Non-trivial pricing strategies for firms with market power So far, we’ve been discussing cases when every unit of firm’s output was priced the same. Now,

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Price Discrimination: Capturing CS
Advertisements

Chapter Twenty-Five Monopoly Behavior. How Should a Monopoly Price? u So far a monopoly has been thought of as a firm which has to sell its product at.
Chapter 18 Pricing Policies McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Chapter Twenty-Five Monopoly Behavior. How Should a Monopoly Price? u So far a monopoly has been thought of as a firm which has to sell its product at.
Price Discrimination Monopoly Wrap-Up Chapter 15 Completion.
Price Discrimination.
Advanced Pricing Ideas 1. 2 We have looked at a single price monopoly. But perhaps other ways of pricing can lead to greater profits for the sports team.
1 3 rd Price Discrimination. 2 Review We saw a monopoly is the only firm that sells a product. Up to this point we worked with a single price monopoly.
Chapter 14 Advanced Pricing Techniques
Monopoly Outline: Outline: Characteristics of a monopoly Characteristics of a monopoly Why monopolies arise? Why monopolies arise? Production and pricing.
Chapter Twenty-Five Monopoly Behavior. How Should a Monopoly Price? u So far a monopoly has been thought of as a firm which has to sell its product at.
MBA 201A Section 4 - Pricing. Overview  Review of Pricing Strategies  Review of Pricing Problem from Class  Review PS3  Questions on Midterm  Q&A.
Chapter Twelve Pricing.
Harcourt, Inc. items and derived items copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. Monopoly u A monopoly is the sole seller of its product.  its product does not.
© 2008 Pearson Addison Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter Twelve Pricing and Advertising.
15 Monopoly.
1 Price discrimination A form of Monopoly Power. 2 Our story of monopoly is incomplete. We have seen the case where the monopolist charges all customers.
1 1 st degree price discrimination A form of Monopoly Power.
Monopoly While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker. A firm is considered a monopoly if it is the sole seller of.
12 MONOPOLY CHAPTER.
12 MONOPOLY CHAPTER.
Copyright © 2008 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Managerial Economics, 9e Managerial Economics Thomas Maurice.
All Rights ReservedMicroeconomics © Oxford University Press Malaysia, – 1.
Economics Winter 14 April 4 th, 2014 Lecture 32 Ch. 13: Pure monopoly.
Price Discrimination Prof. Dr. Murat Yulek. Market structures There are different market structures with varying effects on the consumer and total welfare.
0 Introduction  A monopoly is a firm that is the sole seller of a product without close substitutes.  The key difference: A monopoly firm has market.
 Firm that is sole seller of product without close substitutes  Price Maker not a Price Taker  There are barriers to entry thru: Monopoly Resources,
Price Discrimination The practice of charging unequal prices or fees to different buyers (or classes of buyers) is called price discrimination.
Chapter 14: Advanced Pricing Techniques McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
Chapter 14: Advanced Pricing Techniques
Chapter 15 Monopoly 1.
Monopoly CHAPTER 15.
Copyright © 2004 South-Western Monopoly vs. Competition While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker. A firm is considered.
Pricing Examples. Bundling In marketing, product bundling offers several products for sale as one combined product. This is common in the software business.
4 Market Structures Candy Markets Simulation.
Today Begin Monopoly. Monopoly Chapter 22 Perfect Competition = Many firms Oligopoly = A few firms Four Basic Models Monopoly = One firm Monopolistic.
Chapter 11 Pricing with Market Power. Chapter 112 Capturing Consumer Surplus All pricing strategies we will examine are means of capturing consumer surplus.
Copyright©2004 South-Western Monopoly. Copyright © 2004 South-Western While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker.
MICROECONOMICS: Theory & Applications
1 Microeconomics, 2 nd Edition David Besanko and Ronald Braeutigam Chapter 12: Pricing to Capture Surplus Value Prepared by Katharine Rockett © 2006 John.
Eco 6351 Economics for Managers Chapter 7. Monopoly Prof. Vera Adamchik.
© 2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc Chapter 14 Price Discrimination and Monopoly Practices.
Monopoly Chapter 15.
Principles of Economics Ohio Wesleyan University Goran Skosples Monopoly 10. Monopoly.
a market structure in which there is only one seller of a good or service that has no close substitutes and entry to the market is completely blocked.
Chapter 11 Pricing with Market Power. Chapter 11Slide 2 Topics to be Discussed Capturing Consumer Surplus Price Discrimination Intertemporal Price Discrimination.
PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University Monopoly 1 © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied,
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 25 Monopoly Behavior.
Chapter 19: Consumer Choice Copyright © 2013 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin 13e.
MONOPOLY 12 CHAPTER. Objectives After studying this chapter, you will able to  Explain how monopoly arises and distinguish between single-price monopoly.
Advanced Pricing Techniques
Copyright©2004 South-Western 15 Monopoly. Copyright © 2004 South-Western Monopoly While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price.
Chapter 11 Monopoly.
Every product is sold in a market that can be considered one of the above market structures. For example: 1.Fast Food Market 2.The Market for Cars 3.Market.
Chapter 25 Monopoly Behavior Price Discrimination Price discrimination: selling different units of output at different prices. First-degree price.
Study Unit 11 Pricing with Market Power. Why and how is consumer surplus captured. How is price discrimination used to capture consumer surplus. How is.
Chapter 11 Pricing w/Mkt Power Will cover 11.1 and Goal of firms with market power: capture CS and convert it to profits. Issue: HOW firms with mkt.
19-1 Consumer Choice  Prices are important in determining consumer behavior.  New products have to be priced correctly. The price could be set too high.
Chapter Monopoly 15. In economic terms, why are monopolies bad? Explain. 2.
Price Discrimination 1. Defined: Sellers engage in price discrimination when they charge different prices to different consumers for the same good, because.
Chapter 25 Monopoly Behavior. How Should a Monopoly Price? So far a monopoly has been thought of as a firm which has to sell its product at the same price.
As we wait for class to start, please sign in for today’s attendance tracking: Text to 37607: Lenovo44 netID Go online to: PollEv.com/dyson netID or.
Chapter: 14 >> Krugman/Wells Economics ©2009  Worth Publishers Monopoly.
14-1 Learning Objectives  Explain why uniform pricing does not generate maximum possible total revenue and how price discrimination can generate more.
Price Discrimination.
Chapter 14: Advanced Pricing Techniques
Monopoly and Pricing.
Monopoly and Pricing.
Chapter Twenty-Five Monopoly Behavior.
Presentation transcript:

Non-trivial pricing strategies for firms with market power So far, we’ve been discussing cases when every unit of firm’s output was priced the same. Now, it’s time to look at more interesting cases.

CS = MV – P (marginal value) Welfare measures Every consumer has some subjective valuation for each unit of the good, called marginal value, or marginal “utility”. Think of it as the highest price she would pay, or what the good is “worth” to her. Consumer surplus (CS) – equals the value (“utility”) a consumer gets from a good but doesn’t have to pay for. CS from an individual purchase: (price) (price actually paid)

P Q Demand, derived from a schedule of marginal values Market price CS Total market CS is represented by the area under the demand curve and above the price.

By analogy, producer surplus (PS) is the difference between the actual price and the minimum price at which the producer would agree to sell the good (the latter usually equals the marginal cost, MC). PS = P – MC Note the concept of PS is somewhat similar to but not the same as profit!

P Q Total producer surplus in the market is represented by the area below the market price level and above the supply curve. Supply, derived from a marginal cost schedule Market price PS

In a free market… $ S D Q … the sum of consumer and producer surpluses is maximized CS PS Every opportunity to make someone better off through exchange of goods is taken advantage of.

P Q For a monopoly… D MC MR Profit CS DWL All pricing strategies to be discussed below are designed to increase the chunk of the market surplus that goes to the producer, thus further increasing its profit.

1.Price discrimination (3 rd degree) Price discrimination is a general name for the practice of charging different consumers or groups of consumers different prices for the same product. Consider a town with 2000 college students and 1000 retirees. Students want to see a movie as long as the price doesn’t exceed $8. Elderly people are interested only if the price is $5 or below.

If you set the ticket price at $8, the revenue is TR = P * Q = 8 * 2000 = $16,000 If you lower the price to $5, the revenue is TR = P * Q = 5 * ( ) = $15,000 If you frame it as a discount for seniors, your revenue is TR = 8 * * 1000 = $21,000 An important condition is that students are ineligible for the discount.

Such practice of splitting the market into two or more groups and charging each a separate price – is called third-degree price discrimination. Conditions necessary for its success: Presence of at least two groups with known demand differences; The ability of the firm to distinguish among groups; The size of a group does not matter! All that matters is elasticity of demand by each group. The group with the more elastic demand gets charged a lower price, and vice versa Certain degree of market power to the firm; The possibility of product resale has to be eliminated.

Other examples of 3 rd degree price discrimination: Bus fare Museum admissions Airfare contingent on Saturday night stay Store coupons

2. Perfect (first-degree) price discrimination The hypothetical case when each consumer is charged the maximum price she is willing to pay (her subjective value, that is). It is rarely observed in real-world situations due to the difficulty of determining each consumer’s Marginal Value. Still, we can think of examples when a seller tries to achieve this. The chances for success of such practice are higher when the seller has only a few customers. Also, consider person-to-person sales.

$ MC Q P First-degree price discrimination - For every customer, (individual) price gets pushed all the way up to his/her MU; Individual prices

$ MC Q P First-degree price discrimination - For every customer, (individual) price gets pushed all the way up to his/her MU; - Producer gets the ENTIRE market welfare

3. Volume discounts (a.k.a. 2 nd degree PD) Also a form of price discrimination, since the buyers self-select themselves into high-volume and low- volume buyers, and each group pays a different per- unit price. Suppose you are a seller who has certain stock of shirts you need to sell. For simplicity, let’s say your goal is to maximize revenue. Every day, a hundred customers visit your store.

Let’s start with the unrealistic case when All customers are identical; You know everyone’s valuation for successive shirts: Shirt #Marginal Value, $ You need to decide what price tag to put on the shirt rack.

If charging a flat rate for each shirt: P = $15, TR = 15*100 = $1,500 P = $10, TR = 10*200 = $2,000 P = $6, TR = 6*300 = $1,800 P = $2, TR = 2*400 = $800 A better idea: Recognize the fact that each successive shirt is valued less than the previous one and price them accordingly. For example: P = $15, buy one, get second for 40% off TR = (15 + 9)*100 = $2,400 – better than any of the above cases

Of course People have different tastes, therefore different utility schedules. You never know what those schedules are. But stores do know that the willingness to pay falls with every successive shirt. Therefore, the above example explains how some stores in some cases may benefit from running sales of the “Buy one, get second at X% off” type.

Other examples of volume discounts: declining rates in parking garages, pricing by (some) electric companies, frequent flyer programs.

4. Bundling, or tie-in sales The table below shows how Bill and Linda value two rides at an amusement park. Ride Person MambaTimberwolf Bill$5$1 Linda$3$2 Suppose you, the manager of the amusement park, first decide to charge a separate price for each ride. What is the best price to charge?

For Mamba: P = $5, TR = 5*1 = $5 P = $3, TR = 3*2 = $6 For Timberwolf: P = $2, TR = 2*1 = $2 P = $1, TR = 1*2 = $2 Total revenue from Linda and Bill = = $8

A better idea: sell the two rides together, as a “bundle”. Best price for the bundle: P = $5, TR = 5 * 2 = $10 - better than under “regular” pricing This strategy works best when the valuations of different consumers for different goods or services are negatively correlated. Other examples – Newspapers, Cable TV. Ride Person MambaTimberwolf M + T Bill$5$1 Linda$3$2 $6 $5

P Q 5. Block pricing D MC MR If selling individually: The best price is $ Demand of an individual consumer 63

5. Block pricing If selling individually: Profit = Demand of an individual consumer Q D MC MR

5. Block pricing If selling individually: Profit = (1.25 – 0.50)*3 = $2.25 Demand of an individual consumer Q D MC MR

5. Block pricing Each consumer values units up to #6 above MC Demand of an individual consumer Q D MC MR

5. Block pricing What if we sell this product ONLY as a six-pack? Demand of an individual consumer Q D MC MR

Pricing the 6-pack: A customer would pay: Up to $1.75 for the first unit; Up to $1.50 for the second; Up to $1.25 for the third; Up to $1.00 for the fourth; Up to $0.75 for the fifth; Up to $0.50 for the sixth. (units after #6 are not worth producing) Total value consumer places on a six-pack is $6.75. That is the price we should charge.

5. Block pricing Profit under block pricing Q D MC MR and under regular pricing

P Q 6. Two-part pricing D MC MR Demand of an individual consumer The profit-maximizing point is P = $35, Q = 10, Π = $250Same price + one-time fee equal to consumer’s CS from purchase

P Q 6. Two-part pricing D MC MR Demand of an individual consumer Same price + one-time fee equal to consumer’s CS from purchase

An even better idea: lower the per-unit price and keep charging the fee (which will now be larger) P Q 6. Two-part pricing D MC MR Demand of an individual consumer

An even better idea: lower the per-unit price (P=MC=$10) and keep charging the fee (which will now be larger) P Q 6. Two-part pricing D MC MR Demand of an individual consumer

The i-Phone case

Prices are falling over time – WHY? Possible explanations: - Obsolescence – Better products developed – demand drops - More firms enter – stronger competition – profit margin drops - More efficient production technologies developed – production costs drop – price drops - “Intertemporal price discrimination”, or separating customers across time, based on their patience factor

$ MC Demand from all the consumers who will ever want your product Q You could satisfy them all at once…

$ MC Demand from all the consumers who will ever want your product Q

$ MC Demand from all the consumers who will ever want your product Q … or, you could serve them one group at a time, starting with those who value the good the most April May June July

$ MC Demand from all the consumers who will ever want your product Q