PCP Microeconomics Session 12 Takako Fujiwara-Greve.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Optimal Contracts under Adverse Selection
Advertisements

Hal Varian Intermediate Microeconomics Chapter Thirty-Six
Optimal Contracts under Adverse Selection. What does it mean Adverse Selection (AS)? There is an AS problem when: before the signing of the contract,
Chapter 37 Asymmetric Information In reality, it is often the case that one of the transacting party has less information than the other. Consider a market.
Michael R. Baye, Managerial Economics and Business Strategy, 3e. ©The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., 1999 Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter.
Moral hazard and contracts
Chapter 14 Markets with Asymmetric Information. Chapter 17Slide 2 Topics to be Discussed Quality Uncertainty and the Market for Lemons Market Signaling.
Vicki Curtis, Jeremy Wei, Jordan Hill, Cody Rice.
1 . 2 Uncertainty Dixit: Optimization in Economic Theory (Chapter 9)
Contracts and Mechanism Design What Contracts Accomplish Moral Hazard Adverse Selection (if time: Signaling)
14.1 Economic settings in which one side has better information than the other. Buying a Company Firm T is worth $20 a share or $80 (50-50 chances) depending.
Recruitment and effort of teachers The principal-agent problem Kjell G. Salvanes.
Interactions of Tax and Nontax Costs n Uncertainty u Symmetric uncertainty u Strategic uncertainty (information asymmetry) F Hidden action (moral hazard)
Economics 410 Managerial Economics Thursday September 23, 1999.
Chapter 19 Contracts and Moral Hazards
L25 Asymmetric Information. Structure of the course 1) Consumers choice 2) Equilibrium, Producers (Pareto efficiency) 3) Market Failures - fixed cost:
Asymmetric Information ECON 370: Microeconomic Theory Summer 2004 – Rice University Stanley Gilbert.
Management Motivation Theories
Chapter 9 THE ECONOMICS OF INFORMATION Copyright ©2002 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. MICROECONOMIC THEORY BASIC.
Managerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 5e Managerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 5e Chapter 15: Incentive Compensation McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
Confronting Moral Hazard: Economic Incentives Ignore other incentives? Pride Opinion of peers The general good Ethical considerations Adam Smith Theory.
The Organization of the Firm
Steven Landsburg, University of Rochester Chapter 18 Risk and Uncertainty Copyright ©2005 by Thomson South-Western, a part of the Thomson Corporation.
Harcourt Brace & Company Chapter 7 Consumers, Producers and the Efficiency of Markets.
Game Theory “A little knowledge is a dangerous thing. So is a lot.” - Albert Einstein Topic 7 Information.
Principal - Agent Games. Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help,
Semester 2, Seminar 7 – Contracting & Accounting Information Financial Accounting.
Chapter 37 Asymmetric Information. Information in Competitive Markets In purely competitive markets all agents are fully informed about traded commodities.
Asymmetric Information
© 2006 Pearson Education Canada Inc.9-1 Conflict Resolution Game Theory Agency Theory.
Copyright © 2009 by Pearson Education Canada Chapter 9 An Analysis of Conflict.
D.M. KREPS CH 16MORAL HAZARD AND INCENTIVES 1 INTRODUCTION MORAL HAZARD MORAL HAZARD ; When one party to a transaction may undertake certain actions that.
Lecture 2 in Contracts Employment Contracts This lecture studies how those who create and administer organizations design the incentives and institutional.
The Moral Hazard Problem Stefan P. Schleicher University of Graz
Health Economics Unit Definition of Economics  Demand − relationship between quantities and prices that addresses how much bought at each price.
Externalities.
Economics of Strategy Slide show prepared by Richard PonArul California State University, Chico  John Wiley  Sons, Inc. Chapter 14 Agency and Performance.
Frank Cowell: Microeconomics Contract Design MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell Almost essential Adverse selection Almost essential Adverse.
Micro E conomics Unit 7 Slide 1 Created: Jan by Jim Luke. Are you paid what you are worth? Anybody you know who is “overpaid”?
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 37 Asymmetric Information.
Asymmetric Information
Managerial Effort Incentives and Market Collusion Cécile Aubert University of Bordeaux (GREThA) and Toulouse School of Economics (LERNA) ACLE 2009.
QR 24 Economics Review Session 12/3/2009. Agenda Demand curves Supply curves Equilibrium Market failures – Moral hazard – Adverse selection Net Present.
Chapter 4 The Adverse Selection Problem Stefan P. Schleicher University of Graz Economics of Information Incentives and Contracts.
Contracting The incentives of the employer (principal) and employee (agent) are different. A contract is designed to implement an outcome both parties.
Lecture 5 Financial Incentives This lecture is paired with our previous one that discussed employee benefits. Here we focus on the reasons why monetary.
ECO 340: Micro Theory Optimal Contracts Sami Dakhlia U. of Southern Mississippi
© 2010 Institute of Information Management National Chiao Tung University Chapter 7 Incentive Mechanism Principle-Agent Problem Production with Teams Competition.
Frank Cowell: Contract Design CONTRACT DESIGN MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell July Almost essential: Adverse selection Almost.
Frank Cowell: Microeconomics Moral Hazard MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell Almost essential Risk Almost essential Risk Prerequisites.
Review Monopoly Summary A monopoly is a firm that is the sole seller in its market. It faces a downward-sloping demand curve for its product. A.
The Base Model. Objectives of the chapter Describe the basic elements of the Basic Principal-Agent model Study the contracts that will emerge when information.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2004 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Chapter 2 Objective and Risk Management.
Microeconomics Course E John Hey. Chapter 26 Because we are all enjoying risk so much, I have decided not to cover Chapter 26 (on the labour market)
Economics 410 Managerial Economics Sunday September 26, 1999.
AGENCY AND PERFORMANCE MEASUREMENT. The Principal/Agent Framework Agency Problem/Agency Conflict : # Principal's objection is to maximize value its receive.
Copyright ©2015 Pearson Education, Inc. All rights reserved.20-1 Topics 1.The Principal-Agent Problem. 2.Using Contracts to Reduce Moral Hazard. 3.Monitoring.
Chapter 3 An Overview of the Healthcare Financing System Copyright 2015 Health Administration Press1.
Chapter Thirty-Six Asymmetric Information. Information in Competitive Markets u In purely competitive markets all agents are fully informed about traded.
Asymmetric Information
Asymmetric Information
Asymmetric Information
Asymmetric Information
Asymmetric Information
Lecture 8 Asymmetric Information: Adverse Selection
RKO Warner Video Videotape rental firm in NYC Problems
Markets with Asymmetric Information
Chapter 19 Contract Theory
Asymmetric Information
Chapter 38 Asymmetric Information
Presentation transcript:

PCP Microeconomics Session 12 Takako Fujiwara-Greve

Homework 10 Real-world Externalities Noise, pirating music CDs, blocking sunlight of neighbors, land price near a new railway Recycling may be positive externalities to future generation Studying with highly motivated friends

Kreps 14.1 (a) commute time via the bridge = 30 + n B /20k = commute time via the tunnel = 40 + (400k - n B )/5000 n B = 360,000 n T = 40,000  30 + nB/20k = 48 minutes (b) total commute time = n B ·48 + n T · 48 = 400 k · 48 =19.2 million minutes

14.1 (c ) Minimize n B (30 +n B /20k) + (400k - n B ) (40 + (400k - n B )/5000) By differentiation n B /2000 = 0 n* B = 340,000 n* T = 60,000  Commute time  Bridge k/20k =47 min.  Tunnel k/5k =52 min. (d) impose toll of 0.5 for the bridge

Kreps, 15.2

EU approach Jo: EU from the gamble = 0.25 · · 0.49 = Utility from sure $7500 ≈ 0.65 Jack: EU =0.25 √45, √5000 ≈ Utility from sure $7500 = √12500 ≈ Jim: EU = 0.25 √90, √50,000 ≈ Utility from sure $7500 = √57500 ≈239.79

Solving for Certainty Equivalent Jack x = ( ) => CE ≈ 6250 < 7500 Jim x + 50,000 = ( ) => CE ≈ 8905>

Kreps, 15.3 (a) 40, · 750,000 = 2500

Moral Hazard Insured factory owner: will she take care of dangerous things well? Workers: will they work hard when they are not supervised? Partnership: will partners work hard to increase the joint profit? Actions of one party affects the welfare of others, where the interests of the parties are not the same

Incentives Direct financial incentives  If you work hard, I pay you more Reciprocity, reputation  If you are nice to others, others will be nice to you later Intrinsic motivation, social norm  Feel proud or feel guilty for being bad

Solution 1: write a contract Determine the “correct” action Write it in the contract Problem How can we monitor/measure/prove?

Solution 2: Put all responsibility on the person who takes actions No insurance Tie payment to the worker’s sales Problem No risk sharing Simultaneous moral hazard

Fundamental problems with incentives The desired actions cannot be specified contractually  Measurement, monitoring, enforceability Even if the desired action is taken, there is uncertainty about the consequences Loading the full consequences on the party taking actions is undesirable  Could share the risk and improve all

Salesperson Compensation Sale --> you (employer) get $60,000 No sale -->you get $0 Salesperson’s choices disutility  Kills himself: sale with prob  Works hard: sale with prob  Not hard: sale with prob  Loafs: sale with prob S’s utility √wage - disutility Outside opportunity: $10,000 w/ no disutility  Employer must give at least utility 100 Employer: risk neutral

If you can specify an effort level in a contract “S chooses effort level A and be paid X if a sale is made and Y if not” Efficient risk sharing: X = Y No effort is ok: √w - 0 ≥100 w = $10,000  Employer’s profit = (0.05)(60,000) - 10,000 = Let him try: √w - 10 ≥100 w = $12,100  Profit = (0.25)(60,000) - 12,100 = 2900

Work hard: √w - 20 ≥100 w = 14,400  Profit = (0.4) (60,000) - 14,400 = 9600 Kill himself: √w - 40 ≥100 w = 19,600  Profit = (0.5)(60,000) - 19,600 = 10,400 Optimal action for the employer = killing level

If effort is not contractable If S is risk neutral, put all risk on him But S is risk averse… Shall the employer take all risk? No! Then S will not make any effort  C.f: pride, reputation, promotion…

Try a bonus contract Base wage = 9500 Bonus = 15,000 if and only if a sale is made quit 100 loaf0.95 √ √ 245,000 = √ √ 245, = try hard kills 0.6√ √ 245, = √ √ 245, =

For this bonus contract Salesperson will try but not hard Profit = 0.25 · 60, · 15,000 = 1750 Trade-off Efficient risk sharing => put risk on the employer Motivation => tie the wage to outcomes (risky) Optimal solution: compromise of these

To find “optimal” contract That maximizes the profit Step 1: For each of possible effort level (action), what is the cheapest way to motivate him to do? Step 2: Which effort level (with the cheapest contract) maximizes your profit?

Problem 19.1: Let’s solve! Find the cheapest (wage, bonus) to induce “try but not hard” level of effort b= utility from base wage x= utility from base wage + bonus quit 100 loaf0.95 b x 0.75 b x -10 try hard kills 0.6 b x b x - 40

Only two binding constraints To maximize your profit we only need to satisfy Participation constraint 0.75 b x - 10 = 100  > would also work, but why pay more? Incentive constraint (not to choose easier action) 0.75 b x - 10 = 0.95 b x  Check later that other effort levels are not better

Solution b=97.5, x=147.5 => base wage = , bonus = 12,250  0.5 b x - 40 < 0.6 b x - 20 < 0.75 b x - 10 ok Your profit 0.25 (60, ,756.25) ( ) =

To “induce”? loafing Participation constraint only No need to give him a bonus Base wage = 10,000 bonus =0 Your profit = 0.05· = -7000

To induce hard work Participation constraint 0.6 b x - 20 = 100 Incentive constraint 0.6 b x - 20 = 0.75 b x - 10  Check others of course Solution: b = , x = 160 Base wage = , bonus = 16,889 Your profit =

To induce killing level Participation constraint 0.5 b x - 40 = 100 Incentive constraint 0.5 b x - 40 = 0.6 b x - 20 =>b = 40, x = 240 Base wage = 1600, bonus = 56,000 Your profit = 400

Therefore… If the action can be specified in a contract, killing level was optimal and your profit = 10,400

Suggested Exercises Kreps, Problem 19.3 Answers to the above will be posted in my website on Friday 15th  For a limited time, probably until early August You can pick up your homework 11 anytime at my office from 15th (I hope). Answers are posted asap.

Summary of the Course Optimization  Marginal X, supply, demand, price discrimination … Market equilibrium Efficiency, surplus Externalities Risk and expected utility Hidden information (Adverse selection) Moral hazard

Towards the final… 1 sheet of A4-size paper, EJ, JE dictionary (incl. electronic ones) You all did fine in homeworks Review concepts Review computations  But it will not be very complex (like opening a root) What is important?