Feedback to market B

Market definition: Feedback loops pA↑pA↑ qA↓qA↓DB↓DB↓qB↓qB↓DA↓DA↓qA↓qA↓ πA↑πA↑πA↓πA↓ πB↓πB↓ πA↓πA↓ For given p B For given p A πA↑πA↑ Normal Market: Does total π A ↑? If yes, market no wider pB↓pB↓qB↑qB↑ πB↓πB↓ DA↑DA↑qA↑qA↑ πA↑πA↑ Profits dissipated in market B Feedback to market A Feedback to market A Feedback to market B

Market definition: Feedback loops pA↑pA↑ qA↓qA↓DB↓DB↓qB↓qB↓DA↓DA↓qA↓qA↓ πA↑πA↑πA↓πA↓ πB↓πB↓ πA↓πA↓ For given p B For given p A πA↑πA↑ Normal Market: Does total π A ↑? If yes, market no wider pB↓pB↓qB↑qB↑ πB↓πB↓ DA↑DA↑qA↑qA↑ πA↑πA↑ Profits dissipated in market B Feedback to market A Feedback to market A Feedback to market B

2-sided markets: Second key factor  p A will tend to be lower when either:  each additional buyer in market A generates significant extra revenue in market B; or  it is hard to persuade market A buyers to sign up.  More formally (Rochet & Tirole, 2006): price – ‘cost’ = 1. price elasticity of demand  If ‘cost’ increases (due to lower revs in other market), then so will price (The ‘waterbed effect’)

Predation and excessive pricing  In a two-side market, we may typically observe:  Prices below marginal cost on one side of a market; and  Prices well above marginal cost on the other  Such pricing is an efficient response to network externalities.  Competition authorities need to be aware of this when assessing predation or excessive pricing  We also need to be aware of the ‘waterbed effect’, when imposing remedies

However…  This does not mean predation (and excessive pricing) doesn’t occur  For example, what if pricing structure affects market structure?  Specifically, what if pricing low on one side of a market prevents entry into both sides?  Can such a pricing structure increase ‘tippability’ of already ‘tippable’ markets?  But how to assess?

A careful approach is needed  Low pricing on one side of a two sided market can be exclusionary  But application of simple Akzo type test for predation (ie is P < AAC?) problematic  A possible approach?  to apply an Akzo type test, but  to employ an ‘opportunity cost’ benchmark

Collusion on one side of the market  True that increased profits from collusion on one side of a market get competed away on the other  Does this justify a laissez faire approach?  No!  Not all additional profits are competed away  Prices typically even higher than without collusion, suggesting inefficient price asymmetry  But it does make it difficult to determine appropriate exemption criteria where relevant

2-sided markets: Third key factor  2-sided markets are often ‘tippable’  Often observe competition ‘for’ the market  This competition can get rough – but should competition authorities intervene?  After all – a monopoly anyway  Does it matter who wins?  Yes! And best for both consumers and dynamic competition if the best product wins

2-sided markets: Fourth key factor  The ‘tippability’ of 2-sided markets is reduced if there is multi-homing on one (or both) side of the market  A move to single-homing by a relatively small part of the previously multi-homing side of the market can sometimes have major effects.

The effect of single-homing Buyer 1Platform ASeller 1 Buyer 2Platform BSeller 2

The effect of single-homing Buyer 1Platform ASeller 1 Buyer 2Platform BSeller 2

Exclusivity contracts  Assessment of exclusivity contracts (or refusal to supply) is complicated in ‘tippy’ markets:  Small scale coverage could ‘tip’ the balance  Interesting that customers do better by being ‘single homing’ under profit-maximising pricing  So no need for profit sacrifice to ‘bribe’ customers to sign exclusive contracts or to refuse to supply  Could ‘multi-homing be a remedy?

2-sided markets: Fifth key factor  The advertising funded nature of media can result in imperfect product/political diversity  For media regulators:  This clearly provides a microeconomic justification for some form of regulatory intervention  But how to decide ‘what is welfare optimal’ in real life?  For competition authorities:  Does it suggest a need to think about wider ‘public interest’ issues when assessing media mergers?

Competition Policy in Two-Sided Markets - Some brief remarks Dr Amelia Fletcher Chief Economist Office of Fair Trading LEAR Conference 7th June 2007 NB The views expressed here are my own, and not necessarily those of the OFT