If cost is given as a function of Q, then For example: TC = 10,000 + 200 Q + 1.5 Q 2 MC = ? While dealing with discrete data, Marginal cost Production.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. Monopolistic competition is a market structure in which A large number of firms compete. Each firm produces a differentiated.
Advertisements

Chapter 12 Managerial Decisions for Firms with Market Power
Managerial Decisions for Firms with Market Power
The Demand for Labor The Demand for Labor The demand for labor is a derived demand. Employer’s demand for labor is a function of the characteristics of.
14 Perfect Competition CHAPTER Notes and teaching tips: 4, 7, 8, 9, 25, 26, 27, and 28. To view a full-screen figure during a class, click the red “expand”
When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Explain a perfectly competitive firm’s profit-
Production. Costs Problem 6 on p.194. OutputFCVCTCAFCAVCATCMC 010,
11 CHAPTER Perfect Competition
15 Monopoly.
© 2010 Pearson Education. Fifty years ago, when Dan Carney opened his first Pizza Hut in Wichita, he had a local monopoly. But today the pizza market.
Monopoly While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker. A firm is considered a monopoly if it is the sole seller of.
Eco 101 Principles of Microeconomics Consumer Choice Production & Costs Market Structures Resource Markets
Lecture 4: The Demand for Labor
Managerial Decisions for Firms with Market Power
Perfect Competition Principles of Microeconomics Boris Nikolaev
Types of Market Structure
Introduction to Monopoly. The Monopolist’s Demand Curve and Marginal Revenue Recall: Optimal output rule: a profit-maximizing firm produces the quantity.
Monopolistic Competition
Chapter EightCopyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall. 1 Chapter 8-B Pricing and Output Decisions: Perfect Competition and Monopoly.
Economic Applications of Functions and Derivatives
AP microeconomics Semester Review.
The Demand For Resources Chapter 12 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2009 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
Copyright © 2008 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Managerial Economics, 9e Managerial Economics Thomas Maurice.
Market Structure In economics, market structure (also known as market form) describes the state of a market with respect to competition. The major market.
Chapter 12: Managerial Decisions for Firms with Market Power
Chapter 15 notes Monopolies.
Input Demand: Labor and Land Markets
Today Begin Monopoly. Monopoly Chapter 22 Perfect Competition = Many firms Oligopoly = A few firms Four Basic Models Monopoly = One firm Monopolistic.
13 PART 5 Perfect Competition
Short-run Production Function
1 Monopoly and Antitrust Policy Chapter IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND MARKET POWER imperfectly competitive industry An industry in which single firms.
CHAPTER 21 PURE COMPETITION COMPETITION.
The Supply Curve and the Behavior of Firms
Econ 2610: Principles of Microeconomics Yogesh Uppal
Next page Chapter 5: The Demand for Labor. Jump to first page 1. Derived Demand for Labor.
CHAPTER 12 Competition.  What is perfect competition?  How are price and output determined in a competitive industry?  Why do firms enter and leave.
Price Discrimination Price discrimination exist when sales of identical goods or services are transacted at different prices from the same provider Example.
Perfect Competition1 PERFECT COMPETITION ECO 2023 Principles of Microeconomics Dr. McCaleb.
PERFECT COMPETITION 11 CHAPTER. Objectives After studying this chapter, you will able to  Define perfect competition  Explain how price and output are.
Monopolistic Competition CHAPTER 13A. After studying this chapter you will be able to Define and identify monopolistic competition Explain how output.
Chapter 6: Perfectly Competitive Supply
Perfect Competition CHAPTER 10 When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Explain a perfectly.
Managerial Decisions for Firms with Market Power BEC Managerial Economics.
9.1 Input Demand: Labor and Land Markets Input demand is said to be a Derived demand because it is dependent on the demand for the outputs those inputs.
11 CHAPTER Perfect Competition.
Every product is sold in a market that can be considered one of the above market structures. For example: 1.Fast Food Market 2.The Market for Cars 3.Market.
Perfect Competition CHAPTER 11. What Is Perfect Competition? Perfect competition is an industry in which  Many firms sell identical products to many.
Chapter 22: The Competitive Firm Copyright © 2013 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin 13e.
© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What Is Perfect Competition? Perfect competition is an industry in which  Many firms sell identical products to many.
Perfect Competition CHAPTER 11 C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to 1 Explain a perfectly.
Copyright © 2006 Nelson, a division of Thomson Canada Ltd. 15 Monopoly.
Perfect Competition.
Pricing and Output Decisions: Perfect Competition and Monopoly
Chapter 14 Questions and Answers.
© 2010 Pearson Education Canada Perfect Competition ECON103 Microeconomics Cheryl Fu.
Chapter Monopoly 15. In economic terms, why are monopolies bad? Explain. 2.
Producer Choice: The Costs of Production and the Quest for Profit Mr. Griffin AP ECON MHS.
Monopoly CCE ECO 211 REMEDIAL. Section3.1 MONOPOLY A monopoly is a type of an imperfect market. It is a market structure in which a single seller is the.
Lecture 7 Chapter 20: Perfect Competition 1Naveen Abedin.
12 PERFECT COMPETITION. © 2012 Pearson Education.
Review Difference between fixed and variable resources
Unit 4: Imperfect Competition
Short-run Production Function
Costs of Production in the Long-run
AP Microeconomics Review #3 (part 1)
Managerial Decisions for Firms with Market Power
Chapter 7: Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly
Pure Competition Chapter 9.
Introduction Characteristics of Perfect Competition
AP Microeconomics Review Unit 3 (part 1)
Presentation transcript:

If cost is given as a function of Q, then For example: TC = 10, Q Q 2 MC = ? While dealing with discrete data, Marginal cost Production. Costs

Problem 2 on p.194. “Diminishing returns” – what are they? In the short run, every company has some inputs fixed and some variable. As the variable input is added, every extra unit of that input increases the total output by a certain amount; this additional amount is called “marginal product”. The term, diminishing returns, refers to the situation when the marginal product of the variable input starts to decrease (even though the total output may still keep going up!)

Total output, or Total Product, TP Amount of input used Marginal product, MP Range of diminishing returns

KLQMP K Calculating the marginal product (of capital) for the data in Problem 2:

KLQMP K Calculating the marginal product (of capital) for the data in Problem 2:

KLQMP K Calculating the marginal product (of capital) for the data in Problem 2:

In other words, we know we are in the range of diminishing returns when the marginal product of the variable input starts falling, or, the rate of increase in total output slows down. (Ex: An extra worker is not as useful as the one before him) Implications for the marginal cost relationship: Worker #10 costs $8/hr, makes 10 units. MC unit =

In other words, we know we are in the range of diminishing returns when the marginal product of the variable input starts falling, or, the rate of increase in total output slows down. (Ex: An extra worker is not as useful as the one before him) Implications for the marginal cost relationship: Worker #10 costs $8/hr, makes 10 units. MC unit = $0.80 Worker #11 costs $8/hr, makes …

In other words, we know we are in the range of diminishing returns when the marginal product of the variable input starts falling, or, the rate of increase in total output slows down. (Ex: An extra worker is not as useful as the one before him) Implications for the marginal cost relationship: Worker #10 costs $8/hr, makes 10 units. MC unit = $0.80 Worker #11 costs $8/hr, makes 8 units. MC unit =

In other words, we know we are in the range of diminishing returns when the marginal product of the variable input starts falling, or, the rate of increase in total output slows down. (Ex: An extra worker is not as useful as the one before him) Implications for the marginal cost relationship: Worker #10 costs $8/hr, makes 10 units. MC unit = $0.80 Worker #11 costs $8/hr, makes 8 units. MC unit = $1 In the range of diminishing returns, MP of input is falling and MC of output is increasing

Marginal cost, MC Amount of output Amount of input used Marginal product, MP This amount of output corresponds to this amount of input

When MP of input is decreasing, MC of output is increasing and vice versa. Therefore the range of diminishing returns can be identified by looking at either of the two graphs. (Diminishing marginal returns set in at the max of the MP graph, or at the min of the MC graph)

Profit is believed to be the ultimate goal of any firm. In Problem 2, what number of units of capital maximizes the firm’s profit? P K = $75 P L = $15 P OUTPUT = $2 The aggregate approach: KLQVCFCProfit

Profit is believed to be the ultimate goal of any firm. In Problem 2, what number of units of capital maximizes the firm’s profit? P K = $75 P L = $15 P OUTPUT = $2 The aggregate approach: KLQVCFCProfit

Profit is believed to be the ultimate goal of any firm. In Problem 2, what number of units of capital maximizes the firm’s profit? P K = $75 P L = $15 P OUTPUT = $2 The aggregate approach: KLQVCFCProfit

Profit is believed to be the ultimate goal of any firm. In Problem 2, what number of units of capital maximizes the firm’s profit? P K = $75 P L = $15 P OUTPUT = $2 The aggregate approach: KLQVCFCProfit

Principle (Marginal approach to profit maximization): If data is provided in discrete (tabular) form, then profit is maximized by producing all the units for which and stopping right before the unit for which

Principle (Marginal approach to profit maximization): If data is provided in discrete (tabular) form, then profit is maximized by producing all the units for which MR > MC and stopping right before the unit for which MR < MC In our case, price of output stays constant throughout therefore MR = P (an extra unit increases TR by the amount it sells for) If costs are continuous functions of Q OUTPUT, then profit is maximized where

Principle (Marginal approach to profit maximization): If data is provided in discrete (tabular) form, then profit is maximized by producing all the units for which MR > MC and stopping right before the unit for which MR < MC In our case, price of output stays constant throughout therefore MR = P (an extra unit increases TR by the amount it sells for) If costs are continuous functions of Q OUTPUT, then profit is maximized where MR=MC

The marginal approach: To find the profit maximizing amount of input (part d), we need to compare the marginal benefit from a change to the marginal cost of than change. More specifically, we compare VMP K, the value of marginal product of capital, to the price of capital, or the “rental rate”, r. KLQMP K VMP K r

Back to problem 2, p.194. To find the profit maximizing amount of input (part d), we will once again use the marginal approach, which compares the marginal benefit from a change to the marginal cost of than change. More specifically, we compare VMP K, the value of marginal product of capital, to the price of capital, or the “rental rate”, r. KLQMP K VMP K r

Back to problem 2, p.194. To find the profit maximizing amount of input (part d), we will once again use the marginal approach, which compares the marginal benefit from a change to the marginal cost of than change. More specifically, we compare VMP K, the value of marginal product of capital, to the price of capital, or the “rental rate”, r. KLQMP K VMP K r > > > > > < STOP

Back to problem 2, p.194. To find the profit maximizing amount of input (part d), we will once again use the marginal approach, which compares the marginal benefit from a change to the marginal cost of than change. More specifically, we compare VMP K, the value of marginal product of capital, to the price of capital, or the “rental rate”, r. KLQMP K VMP K r > > > > > < STOP

What if the cost of labor (the fixed cost in this case) changes? How does the profit maximization point change? KLQVCFCProfit

What if the cost of labor (the fixed cost in this case) changes? How does the profit maximization point change? KLQVCFCProfit

What if the cost of labor (the fixed cost in this case) changes? How does the profit maximization point change? KLQVCFCProfit

Fixed cost does not affect the firm’s optimal short- term output decision and can be ignored while deciding how much to produce today. Principle: Consistently low profits may induce the firm to close down eventually (in the long run) but not any sooner than your fixed inputs become variable ( your building lease expires, your equipment wears out and new equipment needs to be purchased, you are facing the decision of whether or not to take out a new loan, etc.)

Why would we ever want to be in the range of diminishing returns? Consider the simplest case when the price of output doesn’t depend on how much we produce. Until we get to the DMR range, every next worker is more valuable than the previous one, therefore we should keep hiring them. Only after we get to the DMR range and the MP starts falling, we should consider stopping. Therefore, the profit maximizing point is always in the diminishing marginal returns range! Surprised?

Cost minimization (Another important aspect of being efficient.) Suppose that, contrary to the statement of the last problem, we ARE ABLE to change not just the amount of capital but the amount of labor as well. (Recall the distinction between the long run and the short run.) Given that extra degree of freedom, can we do better? (In other words, is there a better way to allocate our budget to achieve our production goals?)

In order not to get lost in the multiple possible (K, L, Q) combinations, it is useful to have some of them fixed and focus on the question of interest. In our case, we can either: Fix the total budget spent on inputs and see if we can increase the total output; or, Fix the target output and see if we can reduce the total cost by spending our money differently.

Think of the following analogy: Sam needs his 240 mg of caffeine a day or he will fall asleep while driving, and something bad will happen. He can get his caffeine fix from several options listed below: OptionCaffeine, mg Bottled Frappucino, 9.5oz80 Coca-Cola, 12oz 40 Mountain Dew, 12oz60 Which one should he choose?

Think of the following analogy: Sam needs his 240 mg of caffeine a day or he will fall asleep while driving, and something bad will happen. He can get his caffeine fix from several options listed below: OptionCaffeine, mgCost of ‘input’ Bottled Frappucino, 9.5oz80 Coca-Cola, 12oz 40 Mountain Dew, 12oz60

Think of the following analogy: Sam needs his 240 mg of caffeine a day or he will fall asleep while driving, and something bad will happen. He can get his caffeine fix from several options listed below: OptionCaffeine, mgCost of ‘input’ Bottled Frappucino, 9.5oz80$2.00 Coca-Cola, 12oz 40$0.80 Mountain Dew, 12oz60$1.00

Think of the following analogy: Sam needs his 240 mg of caffeine a day or he will fall asleep while driving, and something bad will happen. He can get his caffeine fix from several options listed below: OptionCaffeine, mgCost of ‘input’Mg/$ Bottled Frappucino, 9.5oz80$2.00 Coca-Cola, 12oz 40$0.80 Mountain Dew, 12oz60$1.00

Think of the following analogy: Sam needs his 240 mg of caffeine a day or he will fall asleep while driving, and something bad will happen. He can get his caffeine fix from several options listed below: OptionCaffeine, mgCost of ‘input’Mg/$ Bottled Frappucino, 9.5oz80$ Coca-Cola, 12oz 40$ Mountain Dew, 12oz60$1.0060

Think of the following analogy: Sam needs his 240 mg of caffeine a day or he will fall asleep while driving, and something bad will happen. He can get his caffeine fix from several options listed below: OptionCaffeine, mgCost of ‘input’Mg/$ Bottled Frappucino, 9.5oz80$ Coca-Cola, 12oz 40$ Mountain Dew, 12oz60$1.0060

Next, think of caffeine as Sam’s ‘target output’ (what he is trying to achieve) and drinks as his inputs, which can to a certain extent be substituted for each other. The same principle holds for any production unit that is trying to allocate its resources wisely: In order to achieve the most at the lowest cost possible, a firm should go with the option with the highest MP input /P input ratio. Note that following this principle will make the firm better off regardless of the demand it is facing!

If then - reduce the amount of capital; - increase the amount of labor. If then - reduce the amount of labor; - increase the amount of capital. If then inputs are used in the right proportion. No need to change anything. As you do that, - MP L will decrease; - MP C will increase; - the LHS will get smaller, - the RHS bigger

Profit maximization in different market structures In the Elasticity topic, we discussed a firm facing downward-sloping demand – if a company wants to attract more customers, it has to lower its price. Tonight, we considered examples where the price the firm could get for each unit of out put did not depend on the number of units produced. Which way is right? Which way is more realistic therefore more relevant?

Traditionally, economics textbooks distinguish four types of markets, or of market structures. They differ in the degree of market power an individual firm has: Perfect competition Monopolistic competition Oligopoly Monopoly “Market power” also known as “pricing power” is defined in the managerial literature as the ability of an individual firm to vary its price while still remaining profitable or as the firm’s ability to charge the price above its MC. the least market power the most market power

Perfect competition The features of a perfectly competitive market are: Large number of competing firms; Firms are small relative to the entire market; Products different firms make are identical; Information on prices is readily available.

As a result, the price is set by the interaction of supply and demand forces, and an individual firm can do nothing about the price. P Q This is the story of any small-size firm that cannot differentiate itself from the others.

What does a Total Revenue (TR) graph look like for such a firm, if plotted against quantity produced/sold? Q TR Every unit sells at the same price so… Slope equals price

How about the Marginal Revenue graph? Q MR Every unit sells at the same price so… MR = P

The profit maximization story told graphically: In aggregate terms: Q TR TC FC max capacity Profit max profit

In marginal terms: Q MR MC max profit

Doing the same thing mathematically: TC = Q + 5 Q 2, And the market price is $160, What is the profit maximizing quantity (remember, price is determined by the market therefore it is given)? Just like in the case with tabular data, there are two approaches.

1.Aggregate: Profit = TR – TC =

1.Aggregate: Profit = TR – TC = 160 Q – ( Q + 5 Q 2 )

1.Aggregate: Profit = TR – TC = 160 Q – ( Q + 5 Q 2 ) = =120 Q – 100 – 5 Q 2 A function is maximized when its derivative is zero; Specifically, when it changes its sign from ( + ) to ( – ) d(Profit)/dQ = – 10 Q = 0 Q = 12

2. Marginal (looking for the MR = MC point) MR = Price = $160 MC = d(TC)/dQ ; TC = Q + 5 Q 2 MC = Q MR = MC 160 = Q 120 = 10 Q Q = 12

What if the market is NOT perfectly competitive? (This happens if some or all of the attributes of perfect competition are not present. For example: - The firm in question is large (takes up a large portion of the market); - The firm produces a good that consumers perceive as different from the others; - Searching for the best deal is costly for consumers; Etc.)

For now, we will consider Monopolistic competition and Monopoly Many small firms -One LARGE firm Fairly easy entry and exit- Entry is very costly or impossible As a firm in either of these markets raises its price, the quantity it is able to sell drops – Demand curve is downward sloping! In both markets, a firm can vary its price to some extent

Demand curve of an individual firm: Q P

Total Revenue: Q TR

Marginal Revenue as a function of quantity: Q MR - Starts out positive; - Gradually decreases; - Hits zero when TR = MAX; - Goes on into the negative range.

In fact, when demand is linear, so is MR Q MR P MR and demand curves share the same vertical intercept but MR decreases twice as fast.

The profit maximization story told graphically: In aggregate terms: Q TR TC Profit

In marginal terms: Q MR P Profit-maximizing quantity Profit-maximizing price Note that for a profit-maxing firm with market power price is always higher than the MC of the last item produced The more market power a firm has, the greater that difference (“profit margin”, “markup”) MC

Recall also that profit is maximized where MR=MC… …whereas revenue is maximized where MR=0 Q MR P MC Profit-max quantity Revenue-max quantity Profit-maximizing price Revenue- maximizing price

Recall also that profit is maximized where MR=MC… …whereas revenue is maximized where MR=0 Q MR P MC Profit-max quantity Revenue-max quantity Profit-maximizing price Revenue- maximizing price For an imperfectly competitive firm, profit is always maximized at a smaller output quantity (therefore at a higher price) than revenue is maximized.

Analytically: TC = Q + 5 Q 2, And the demand facing the firm is given by Q D = 25 – 0.1 P What is the profit maximizing quantity AND price?