Empowerment and Efficiency: Tenancy Reform in West Bengal

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
AD and AS Tragakes 2012, chapter 9. Aggregate Demand Aggregate Demand (AD): The total quantity of aggregate output, or real GDP, that all buyers in an.
Advertisements

Introduction Describe what panel data is and the reasons for using it in this format Assess the importance of fixed and random effects Examine the Hausman.
DEMOGRAPHIC CHANGE, THE IMPACT MODEL, AND FOOD SECURITY IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA Kevin J.A. Thomas and Tukufu Zuberi.
PERFECT COMPETITION Economics – Course Companion
1 STRUCTURAL ECONOMIC CHANGES IN CHINA AND VIETNAM: POLICY ISSUES AND CONSEQUENCES FOR AGRICULTURE Clem Tisdell Professor Emeritus School of Economics.
© 2003 Prentice Hall Business PublishingMacroeconomics, 3/eOlivier Blanchard Prepared by: Fernando Quijano and Yvonn Quijano 12 C H A P T E R Technological.
Economic Growth in Mozambique Experience & Policy Challenges Crispolti, V. (AFR) Vitek, F. (SPR)
1 SSS II Lecture 1: Correlation and Regression Graduate School 2008/2009 Social Science Statistics II Gwilym Pryce
The transmission mechanism of monetary policy Banco Central do Brasil conference: “One year of inflation targeting” 10th July 2000 Alec Chrystal Bank of.
Economic Theory, 3 rd Stage Prepared by Nyaz Najmadin To Accompany Principles of Macroeconomics, fifth edition, 2009 By N. Gregory Makiw.
Openness, Economic Growth, and Human Development: Evidence from South Asian countries from Middlesex University Department of Economics and.
Chapter 17 Unemployment, Inflation, and Growth. 2 Introduction In Chapter 4, 5, 6, we have studied a classical model of the complete economy, but said.
Performance of World Economies Gavin Cameron Monday 25 July 2005 Oxford University Business Economics Programme.
Poverty and Income Distribution in Ethiopia: By Abebe Shimeles, PhD.
A Comparative Analysis of Technical Efficiency of Tobacco and Maize Farmers in Tabora- Tanzania A.Kidane; A.Hepelwa; E.Ngeh & T. W. Hu This study was supported.
Squeezing more out of existing data sources: Small Area Estimation of Welfare Indicators Berk Özler The World Bank Development Research Group, Poverty.
Economic Growth Chapter 17. Introduction Two definitions of economic growth (from Chapter 8) – The increase in real GDP, which occurs over a period of.
Policy Issues of EDRC Models Ex-ante Poverty Impact Assessment of Macroeconomic Policies International Workshop Washington, D.C. October 14-15, 2003 Aghasi.
The 8-7 National Poverty Reduction Program in China: the National Strategy and its Impact Wang Sangui, Li Zhou, Ren Yanshun.
The challenge of sustainable
Chapter 9 Economic Growth and Rising Living Standards
Agricultural Technology, Productivity, and Poverty in Madagascar Bart Minten Chris Barrett February 2006.
Why Has Income Inequality in Thailand Increased? An Analysis Using Surveys.
Growth of the Economy And Cyclical Instability
International Issues.
Economies of Scale Is Bigger Really Better?. Economies of Scale Economies of scale refers to the phenomena of decreased per unit cost as the number of.
Regression Method.
Equity and efficiency impacts of rural land rental restrictions : Evidence from India Land Policies & Legal Empowerment of the Poor Nov 3, 2006 H.K. Nagarajan,
Matching Methods. Matching: Overview  The ideal comparison group is selected such that matches the treatment group using either a comprehensive baseline.
 Circular Flow of Income is a simplified model of the economy that shows the flow of money through the economy.
Lessons and implications for agriculture and food Security in the region IFPRI-ADB POLICY FORUM 9-10 August 2007 Manila, Philippines Rapid Growth of Selected.
Land Rental Markets in the Process of Structural Transformation: Productivity and Equity Impacts in China Songqing Jin and Klaus Deininger World Bank.
Welfare Reform and Lone Parents Employment in the UK Paul Gregg and Susan Harkness.
Centre for Market and Public Organisation Using difference-in-difference methods to evaluate the effect of policy reform on fertility: The Working Families.
Upali Amarasinghe, Stefanos Xenarios Rajendran Srinivasulu, Dhrubra Pant, Madar Samad Water Poverty Analysis IGB Basin Focal project.
Assessing the Distributional Impact of Social Programs The World Bank Public Expenditure Analysis and Manage Core Course Presented by: Dominique van de.
The Land Leverage Hypothesis Land leverage reflects the proportion of the total property value embodied in the value of the land (as distinct from improvements),
Spatial and non spatial approaches to agricultural convergence in Europe Luciano Gutierrez*, Maria Sassi** *University of Sassari **University of Pavia.
Estimation of the pass-through and welfare effects of the tariff reduction for yellow corn in Peru between 2000 and 2011 Cecilia Matta Jara & Ana Vera.
Workshop on Medium Term Outlook for India’s Food Sector Overview of the Issues by by Shashanka Bhide NCAER Project Supported by Food and Agriculture Organisation.
Methodology of Examining the Nexus between Trade Liberalization, Growth and Poverty: Some Thoughts Dr. Selim Raihan Assistant Professor Department of Economics.
HAOMING LIU JINLI ZENG KENAN ERTUNC GENETIC ABILITY AND INTERGENERATIONAL EARNINGS MOBILITY 1.
Public Policy Analysis ECON 3386 Anant Nyshadham.
Answers to Review Questions  1.Explain the difference between aggregate demand and the aggregate quantity demanded of real output. Ceteris paribus, how.
Seðlabanki Íslands Inflation control around the world: Why are some countries more successful than others? Thórarinn G. Pétursson Central Bank of Iceland.
The dynamics of poverty in Ethiopia : persistence, state dependence and transitory shocks By Abebe Shimeles, PHD.
Applying impact evaluation tools A hypothetical fertilizer project.
Answers to Review Questions  1.What are the ultimate targets of monetary policy?  The ultimate targets of monetary policy include stable prices, sustainable.
Targeting of Public Spending Menno Pradhan Senior Poverty Economist The World Bank office, Jakarta.
A Comparison from Matching Surveys in Africa and China: Plan in China Jinxia Wang Center for Chinese Agricultural Policy (CCAP) Chinese Academy of Sciences.
Why is productivity growth so vital? To see more of our products visit our website at Ruth Tarrant, Head of Economics and Politics, Bedales.
Bangladesh Poverty Assessment: Building on Progress Poverty Trends and Profile Dhaka, October 23 rd 2002.
1 AGRARIAN STRUCTURE: The Role of Land Policies Gershon Feder The World Bank.
Assessing the Impact of Informality on Wages in Tanzania: Is There a Penalty for Women? Pablo Suárez Robles (University Paris-Est Créteil) 1.
Www. CEFIR.ru Institutional determinants of deregulation Evgeny Yakovlev and Ekaterina Zhuravskaya.
Land Rental in Ethiopia Marshallian inefficiency or factor market imperfections and tenure insecurity as binding constraints? Klaus Deininger, Daniel Ayalew,
Cross-Country Workshop for Impact Evaluations in Agriculture and Community Driven Development Addis Ababa, April 13-16, Causal Inference Nandini.
Competition Policy and Economic Growth: Evidence from Latin America Esteban Greco Diego Petrecolla Carlos A. Romero.
Modeling Poverty Martin Ravallion Development Research Group, World Bank.
Assessing Long Run Structural Change in Multi-Sector General Equilibrium Models Roberto Roson Dept. Economics, Ca’Foscari University, Venice and IEFE Bocconi.
Measuring Results and Impact Evaluation: From Promises into Evidence
Songqing Jin – Michigan State University Klaus Deininger – World Bank
Klaus Deininger, Songqing Jin, Vandana Yadav
Luciano Gutierrez*, Maria Sassi**
The Fluctuation in the price of rice market
Ch. 13. Pooled Cross Sections Across Time: Simple Panel Data.
Evaluating Impacts: An Overview of Quantitative Methods
Dr. Selim Raihan Assistant Professor Department of Economics
Ch. 13. Pooled Cross Sections Across Time: Simple Panel Data.
Presentation transcript:

Empowerment and Efficiency: Tenancy Reform in West Bengal Abhijit V. Banerjee, Paul J. Gertler, Maitreesh Ghatak (April 2002)

Recalling dual impact of reforms on productivity Bargaining power effect of the reform The legal contract becomes the tenant’s “outside option,” which increases his bargaining power vis-a`-vis the landlord and forces the landlord to offer him a higher crop share, which translates into stronger incentives An increase in the tenant’s bargaining power, with everything else held constant, leads to an increase in his share and productivity Security of tenure effect of the reform The landlord may use the threat of eviction when output is low to induce the tenant to work harder and disallowing eviction restricts the use of such incentives and therefore reduces efficiency But greater security of tenure encourages the tenant to invest more since it gives him the confidence that he will stay on the land long enough to enjoy the fruits of his investment

Net effect of Operation Barga – negative or positive? From the theoretical analysis we know that tenancy laws that lead to improved crop shares and higher security of tenure for tenants can have a positive effect on productivity Since Operation Barga both eliminated evictions and increased (m), its net effect could be positive or negative The model says that the tenant’s share of the crop should go up, or at least not go down, when (m) goes up There is evidence based on Operation Barga that explains around 28 % of the subsequent growth of agricultural productivity NOTE: We know from the aggregate data that the tenants responded positively to the reform: By 1993, about 65% of all sharecroppers were registered, compared to 15% before Operation Barga

Evidence from author’s sample The proportion of tenants getting more than 50% of output increased from 17 % to 39% post reform The increase in share was greater for registered tenants than unregistered

Evidence on the effect of Operation Barga on productivity Quasi-experimental approach* that uses Bangladesh as a control (similar to West Bengal in most productivity trends and agriculture related criterion such as agro climatic conditions, main crops grown, prevalence of tenancy, and agricultural technology (HYV) ) The fact that Operation Barga was implemented in West Bengal but not in Bangladesh can be largely attributed to an exogenous shock**. Program intensity approach that uses the number of registered sharecroppers in a district as a measure of program intensity and compares the growth in productivity in districts in which Operation Barga was implemented intensely to districts in which the program was implemented less intensely *A quasi-experiment is an empirical study used to estimate the causal impact of an intervention on its target population but it specifically lacks the element of random assignment to treatment or control. This is more of a natural experiment as assignment discretion doesn’t lie with the researcher. ** National political upheaval (Not factors affecting only West Bengal) caused the Left to come into control.

COMPARISON TO BANGLADESH

Rice yield trend comparison Between 1969 and 1978, rice yields increased by 9.3% in West Bengal and by 11% in Bangladesh (similar trend line: comparable baseline characteristics) In the period after Operation Barga was introduced (1979–93), rice yields in West Bengal increased by 69% compared to 44% in Bangladesh Agricultural productivity increased in part due to Green Revolution’s HYV seeds, fall in fertilizer price, increase in small scale pvt irrigation

Empirical methodology The authors measure the impact of Operation Barga on agricultural rice yields using a difference-in-difference estimator with district-level panel data. The difference-in-difference specification compares the change (before and after Operation Barga) in yields in treatment districts (West Bengal) with the corresponding change in control districts (Bangladesh) The difference-in-difference model makes the counterfactual assumption that the treatment districts would grow at the same rate as the control districts if there were no intervention The authors control for public irrigation and adoption of HYV grains of rice, since these are interventions that were contemporaneous with Operation Barga and were differentially implemented in West Bengal and Bangladesh

Simple Difference-in-Difference (Growth in yield) ss intensely NOTE: The data are district-level data from 14 West Bengal and 15 Bangladesh districts collected from various official government sources, and we expect the last time period to have the full effect of the reform, and * (LOS 10%), ** (LOS 5%), *** (LOS 1%)

Adjusted Difference-in-Difference: Time varying controls Model1: simple unadjusted difference-in-difference model Model 2: controlling for public irrigation and rainfall Model 3: additionally controlled for HYV share Period: 1977-91 (due to data availability), thus sample size is different

Possible problem with the methodology There may be unobserved differences in government programs between the two countries and if these unobserved programs behaved like the observed programs (Operation Barga) and also expanded faster in Bangladesh in the post–Operation Barga period, our difference-in-difference estimates of the impact of Operation Barga on agricultural productivity would give us a lower-bound estimate. The authors cannot completely rule out the possibility that there were unobservable policies that confound the estimated effect The drought could have affected effort on part of the West Bengal government.

PROGRAM INTENSITY APPROACH

The basic approach The approach taken uses the district sharecropper registration rate as a measure of program intensity and then examines whether productivity rises faster in areas with greater program intensity In 1978 (program launch), the average level of registration for West Bengal was 15% and in 1993 stood at 65% of the total number of sharecroppers (Increase in take-up rate: (0.65-0.15)/0.15 = 58% The authors add data on the length of roads constructed and maintained by the public works department to the set of time-varying controls for West Bengal used in the previous analysis

Empirical methodology Identification issues: Since the registration rate may be correlated with unobserved productivity shocks Due to a combination of the supply and demand of registration opportunities, as well as non random selection of villages to offer registration (registration opportunity at their doorstep was extremely important for tenants in rural areas) DEMAND SIDE: A tenant’s decision to register is likely to be affected by his ability, wealth, relations with the landlord, and other characteristics that are associated empowerment and efficiency with his dependence on the landlord (e.g., for loans) or his bargaining power The wealthier, more able, and more enterprising tenants are likely to be more productive and adopt productivity-enhancing technology, and more likely to register A district with a higher proportion of more productive tenants is likely to have high output as well as high registration => However, as long as individual characteristics are constant over time, they should not be a problem as long as we allow for district fixed effects

Identification issues SUPPLY SIDE: The geographic distribution of sharecroppers within a district varied across districts, and as a result, the marginal cost of making registration opportunities available to tenants varied across districts If the government introduced registration opportunities in districts of high (or low) productivity first, then the registration rate would be correlated with unobserved productivity characteristics If allocations were based on initial productivity, which is a time-invariant factor, the district fixed effects control for this source of bias If the government dynamically allocated registration opportunities on the basis of current productivity in the district, then the fixed-effects estimate will be biased A similar problem could occur if the order of villages selected within a district was based on productivity

Identification issues Identification issues: Since the registration rate may be correlated with unobserved productivity shocks: Due to correlation with the progression of other (omitted) programs: Expansion of infrastructure in West Bengal: Controlling for availability of public irrigation and roads within districts HYV seeds spread during this period: Controlling by including the share of gross cropped area planted with HYV seeds Bias in Left front districts: A Left Front majority district (in 1977) dummy variable interacted with time Proximity to Calcutta (admin. Centre): The interaction of a southern district dummy variable with time Registration targeted at high sharecroppers regions: The initial extent of sharecropping interacted with time dummies as additional explanatory variables

> Productivity rise of ~20% (owing to registration: 0.36*0.58) > A weighted average used to evaluate full impact ~ 28% (total increase in rice yield: 69%)

Conclusion We concluded from the theoretical analysis that tenancy laws that lead to improved crop shares and higher security of tenure for tenants can have a positive effect on productivity Evidence from West Bengal suggests that the tenancy reform program called Operation Barga explains around 28% of the subsequent growth of agricultural productivity there However, given data limitations, we cannot separate the direct and indirect effects of Operation Barga (like empowerment of the poor, change in society’s mindset of collective action)

Land Reform, Poverty Reduction, and Growth: Evidence from India Timothy Besley and Robin Burgess (May, 2000)

Introduction (1/2) Land reforms in developing countries are often aimed at improving the poor's access to land, although their effectiveness has often been hindered by political constraints on implementation India is an important case study of land reform: It is home to a significant fraction of the poor in the developing world and in the post independence period we have been subjected to the largest body of land reform legislation ever to have been passed in so short a time period in any country This paper studies land reform as a redistributive policy as improvement in the asset base of the poor has been viewed as a central strategy to relieve endemic poverty The authors attempt to study the growth-inequality interaction in this context

Introduction (2/2) This paper takes advantage of the state level panel data available for the 16 main Indian states from 1958-1992 to assess the real impact on the conditions of the poor of the land reform legislation, and on overall growth Most existing empirical evidence on the links between redistribution and growth comes from cross-country data wherein there are insurmountable problems of comparability of data across countries and concerns about endogeneity The fact that this data comes from one country with similar data collection strategies in each state, and the relatively long time period helps to deal with above mentioned endogeneity issues Principal finding: Land reforms do appear to have led to reductions in poverty in India. (This finding is robust to a number of methods of estimation, and the inclusion/exclusion of many different controls)

Background and Data Under the 1949 Indian Constitution, states were granted the powers to enact land reforms and this autonomy ensures that there has been significant variation across states and time in terms of the number and types of land reforms that have been enacted Land reform acts are categorized as per their main purpose: Tenancy reforms : Attempts to regulate tenancy contracts both via registration and stipulation of contractual terms (shares) Abolishing intermediaries: Intermediaries who worked under feudal lords (Zamandari) to collect rent Ceilings on landholdings: Redistributing surplus land to the landless people Consolidation of disparate landholdings: Aimed at achieving efficiency gains

Background and Data Poverty measures : The headcount index and the poverty gap have been employed. Given that NSS surveys are not annual, weighted interpolation has been used to obtain values between surveys. The all-India rural headcount measure has fallen from around 55 % to 40 %, and the rural poverty gap from 19 % to around 10 % Agricultural wage : Data were also collected to enable us to examine whether land reforms had general equilibrium effects and were thus capable of reaching groups of the poor (e.g., landless laborers) who did not directly benefit from the reforms Output: Real values of per capita agricultural, nonagricultural, and combined state domestic product are also available to examine the determinants of growth Measure of agricultural yields: Defined as real agricultural state domestic product divided by the net sown area. This crudely captures technological changes in agriculture Public finance data: Taken at the state level, collected chiefly as a means to control for other government interventions besides land reform Poverty measures are based on consumption distributions from 22 rounds of the (NSS). The poverty line is based on a nutritional norm of 2400 calories per day and is defined as the level of average per capita total expenditure

Empirical approach: Panel data regression The empirical approach is to run panel data regressions of the form: (1) x(st) is some measure of poverty in state s at time t Alpha (s) is a state fixed effect Beta (t) is a year dummy variable y(st) is a vector of variables that we treat as exogenous l(st-4) is the stock of past land reforms four periods previously E (st) is an error term which we model as AR(1) process where the degree of autocorrelation is state-specific: NOTE: The approach is also reduced form because land reform legislation is used as regressor-we are unable to measure whether land reforms are actually implemented

Empirical approach: Panel data regression Estimation via GLS will also allow for heteroskedasticity in the error structure with each state having its own error variance. Equation (1) is a reduced-form model of the impact of land reform Effect of land reform on poverty is picked up by that variable along with other effects that change the claims that tenants have to land Land reform is represented only by the cumulative land reform variable where all types of land reforms are aggregated NOTE: The approach is also reduced form because land reform legislation is used as regressor-we are unable to measure whether land reforms are actually implemented

(1) Only state and year effects CHANGES IN (1) – (8): (1) Only state and year effects (2) Using interpolated years when NSS n.a. (3) Disaggregation into various reforms (4) Using head count index (alternative) (5) Urban poverty gap checked for (no significant negative association) (6) Capturing closing rural urban poverty gap (given non response of urban poverty gap) (7) Disaggregated impact of land reforms (8) Checking with head count rural-urban difference

If land reform pushes up agricultural wages, this represents an additional mechanism through which these reforms can reduce rural poverty The results illustrate an indirect route through which land reform may positively affect the welfare of landless laborers even if they do not benefit directly from the reform

Disaggregated land reform variables lagged four periods have no significant impact on total state income per capita Suggests that tenancy reform has a negative effect on agricultural output with land consolidation having the opposite effect (no other effects observed) Shows that both the tenancy reform and land consolidation effects are robust to including our other policy variables lagged four years Effects remain when agricultural yields rather than income per capita is the left-hand-side variable Effect of tenancy reform is robust to including other policy variables

Interpreting the results Results hint at an equity-efficiency trade- off for tenancy reforms- both poverty and output per capita are lower after such reforms are enacted No such trade-off emerges for abolition of intermediaries Ceilings on landholdings do not seem to have an effect on either output measures or poverty, while land consolidation promotes output increases in agriculture without affecting poverty >> Overall, these results suggest that the impact on poverty comes mainly through reforms that affect production relations, rather than by altering the distribution of land

Conclusion Robust evidence of a link between poverty reduction and two kinds of land reform legislation - tenancy reform and abolition of intermediaries Land reform can benefit the landless by raising agricultural wages Even partial, second-best reforms which mainly affect production relations in agriculture can play a significant role in reducing rural poverty The analysis suggests that a reduction of the all-India poverty gap of 1% can be explained by land reform (one-tenth of the actual reduction in poverty over the period) (This remains true even after factoring in the possibility that output per capita is reduced by some kinds of land reform) This comparison suggests that implementing a land reform has a similar effect on poverty reduction to a 10% rise in per capita income, or around 4-5 years growth at the all-India average growth rate over this period

THANK YOU!