Competition Among Asymmetric Sellers with Fixed Supply Uriel Feige ( Weizmann Institute of Science ) Ron Lavi ( Technion and Yahoo! Labs ) Moshe Tennenholtz.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Conditional Equilibrium Outcomes via Ascending Price Processes Joint work with Hu Fu and Robert Kleinberg (Computer Science, Cornell University) Ron Lavi.
Advertisements

Auction Theory Class 5 – single-parameter implementation and risk aversion 1.
Nash Equilibrium: Illustrations
Ultimatum Game Two players bargain (anonymously) to divide a fixed amount between them. P1 (proposer) offers a division of the “pie” P2 (responder) decides.
ECON 100 Tutorial: Week 9 office: LUMS C85.
Seminar in Auctions and Mechanism Design Based on J. Hartline’s book: Approximation in Economic Design Presented by: Miki Dimenshtein & Noga Levy.
Multi-item auctions with identical items limited supply: M items (M smaller than number of bidders, n). Three possible bidder types: –Unit-demand bidders.
Auction Theory Class 3 – optimal auctions 1. Optimal auctions Usually the term optimal auctions stands for revenue maximization. What is maximal revenue?
Competitive Safety Analysis: Robust Decision-Making in Multi-Agent systems Moshe Tennenholtz Summarized by Yi Seung-Joon.
Lectures 7&8 Revisit Elections Now range is left-wing or right-wing politics. Candidate-Voter model Assume even distribution of voters. Voters will vote.
1/22 Competitive Capacity Sets Existence of Equilibria in Electricity Markets A. Downward G. ZakeriA. Philpott Engineering Science, University of Auckland.
Chunyang Tong Sriram Dasu Information & Operations Management Marshall School of Business University of Southern California Los Angeles CA Dynamic.
Excursions in Modern Mathematics Sixth Edition
NOGA ALON, MOSHE BABAIOFF, RON KARIDI, RON LAVI, MOSHE TENNENHOLTZ PRESENTED BY EREZ SHABAT Sequential Voting with Externalities: Herding in Social Networks.
6.896: Topics in Algorithmic Game Theory Lecture 14 Constantinos Daskalakis.
Dynamic Games of Complete Information.. Repeated games Best understood class of dynamic games Past play cannot influence feasible actions or payoff functions.
Bundling Equilibrium in Combinatorial Auctions Written by: Presented by: Ron Holzman Rica Gonen Noa Kfir-Dahav Dov Monderer Moshe Tennenholtz.
A camper awakens to the growl of a hungry bear and sees his friend putting on a pair of running shoes, “You can’t outrun a bear,” scoffs the camper. His.
Mechanism Design and the VCG mechanism The concept of a “mechanism”. A general (abstract) solution for welfare maximization: the VCG mechanism. –This is.
1 An Analysis for Troubled Assets Reverse Auction Saeed Alaei (University of Maryland-College Park) Azarakhsh Malekian (University of Maryland-College.
Agent Technology for e-Commerce Chapter 10: Mechanism Design Maria Fasli
Developing Principles in Bargaining. Motivation Consider a purely distributive bargaining situation where impasse is costly to both sides How should we.
Mechanism Design: Online Auction or Packet Scheduling Online auction of a reusable good (packet slots) Agents types: (arrival, departure, value) –Agents.
UNIT II: The Basic Theory Zero-sum Games Nonzero-sum Games Nash Equilibrium: Properties and Problems Bargaining Games Bargaining and Negotiation Review.
3 SUPPLY AND DEMAND II: MARKETS AND WELFARE. Copyright © 2004 South-Western 7 Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets.
Algoritmisk Spilteori Peter Bro Miltersen dPersp, Uge 5, 2. forelæsning.
Extensive Game with Imperfect Information Part I: Strategy and Nash equilibrium.
Competitive Analysis of Incentive Compatible On-Line Auctions Ron Lavi and Noam Nisan SISL/IST, Cal-Tech Hebrew University.
Noam Nisan Non-price Equilibria in Markets of Discrete goods Avinatan Hassidim, Haim Kaplan, Yishay Mansour, Noam Nisan.
UNIT II: The Basic Theory Zero-sum Games Nonzero-sum Games Nash Equilibrium: Properties and Problems Bargaining Games Bargaining and Negotiation Review.
1 EC9B6 Voting and Communication Lecture 1 Prof. Francesco Squintani
Learning dynamics,genetic algorithms,and corporate takeovers Thomas H. Noe,Lynn Pi.
ECON 6012 Cost Benefit Analysis Memorial University of Newfoundland
Object Of Presentation What is market What is efficiency Economic efficiency Details of three conditions Adam Smith’s Invisible Hand Other factors for.
Principles of Micro Chapter 7: “Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets” by Tanya Molodtsova, Fall 2005.
©2003, Zoran Despotovic, EPFL-I&C, Laboratoire de systèmes d'informations répartis Double Auctioning in a P2P environment (an attempt) Zoran Despotovic.
Yang Cai Sep 8, An overview of the class Broad View: Mechanism Design and Auctions First Price Auction Second Price/Vickrey Auction Case Study:
A Truthful Mechanism for Offline Ad Slot Scheduling Jon Feldman S. Muthukrishnan Eddie Nikolova Martin P á l.
Multi-Unit Auctions with Budget Limits Shahar Dobzinski, Ron Lavi, and Noam Nisan.
Sequences of Take-It-or-Leave-it Offers: Near-Optimal Auctions Without Full Valuation Revelation Tuomas Sandholm and Andrew Gilpin Carnegie Mellon University.
Auction Seminar Optimal Mechanism Presentation by: Alon Resler Supervised by: Amos Fiat.
3 SUPPLY AND DEMAND II: MARKETS AND WELFARE. Copyright © 2004 South-Western 7 Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets.
INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES IN COMMON VALUE AUCTIONS WITH DISCRETE SIGNALS Vasilis Syrgkanis Microsoft Research, NYC Joint with David Kempe, USC Eva Tardos,
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright  2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. GAME THEORY, STRATEGIC DECISION MAKING, AND BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS.
Introduction to Matching Theory E. Maskin Jerusalem Summer School in Economic Theory June 2014.
Chapter 14: Fair Division Part 5 – Defining Fairness.
Topic 2: Designing the “optimal auction” Reminder of previous classes: Discussed 1st price and 2nd price auctions. Found equilibrium strategies. Saw that.
Ad Auctions: Game-Theoretic Perspectives Moshe Tennenholtz Technion—Israel Institute of Technology and Microsoft Research.
Extensive Games with Imperfect Information
Chapter 14 – Fair Division Part 2: The Knaster Inheritance Procedure.
Chapter 3 Fair Division.
Comp 553: Algorithmic Game Theory Fall 2014 Yang Cai Lecture 23.
Harcourt, Inc. items and derived items copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. Revisiting the Market Equilibrium Do the equilibrium price and quantity maximize.
Auctions serve the dual purpose of eliciting preferences and allocating resources between competing uses. A less fundamental but more practical reason.
Strategic Behavior in Business and Econ Static Games of complete information: Dominant Strategies and Nash Equilibrium in pure and mixed strategies.
6.853: Topics in Algorithmic Game Theory Fall 2011 Constantinos Daskalakis Lecture 22.
Auctions serve the dual purpose of eliciting preferences and allocating resources between competing uses. A less fundamental but more practical reason.
Negotiating Socially Optimal Allocations of Resources U. Endriss, N. Maudet, F. Sadri, and F. Toni Presented by: Marcus Shea.
Pricing of Competing Products BI Solutions December
Position Auctions with Budgets: Existence and Uniqueness Ron Lavi Industrial Engineering and Management Technion – Israel Institute of Technology Joint.
Incomplete Information and Bayes-Nash Equilibrium.
By: Donté Howell Game Theory in Sports. What is Game Theory? It is a tool used to analyze strategic behavior and trying to maximize his/her payoff of.
The analytics of constrained optimal decisions microeco nomics spring 2016 the monopoly model (I): standard pricing ………….1optimal production ………….2 optimal.
Lecture 4 on Auctions Multiunit Auctions We begin this lecture by comparing auctions with monopolies. We then discuss different pricing schemes for selling.
False-name Bids “The effect of false-name bids in combinatorial
Failures of the VCG Mechanism in Combinatorial Auctions and Exchanges
Signaling unobservable quality choice through price and advertising: The case with competing firms Speaker: Wu Fulan 3rd August,2009.
Laddered auction Ashish Goel tanford University
Sequential Voting with Externalities: Herding in Social Networks
Lecture 10 Coordination and Reputation
Presentation transcript:

Competition Among Asymmetric Sellers with Fixed Supply Uriel Feige ( Weizmann Institute of Science ) Ron Lavi ( Technion and Yahoo! Labs ) Moshe Tennenholtz ( Technion and MSR ) * Work conducted at MSR Herzliya

Motivation: markets for ads... Thousands of advertisers Handful of publishers B1B2B3Bn q1 q2 Abstract view: Publishers: Determine allocation of slots to advertisers, based on budgets given to them. Cannot adjust size of supply! Advertisers: Based on publishers’ policies, assign budgets. Motivation: How should publishers choose allocation policies to maximize revenue?

Motivation: markets for ads... n advertisers m publishers BBBB q1q1 qmqm This work: Symmetric advertisers, non-symmetric publishers:...

The Model... n buyers m sellers BBBB q1q1 qmqm This work: Symmetric buyers, non-symmetric sellers:...

This model was studied previously: Friedman (1958): – Assumes sellers’ policies are “proportional”: seller j gives buyer i* (b i*j /  i b ij )q j (b ij is the budget that seller j receives from buyer i) This is a “Blotto game” (Generals send soldiers to battlefields) – Studied many times over the years… Also applied to political campaigns, e.g., Snyder (1989) – “Seller” = voting district (supply = number of district voters); “Buyer” = political party that partitions its budget among the various districts. And much more…

Key Difference Previous work: Sellers with fixed exogenous allocation policies – Makes sense for battlefields, voting districts, etc. – But publishers are strategic and are free to determine their own allocation policies This work: Sellers endogenously determine allocation policies to maximize revenue – (In the language of Blotto games: a battlefields decides on its winning function, to maximize the number of soldiers it gets)

Summary of the game Sellers determine allocation policies: given budget assignments, how much items each buyer receives Given allocation policies, buyers partition budgets among sellers Resulting utility of sellers: number of dollars obtained Resulting utility of buyers: number of items obtained – Same assumption as in previous work, this not quasi-linear Assumptions (following previous work): – Complete information – Buyers play a Nash eq. (pure or mixed) of the resulting ”buyers game” (after observing the allocation policies).

Convenient Change of Units... n buyers m sellers B=1 q1q1 qmqm... B=1  i q i = n

“Fair Share”... n buyers m sellers B=1 q1q1 qmqm... B=1  i q i = n Overall: n dollars, n items A reasonable outcome: each item costs one dollar This is the unique Walrasian outcome In this outcome, the revenue of seller j is q j We call q j the “fair share” revenue of seller j.

“Fair Share” Overall: n dollars, n items A reasonable outcome: each item costs one dollar This is the unique Walrasian outcome In this outcome, the revenue of seller j is q j We call q j the “fair share” revenue of seller j. THM (Friedman 1958) If all sellers use proportional allocation, there is a unique Nash equilibrium of the buyers game whose outcome is the fair share outcome. Proportional allocation: seller j gives buyer i* (b i*j /  i b ij )q j (b ij : budget to seller j from buyer i)

“Fair Share” Overall: n dollars, n items A reasonable outcome: each item costs one dollar This is the unique Walrasian outcome In this outcome, the revenue of seller j is q j We call q j the “fair share” revenue of seller j. THM (Friedman 1958) If all sellers use proportional allocation, there is a unique Nash equilibrium of the buyers game whose outcome is the fair share outcome. Thus, collectively, sellers can implement the fair share outcome But, acting strategically, some sellers may use other policies. Can a seller guarantee her fair share?

Safety Level THM 1: If seller j uses proportional allocation, her revenue in any Nash equilibrium of the resulting buyers game will be strictly larger than q j – 1, regardless of the allocation policies used by the other sellers. Remarks: Proportional allocation guarantees q j – 1 but does not guarantee q j (we give an example for that). No strategy can guarantee more than q j +1 We do not know what is the maximal possible guarantee in the interval [ q j – 1, q j + 1 ], and what strategy achieves it.

Extremely Asymmetric Supply Conclusion: a seller with large supply can guarantee almost her fair share, and that’s almost the best she can do (up to an additive +/-1 term). But for a seller with extremely small supply this additive term is very significant. Extreme example: q H = n – ( 1 - 1/n), q L = 1 - 1/n – The THM is meaningless for L – Suppose H uses proportional allocation. By placing all budget with H, every buyer can obtain at least q H /n > q L – Therefore all buyers will put all their budget with H

Are Extreme Asymmetries Common? Consider an Example: 800 buyers, 2 sellers, q H = 720, q L = 80 – On the face of it, supply is not extremely asymmetric (e.g. L can guarantee $79 using proportional allocation). But, suppose this market is actually divided equally to 100 separate sub-markets – The Internet advertising market is divided to many small markets (based on properties like geo, gender, age, smarter targeting…) Each sub-market has 8 buyers, q H =72, q L = 0.8 – H can offer at least 7.2/8 = 0.9 > 0.8 to each buyer. Thus, H obtains all budgets, leaving L with 0 revenue!

A special case with two sellers How extreme should the asymmetries be, for this to happen? The “first” case where the answer is non-trivial is the case of two sellers, q H = n-1, q L = 1 – THM 1 is still meaningless – But how can H 1 obtain more than her fair share? – The answer is not straight-forward, and includes two key ingredients: (i) Budget rigidity (ii) Elimination of Pure Nash

(i) Budget Rigidity A rigid buyer will not split his budget. A rigid seller will accept only rigid buyers. Rigidity can be enforced on the seller’s side by technological and marketing means. It can also originate from the buyer’s side, especially in more traditional markets. – This is also called “single-homing” in the literature – It is common even in Internet advertising [Ashlagi et al.] Remarks: Proportional allocation with budget rigidity gives the same guarantee as proportional allocation Typically, rigidity “favors” large sellers – Example: q1 = 13; q2, …, q9 = 1.5. n=25. All fractional surplus goes to seller 1. (Her revenue is 17, the revenue of every other seller is 1.)

Back to the special case (Reminder: two sellers, q H = n-1, q L = 1) If the H enforces rigidity, multiple equilibria emerge. In a pure Nash: One buyer goes to the L, all others go to H – This is the fair share outcome. Rigidity does not help… However there are also mixed Nash equilibria, including the natural symmetric equilibrium. THM 2: If the large seller enforces rigidity, in every mixed Nash equilibrium the revenue of the large seller is O(n – 1/n) while the revenue of the small seller is O(1/n).  Surprising and significant separation of resulting revenue

(ii) Elimination of pure Nash Proportional allocation among rigid buyers, with a gamble: If a single buyer is rigid and declares he “gambles”, he gets 1 + O(1/n) items. If multiple bidder gamble, they get nothing. All other rigid buyers equally split the remaining items. THM 3: If H uses this, and regardless of the policy of L, H’s revenue in every Nash equilibrium is O(n - 1/n). Technically, an allocation policy is a function of n numbers, without extra bits. The “gamble” can be a bid of 1- . Such allocation is non-monotone (a buyer can get more for less budget); we show that such non-monotonicity is required.

Additional Remarks 1.Restricting H to be monotone: – L cannot guarantee a revenue of 1, even if H is restricted to be monotone. – H cannot guarantee a revenue of n-1 if it is restricted to be monotone. – H can guarantee a revenue of n-1-O(1/n 2 ) with a monotone policy. 2.One way to generalize the case of two extremely asymmetric sellers is to have one large seller and multiple small sellers. In this case the small sellers’ aggregate supply must very small: THM: If all sellers in a set S use proportional allocation, their total revenue in any Nash equilibrium of the resulting buyers game will be strictly larger than (  j  S q j )– 1, regardless of the allocation policies used by the other sellers.

Summary Study competition among sellers that cannot adjust supply size – Determine allocation based on budgets given to them – Like a Blotto game with endogenous winning functions for battlefields A seller that uses proportional allocation can guarantee almost the fair share revenue (the revenue of the Walrasian outcome). – Holds for arbitrary supply sizes and any number of sellers When differences in supply are extreme, the large seller can drive the revenue of the small seller to be almost zero – Two sellers large and small – Optimal policy uses bid rigidity and elimination of pure Nash Main open question: how large supply differences must be, for the large seller to exercise such a extra power?

A bit of political science This model is relevant (among so many other things) to the question of assigning parliament seats as a function of the votes that a party receives in the elections? The analogy: – Parties are sellers, votes that a party receives are its supply. – Seats are rigid buyers (each seat has a budget of 1, to be given to the party who is assigned this seat). Pure Nash of proportional allocation with rigid budgets exactly implements a method invented by D’Hondt (1878) – Well known to favor large parties – Used until this day in many European countries – Already used by Thomas Jefferson (1792) Other methods (e.g. the Hare-Neimeyer method) can be represented as other natural allocation policies.