Inequality and Redistribution in the Australian Welfare State

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
1 Alternative measures of well-being Joint work by ECO/ELSA/STD.
Advertisements

IFS Understanding recent trends in income inequality Alissa Goodman Institute for Fiscal Studies.
Income Inequality International Comparisons. Data Sources 4 Luxembourg Income Study -- uses survey income from 25 countries; data organized to maximize.
The State of Working America, The labor market recession, which began in October 2000 remains with us. This recession marks the end of the long.
Chapter 16 Economic Inequality
Comments on Income and Wealth Concentration in a Historical and International Perspective Berkeley Symposium on Poverty, the Distribution of Income, and.
Assistance for families: An assessment of Australian family policies from an international perspective Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre,
Fiscal Policy, Poverty and Redistribution in Latin America Nora Lustig Tulane University Nonresident Fellow CGD and IAD Inter-American Dialogue Washington,
“Analyzing Health Equity Using Household Survey Data” Owen O’Donnell, Eddy van Doorslaer, Adam Wagstaff and Magnus Lindelow, The World Bank, Washington.
© The Treasury Trends in income inequality and other socio-economic outcomes Ben Gleisner Senior Analyst – Workforce Attachment and Skills.
1 Income Inequality in Rich Countries A B Atkinson, Nuffield College, Oxford ECINEQ Conference Mallorca July 2005.
Public policy and European society University of Castellanza Session 3(a) Inequality in Europe and the USA March
1 Reducing the Gaps in Society: Policy Challenges in the Era of Globalization Dr. Karnit Flug June 2007 Taub Center Conference.
Trends in Income Distribution. Trends in Income Distribution Wealth & Poverty 1.Poverty rose from the late 1970’s until the early 1990’s, both in absolute.
Is Inequality Increasing? Presentation for Parliamentary Library Vital Issues Seminar, 10 October 2012 Peter Whiteford, Crawford School of Public Policy.
IT’S ABOUT HOUSEHOLDS Jennifer Ribarsky Head of Section Sectoral and National Accounts OECD Group of Experts on National Accounts Meeting Geneva, 7 -9.
© 2003 By Default!Slide 1 Inequality Measures Celia M. Reyes Introduction to Poverty Analysis NAI, Beijing, China Nov. 1-8, 2005.
Lecture 2: Inequality. Today’s Readings Schiller, Ch. 2: Inequality “Income, Poverty, and Health Insurance Coverage in the United States,” Current Population.
Employment and Development: Good Jobs and Bad Jobs Turin, Monday, May 22, 2006 François Bourguignon Senior Vice President and Chief Economist The World.
Labor Market Trends in North America – Has Economic Well-being improved ? Lars Osberg Department of Economics, Dalhousie University Halifax, Nova Scotia.
Poverty: Facts, Causes and Consequences Hilary Hoynes University of California, Davis California Symposium on Poverty October 2009.
THEORY OF DISTRIBUTION OF INCOMES
Unit VIII Income Inequality. In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:  How much inequality and poverty exist in our society?  What.
Distribution of Income and Wealth
Distribution of Income & Income Inequality The Lorenz Curve & The Gini Index.
McTaggart, Findlay, Parkin: Microeconomics © 2007 Pearson Education Australia Chapter 18: Economic Inequality and Redistribution.
Social Policy : Trends in spending, recipiency and policy focus Seminar presentation: Korea Institute for Health and Social Affairs 11 October, 2007, Seoul,
Centre for Tax Policy and Administration Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development Trends in Top Incomes & Inequality, and their implications.
Copyright © 2009 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Chapter 17 The Distribution of Income.
Distribution of income and wealth Define income Market income= wages/salaries/profit/rent Gross income= market income + transfers Disposable income= gross.
Lecture 2 : Inequality. Today’s Topic’s Schiller’s major points Introduction to Census data.
Measuring population development from social cohesion perspective by women and men according to the Census data Urve Kask Statistics Estonia.
The distribution of the State budget Total budget: 298 billion NIS, 2005 chart 1.
Bank of Israel Annual Report April was a good year for Israel's economy: The economy grew rapidly, with growth led by the business sector.
Chapter 17 The Distribution of Income McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2012 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
2 DATA AND ESTIMATION 3 4 CONCLUSIONS AND WAY FORWARD 1 MALAYSIAN DEMOGRAPHIC PATTERNS FINDINGS AND IMPLICATIONS.
From GDP to adjusted net disposable income of households – a decomposition analysis Working Party on National Accounts 1-3 December 2010 Julien Dupont.
GROWING TOGETHER: THE AUSTRALIAN SOCIAL DEMOCRATIC MODEL Presentation by Hon Wayne Swan MP Member for Lilley Treasurer (2007 – 2013) Deputy Prime Minister.
The Role of the Fiscal Policy in Poverty Reduction Youngsun Koh Korea Development Institute.
Michael Rogan & John Reynolds. Content International context International Labour Organisation SA context Income, wages & earnings over post-apartheid.
Cumulative impacts of austerity measures and the distribution of economic outcomes John Hills Centre for Analysis of Social Exclusion, London School of.
Backgrounds of Research (1) : Public attention to Income Gap
Economic Conditions of Female- headed Households in Taiwan in Comparison to the United States and Sweden Some reflections on the measurement of social.
Public policy and European society University of Castellanza Session 3(a) Inequality in Europe and the USA March
1 The global distribution of income: past trends and future prospects A B Atkinson, University of Oxford Inequality and poverty in the global economy,
Economic Inequality CHAPTER 18. After studying this chapter you will be able to Describe the inequality in income and wealth in the United States and.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright  2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Who Gets What? The Distribution of Income Who Gets What? The.
 Goal of Equity in Income distribution: is to have a more equitable (fairer) distribution of income. That means productive income is divided among the.
Poverty in Scotland and the UK Communities Analysis Division– September 2015 While relative poverty in Scotland fell in 2013/14, it remained flat in the.
Poverty and Income Inequality in Edinburgh September 2015.
Fighting child poverty across the OECD: is work the answer? Presentation: Joint OECD/Korea Regional Centre on Health and Social policy July 2006, Seoul.
INCOME INEQUALITY IN INDIA
1 Net Worth over $2.3 billion Copyright ACDC Leadership 2015.
Introduction to the UK Economy. What are the key objectives of macroeconomic policy? Price Stability (CPI Inflation of 2%) Growth of Real GDP (National.
Bangladesh Poverty Assessment: Building on Progress Poverty Trends and Profile Dhaka, October 23 rd 2002.
Introduction Characteristics of the Israeli labor market –Low participation rate in the labor force compared to OECD countries –High rate of foreign workers.
1 Measuring Poverty: Inequality Measures Charting Inequality Share of Expenditure of Poor Dispersion Ratios Lorenz Curve Gini Coefficient Theil Index Comparisons.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright  2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Who Gets What? The Distribution of Income Who Gets What? The.
INEQUALITY & DEVELOPMENT Lawrence Summers EC1400, ITF th November 2015.
Fighting child poverty across the OECD: is work the answer?
Public policy and European society University of Castellanza
Some preliminary remarks
Lecture (ppt 2) Inequality: Concepts, Measures and Experience
Social Policy : Trends in spending, recipiency and policy focus
Analysis of results.
Social Policy : Trends in spending, recipiency and policy focus
GDP and beyond Robin Lynch
© 2015 by McGraw-Hill Ryerson Ltd.
Poverty and household spending in Britain
GDP and beyond Robin Lynch
Presentation transcript:

Inequality and Redistribution in the Australian Welfare State Peter Whiteford, Crawford School of Public Policy peter.whiteford@anu.edu.au

Acknowledgements Research supported as part of the GINI project – “Growing Inequalities’ Impacts” http://www.gini-research.org/articles/research. EU Seventh framework programme cooperation, Theme 8, Socio-economic sciences and humanities, SSH-2009 - 2.2.1 social inequalities, their implications and policy options “The project focus is inequalities in income/wealth and education and their social, political and cultural impacts. It highlights potential effects of individual distributional positions and increasing inequality for a host of ‘bad outcomes’ (both societal and individual) and allows feedback from these impacts to inequality itself in a frame of policy-oriented debate and comparison across 25 EU countries, the USA, Japan, Canada and Australia.” Also based on work undertaken and to continue with Gerry Redmond (Flinders University), Philip Hayes and Elizabeth Adamson (UNSW), “Supporting families: Horizontal and vertical equity in the Australian tax-benefit system in historical and comparative perspectives “, funded by ARC (LP 100100596). 1. Since 2004, Treasury’s mission is ‘to improve the wellbeing of the Australian people by providing sound and timely advice to the Government, based on objective and thorough analysis of options, and by assisting Treasury Ministers in the administration of their responsibilities and the implementation of Government decisions’. Developing a consistent and robust understanding of wellbeing is thus critical to Treasury’s work. In this regard, Treasury has developed a wellbeing framework to underpin analysis and advice across the full range of our public policy responsibilities. The framework is drawn from broadly applicable economic principles, which are Treasury’s comparative advantage in the provision of policy analysis and advice to Government. The dimensions chosen for the wellbeing framework are: (i) the level of opportunity and freedom that people enjoy; (ii) the level of consumption possibilities; (iii) the distribution of those consumption possibilities; (iv) the level of risk that people are required to bear; and (v) the level of complexity that people are required to deal with. These dimensions are not necessarily comprehensive, unique or independent. They have been chosen simply because they describe the aspects of wellbeing that are considered to be most relevant to Treasury’s responsibilities. 2. Questions about the contribution of growing income inequality in USA to financial crisis (R.G. Rajan, “Fault Lines”, 2010) 3. “Occupy” movement and 1%. According to the ATO’s tax statistics, if you earned $248 192 or more in 2008-09, you were part of the top 1%. The average income for an individual in the top 1% of taxpayers was $554 185. The median income for that year was $45 200, so the average income for someone in the top 1% was more than 12 times the median.

Background and outline Increasing interest internationally and in Australia in trends in inequality. Questions about the contribution of growing income inequality in USA to financial crisis (R.G. Rajan, “Fault Lines”, 2010) This presentation is primarily descriptive – what has happened to income inequality in Australia over recent decades, and what factors appear to be associated with these trends. Data and methods; measures of inequality Situating Australia internationally Income inequality: trends and driving forces Redistribution through taxes and benefits Discussion and conclusions 3. “Occupy” movement and 1%.

Data and methods Data are from Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS) income surveys from 1981-82 to 2007-08 and in some cases 2009-10. The ABS has changed and improved income measures over time; for consistency we use the “unimproved” income measure, showing lower inequality after 2005-06, but effects on earlier trends uncertain. Income measure is current weekly income of income units (nuclear family), adjusted for household size using “revised OECD equivalence scales”. Income is conventionally made up of market income (earnings, self-employment, investment and property income, private transfers); the addition of transfers from government (social security benefits) or privately (e.g. child support) produces gross income; direct taxes are deducted to estimate cash disposable income. Also important to bear in mind what is not included in cash disposable income – e.g. imputed income from housing, indirect taxes, non-cash benefits, superannuation - or is/maybe included but is not easily identifiable – e.g. tax expenditures (concessions) . the new income measures now include non-cash benefits, bonuses, termination payments and payments for irregular overtime. Commencing with SIH 2007–08, interest paid on money borrowed to purchase shares or units in trusts has been netted off income earned from these sources when deriving net income estimates, with a similar revision applied to results for 2003–04 and 2005–06. While regular workers' compensation receipts have been included in previously published results, lump sum receipts were not. Commencing in SIH 2007–08, both forms of workers' compensation are included in the published estimates. In SIH 2007–08, a wider range of data on financial support received from and paid to family members resident outside the household was collected. Previously these were mainly limited to regular payments for spousal maintenance and child support. In 2007–08, respondents were asked to include other forms of financial support, including goods and services received which were purchased by others e.g. rent, education, food, clothing, car registration and utilities. implementation of the broader measure of income in 2007–08 resulted in an $85 increase in mean weekly gross household income, compared to the previous definition. The additional inclusions affected 3.4m households in total (43%). Most of the impact was on employment income, which increased by $89 per week on average. The inclusion of non-cash employment benefits and bonuses had the most impact ($43 and $32 per week respectively). worked.

How is inequality measured? What inequalities are we interested in or concerned about – inequality of income, inequality of opportunity, inequality of wealth? Inequality is often thought of as disparities or gaps – what is the distance between a low income and a high income household, or what is the ratio of their incomes, e.g. what is the gap between the richest 10% and the poorest 10% (decile) or the richest and poorest 20% (quintile)? A lot of inequality is at the extremes, i.e. within the richest and poorest income groups The measure of inequality most commonly used is the Gini coefficient, which varies between zero – when all households have exactly the same income and one – when one household has all the income. Preferred because it is calculated for everyone in the population. Other measures are sensitive to inequality at the extremes. In 2003 the Gini coefficient for Australia was 0.301 and the 90/10 ratio was around 4 to 1; in the USA, the Gini was 0.381 and the 90/10 ratio was about 6 to 1; in Denmark the Gini was 0.232 and the 90/10 ratio was 2.7 to 1. The ratios of the average incomes of the top decile to the average incomes of the bottom decile were 4.6 to 1 (Denmark), 7.2 to 1 (Australia) and 16 to 1 (USA).

Previous studies A notable recent study of income inequality trends in Australia is the 2011 Fay Gale lecture by Professor Denise Doiron, UNSW. There are a number of similarities between our results and hers, but also some differences. Because our work is interested in long-term trends, we exclude the effects of the improvements made to surveys from 2007-08. Also this work looks mainly at households of working age, rather than all households as in Professor Doiron’s analysis. Despite this, overall trends fairly similar – except Figure 4 in the Fay Gale lecture which shows a decline in real income for the poorest 20% between 2003-07. As shown below we find significant real increases. Note also recent OECD studies, Growing Unequal and Divided We Stand, which also use unadjusted ABS figures.

Situating Australia Internationally

Level of inequality in OECD countries 2008 2005

Change in inequality, OECD countries, 1995 to 2007-08

Sen welfare index, OECD countries, 2008 Mean equivalised income, adjusted to USD (PPPs) and adjusted for inequality

Change in real GDP, Australia and selected OECD countries, 2008 to 2011 Q4 2007=100

Median Australian households have fared extremely well 1998=1 USA Australia

Income inequality: trends and driving forces

Trends in income inequality in Australia, 1981-82 to 2009-10 Gini coefficient

Trends in alternative inequality indicators for working age households, 1981-82 to 2009-10

Patterns of income growth by decile and period, Australia, 1981-82 to 2007-08 Average annual percentage change in real equivalent household income, working age

Components of change in real disposable income, working-age households, 2003-04 to 2007-08

Trends in income inequality in different income components among working age households, Australia, 1982 to 2007-08 Gini coefficient

Redistribution

Assessing redistribution Redistribution refers to the outcomes of different tax and benefit systems – how much do the benefit and tax systems actually change the distribution of household income? Conventionally measured by comparing measures of income inequality at different stages in the income accounting framework: Difference between inequality in market and gross incomes is measured as the impact of social security benefits, Difference between inequality in gross and disposable incomes is measured as the impact of taxation. Redistribution is the product of the volume of taxes and benefits and their distribution across income groups (progressivity). Possible to disaggregate inequality by income sources, type of household (family composition) or location.

Trends in income inequality in different income measures among working age households, Australia, 1982 to 2007-08

Reduction in inequality among households of working age, Australia, 1982 to 2007-08 Point difference in Gini coefficient

Trends in progressivity of transfers and taxes for working age households, 1982 to 2007-08 Concentration coefficient Transfers Taxes

Average tax rates (%) by deciles of household income, 1982, 1996-97 and 2007-08

Assessing income inequality trends Trends in inequality differ by time period, income components and income measures. Thus, there is no single trend, but the complex interaction of multiple influences. Market income inequality rose in period of Labor government, mainly reflecting higher joblessness and wider wage dispersion. Disposable income inequality rose significantly less (about 1/3 as great), reflecting both transfer and tax changes. Despite increasing wage dispersion, market income inequality fell from 1996-97 to 2007-08, mainly because of increased family earnings, particularly for women. Capital income inequality rose significantly after 2003, but insufficient to offset lower inequality in earnings. The effectiveness of the tax system in reducing inequality was stable in the 1980s and early 1990s, but reduced after 1996. Average tax rates fell most for the highest decile (about 4 percentage points). The effectiveness of the transfer system in reducing inequality increased by about 40% in the period of the Labor government, but fell back to its original level by 2007-08. This does not necessarily reflect explicit policy change, but rising earnings among lower income groups lead to a scaling back of income support , heightened by indexation of key benefits to prices.

Joblessness is a major source of inequality in Australia Earnings represent around three-quarters of total pre-tax household income, the largest single component. In 1983, a full-time worker at the 90th percentile earned 2.0 times as much as a worker at the 10th percentile- this disparity increased to 2.3 in 1996, 2.5 in 2004, and 2.8 in 2009-10. In 1982 a working-age family at the 90th percentile earned 112 times as much as a family at the 10th percentile – this disparity reduced to 56 times as much in 1996 and 49 times as much in 2009-10. Benefits reduce inequality more than taxes When social security benefits are added in, this disparity was reduced to 9.8 times as much in 1982, 10.2 times as much in 1996 and 11.4 times as much in 2009-10. Taxes reduced the disparity to 8.0 to 1 in 1982, 7.5 to 1 in 1996 and 9.6 to 1 in 2009-10. But you also need taxes to pay for benefits

Income measures and concepts are important Inequality is lower the longer the time period over which it is measured – between 2001 and 2009 the Gini coefficient went from 0.306 in 2000, 0.300 in 2003, 0.312 in 2007 and 2008 and 0.299 in 2009; inequality over a two-year period varied between 0.286 and 0.295; inequality over a four year period varied between 0.273 and 0.282; inequality over the 9 years was 0.263. Broader measures of resources also suggest lower inequality, particularly the addition of non-cash benefits (health, education, community services) even after subtracting indirect taxes. For example, the 90/10 ratio for disposable income in 2009-10 was 3.9 to 1, but for “final income” it was 2.65 to 1. Inequality is mainly reduced by raising the bottom not reducing the top: Direct taxes and cash transfers increase the incomes of the 10th percentile by 231% and lower the income of the 90th percentile by 19%; The net effect of Indirect benefits and taxes is to raise the 10th percentile by a further 50% and raise the 90th percentile by 1%.

Additional material

Inequality is lower the longer the time period over which it is measured

Inequality of earnings among households of working age, 2005 Gini coefficients for different earnings measures

Trends in earnings inequality for full-time workers, Australia, 1975 to 2008

Trends in poverty, Australia, 1982 to 2009-10

Trends in income inequality (Gini coefficient) among households with a head aged 65 years and over, Australia, 2000-2001 to 2009-10