Prosecution Delay Laches and Antitrust Prof Merges 4/29/08.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Why competition law? Economic performance Social welfare Well being of consumers.
Advertisements

By David W. Hill AIPLA Immediate Past President Partner Finnegan, Henderson, Farabow, Garrett & Dunner, LLP Overview of the America Invents Act.
© Kolisch Hartwell 2013 All Rights Reserved, Page 1 America Invents Act (AIA) Implementation in 2012 Peter D. Sabido Intellectual Property Attorney Kolisch.
Recent Cases on Patentable Subject Matter and Patent Exhaustion Mojdeh Bahar, J.D., M.A. Chief, Cancer Branch Office of Technology Transfer National Institutes.
Law and Economics-Charles W. Upton Legal Background.
Judge Sarah S. Vance, Eastern District of Louisiana Standards for Dismissal and Evaluation of Expert Testimony.
Chapter 46 Antitrust Law Copyright © 2009 South-Western Legal Studies in Business, a part of South-Western Cengage Learning. Jentz Miller Cross BUSINESS.
Copyright © 2004 by Prentice-Hall. All rights reserved. PowerPoint Slides to Accompany BUSINESS LAW E-Commerce and Digital Law International Law and Ethics.
© 2004 West Legal Studies in Business A Division of Thomson Learning 1 Chapter 46 Antitrust Law Chapter 46 Antitrust Law.
Slides developed by Les Wiletzky Wiletzky and Associates Copyright © 2006 by Pearson Prentice-Hall. All rights reserved. Antitrust Law.
1 COPYRIGHT © 2007 West Legal Studies in Business, a part of The Thomson Corporation. Thomson, the Star logo, and West Legal Studies in Business are trademarks.
Greg Gardella Patent Reexamination: Effective Strategy for Litigating Infringement Claims Best Practices for Pursuing and Defending Parallel Proceedings.
US Antitrust Limitations on Patent Licensing Bruce D. Sunstein Bromberg & Sunstein LLP Boston © 2008 Bromberg & Sunstein LLP.
Antitrust Does Google have monopoly power? Microsoft? On what? Why? Why Not? Is that bad? Why? Can you name monopolies in other industries? Is Monopoly.
© 2007 by West Legal Studies in Business / A Division of Thomson Learning CHAPTER 20 Promoting Competition.
Patents Copyright © Jeffrey Pittman. Pittman - Cyberlaw & E- Commerce 2 Legal Framework of Patents The U.S. Constitution, Article 1, Section 8:
Prosecution Delay Laches and Inequitable Conduct Prof Merges 11/23/2010.
Week /28/03Adv.Pat.Law Seminar - rjm1 Today’s Agenda Filling in the Gaps in Your Knowledge of “Basic” Patent Law Duty of Candor – an historical case.
Prosecution Delay Laches Patent Law. United States Patent 5,351,078 Lemelson * September 27, 1994 Apparatus and methods for automated observation.
IP and Anticompetitive Conduct Intro to IP – Prof. Merges
Patents 101 April 1, 2002 And now, for something new, useful and not obvious.
Prosecution Delay Laches and Inequitable Conduct Prof Merges 11/22/2011.
Law Antitrust - Instructor: Dwight Drake United States v. Arnold, Schwinn & Co. (Sup. Ct. 1967) What had happened to Schwinn’s market share? Three.
Chapter 47 Antitrust Law McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2012 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
Antitrust Kim C. Stanger Compliance Bootcamp (5/15)
1 C H A P T E R 14 1 © 2001 Prentice Hall Business PublishingEconomics: Principles and Tools, 2/eO’Sullivan & Sheffrin Market Power and Public Policy:
1 The common law Sherman Act (1890) Clayton Act (1914) § 1 Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1 Trusts, etc., in restraint of trade illegal; penalty Every contract,
Antitrust Policy and Regulation ECO 2023 Chapter 18 Fall 2007.
H I R S C H & P A R T N E R S A v o c a t S o l i c i t o r R e c h t s a n w a l t Pharmaceutical settlement agreements and competition law A litigation.
1 Patent Law in the Age of IoT The Landscape Has Shifted. Are You Prepared? 1 Jeffrey A. Miller, Esq.
Antitrust. “Is there not a causal connection between the development of these huge, indomitable trusts and the horrible crimes now under investigation?
Post-Grant & Inter Partes Review Procedures Presented to AIPPI, Italy February 10, 2012 By Joerg-Uwe Szipl Griffin & Szipl, P.C.
Misuse and Exhaustion Intro to IP – Prof Merges
© 2008 West Legal Studies in Business A Division of Thomson Learning 1 BUSINESS LAW TODAY Essentials 8 th Ed. Roger LeRoy Miller - Institute for University.
 “Market power” is the power of company to control the market for its product.  The law does allow for market monopolies when a patent is issued. During.
1 Overview of Legal Process in IP Cases From notes by Steve Baron © Ed Lamoureux/Steve Baron.
Law Antitrust - Instructor: Dwight Drake Jefferson Parish Hospital Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde (Sup. Ct. 1984) Basic Facts: Exclusive contract between hospital.
© COPYRIGHT DICKSTEIN SHAPIRO LLP. ALL RIGHTS RESERVED. Post Grant Proceedings Before the USPTO and Litigation Strategies Under the AIA Panelists:David.
Chapter 20 Antitrust and Regulation of Competition Copyright © 2015 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without.
1 Working the IP Case Steve Baron Sept. 3, Today’s Agenda  Anatomy of an IP case  The Courts and the Law  Links to finding cases  Parts of.
© 2013 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license.
Law Antitrust - Instructor: Dwight Drake United States v. AT&T (D.D.C. 1981) What products did Western Electric provide Bell Operating Companies?
LAW OF COMPUTER TECHNOLOGY FALL 2015 © 2015 MICHAEL I. SHAMOS Patents Michael I. Shamos, Ph.D., J.D. Institute for Software Research School of Computer.
What is a monopoly? What is market power? How do these concepts relate to each other? What is a monopoly? What is market power? How do these concepts.
 Federal gov may regulate business for any reason as long as advances gov economic need  States may regulate business as long as the laws do not interfere.
Chapter 46 Antitrust Laws and Unfair Trade Practices
Business Law and the Regulation of Business Chapter 43: Antitrust By Richard A. Mann & Barry S. Roberts.
Chapter 23 Antitrust Law and Unfair Trade Practices.
Defenses & Counterclaims III Class Notes: March 27, 2003 Law 677 | Patent Law | Spring 2003 Professor Wagner.
© 2005 West Legal Studies in Business, a division of Thompson Learning. All Rights Reserved.1 PowerPoint Slides to Accompany The Legal, Ethical, and International.
© 2004 West Legal Studies in Business A Division of Thomson Learning 1 Chapter 26 Antitrust and Monopoly.
COPYRIGHT © 2011 South-Western/Cengage Learning. 1 Click your mouse anywhere on the screen to advance the text in each slide. After the starburst appears,
1 Chapter 13 Practice Quiz Tutorial Antitrust and Regulation ©2000 South-Western College Publishing.
Boston New York San Francisco Washington, DC Woods Hole Oceanographic Institute Understanding Intellectual Property June 4, 2008.
© 2004 West Legal Studies in Business, a Division of Thomson Learning 20.1 Chapter 20 Antitrust Law.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Chapter 8: Pure Monopoly Copyright © 2010 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
HOT TOPICS IN PATENT LITIGATION ABA – IP Section, April 9, 2011 Committee 601 – Trial and Appellate Rules & Procedures Moderator: David Marcus Speakers:
49-1 Copyright © 2013 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
1 Click your mouse anywhere on the screen to advance the text in each slide. After the starburst appears, click a blue triangle to move to the next slide.
1 How To Find and Read the Law and Live to Tell (and Talk) About It Steve Baron January 29, 2009.
Enhanced Damages for Patent Infringement: Halo v. Pulse
Chapter 37 Antitrust Law.
Chapter 22 Promoting Competition.
CHAPTER 38 Antitrust.
PowerPoint Slides to Accompany ESSENTIALS OF BUSINESS AND ONLINE COMMERCE LAW 1st Edition by Henry R. Cheeseman Chapter 21 Antitrust Law Slides developed.
How To Find and Read the Law and Live to Tell (and Talk) About It
US Antitrust Limitations on Patent Licensing
Overview of Legal Process in IP Cases
Essentials of the legal environment today, 5e
Overview of Legal Process in IP Cases
Presentation transcript:

Prosecution Delay Laches and Antitrust Prof Merges 4/29/08

35 U.S.C. 315 Appeal (a) PATENT OWNER.- The patent owner involved in an inter partes reexamination proceeding under this chapter- (b) THIRD-PARTY REQUESTER.- A third-party requester- (1) may appeal under the provisions of section 134, and may appeal under the provisions of sections 141 through 144, with respect to any final decision favorable to the patentability of any original or proposed amended or new claim of the patent

(c) CIVIL ACTION.- A third-party requester whose request for an inter partes reexamination results in an order under section 313 is estopped from asserting at a later time, in any civil action arising in whole or in part under section 1338 of title 28, the invalidity of any claim finally determined to be valid and patentable on any ground which the third-party requester raised or could have raised during the inter partes reexamination proceedings. This subsection does not prevent the assertion of invalidity based on newly discovered prior art unavailable to the third-party requester and the Patent and Trademark Office …

Jerome Lemelson,

id=29 Mr. Lemelson, who died in 1997, was granted more than 500 U.S. patents, making him (from a patent-count standpoint, anyway), one of the most prolific inventors in U.S. history. Some have compared him with Edison (that patent count again), but unlike Edison, most people would have difficulty recognizing his name or what any of his inventions were. Ask the dozens of companies he sued over the years for alleged patent infringement, and observers of developments in patent law, and they may tell you that Lemelson’s most significant (and lucrative) invention was how to game the U.S. patent system.

United States Patent 5,351,078 Lemelson * September 27, 1994 Apparatus and methods for automated observation of objects Apparatus and methods are disclosed for automatically inspecting two- or three-dimensional objects or subjects. A detector and the object are moved relative to each other. In one form, a detector, such as a camera or radiation receiver, moves around an object, which is supported to be rotatable such that the detector may receive electromagnetic energy signals from the object from a variety of angles. The energy may be directed as a beam at and reflected from the object, as for visible light, or passed through the object, as for x-ray radiation.

The detector generates analog image signals resulting from the detected radiation, and an electronic computer process and analyzes the analog signals and generates digital codes, which may be stored or employed to control a display.

Inventors: Lemelson; Jerome H. (Incline Village, NV) Assignee: Lemelson Medical, Education & Research Foundation Limited Partnership (Incline Village, NV) Filed: September 16, 1993

“Continuation Abuse” MAJOR controversy over stringent PTO rules limiting number of continuations that patentee is allowed to file

Supreme Court of the United States. WOODBRIDGE et al. v. UNITED STATES. Decided Nov. 12, 1923.

Justice Taft

In this case we have a delay of 9 1/2 years in securing a patent that might have been had at any time in that period for the asking, and this for the admitted purpose of making the term of the monopoly square with the period when the commercial profit from it would be highest. Not until war or fear of war came was there likely to be a strong demand for rifled cannon and their improvement.

Hence the inventor, having put his order for the issue of a patent into the secret archives of the Patent Office in 1852, sat down and waited until after the Civil War came on in 1861 before seeking to avail himself of the patent, thus postponing the time when the public could freely enjoy it for nearly 10 years.

Meantime other inventors had been at work in the same field and had obtained patents without knowledge of the situation with respect to Woodbridge's invention.

This is not a case where evidence has to be weighed as to the purpose of the inventor. He avows his deliberate intention. This is not a case of abandonment. It is a case of forfeiting the right to a patent by designed delay.

Defenses: Antitrust/Misuse Patents confer market power Market power can be abused When it has been, this may provide a defense for an infringer

Antitrust/Misuse Centers on how the patentee deploys the technology Numerous potential ways to abuse the market power conferred by a patent

Examples Use of patents to mask or hide a cartel – “Horizontal” abuse Use of patents to exert control over dealers or customers – “Vertical” abuse

Misuse/Antitrust Counterclaim Plaintiff/Patentee Defendant

Misuse/Antitrust Counterclaim Plaintiff/Patentee Defendant Counterclaim

Misuse/Antitrust Counterclaim Plaintiff/Patentee Defendant Licensing Agreement

Misuse/Antitrust Counterclaim Plaintiff/Patentee Defendant Licensing Agreement Defendant asserts patent is unenforceable due to anticompetitive licensing agreement

Typical Counterclaims Anticompetitive acquisition of patent – Walker Process Equipment, Inc. v. Food Machinery Chemical Corp., 382 U. S. 172 (1965); Handgards, Inc. v. Ethicon, Inc. 743 F. 2d 1282 (9th Cir. 1984) Illegal tie-in – Morton Salt

Illinois Tool Trident, a wholly-owned subsidiary of Illinois Tool Works, is a manufacturer of printheads and owns U.S. Patent No. 5,343,226 covering the technology. The ‘226 patent discloses an ink jet device and a supply system with a hand actuated peristaltic pump. Trident also manufactures ink for use with the patented printheads. Although the ink is not protected by any of Trident’s patents, their standard license agreements grant the right to “manufacture, use and sell… ink jet printing devices…” to other printer manufacturers ONLY “when used in combination with ink and ink supply systems supplied by Trident.”

Misuse/Antitrust Counterclaim Plaintiff/Patentee Defendant Licensing Agreement Defendant asserts patent is unenforceable due to anticompetitive licensing agreement

Independent Ink also manufactures ink useable in Trident’s patented printheads. Independent filed suit in the Central District of California against Trident and Illinois Tool Works alleging, among other things, an illegal tying arrangement in violation of section 1 of the Sherman Act. The district court, however, dismissed the case on summary judgment.

Illinois Tool – p. 1 “This presumption of market power, applicable in the antitrust context when a seller conditions its sale of a patented product (the “tying” product) on the purchase of a second product (the.tied. product), has its foundation in the judicially created patent misuse doctrine.”

How Did the Issue Arise? “Independent filed suit against Trident [Illinois Tool] seeking a judgment of noninfringement and invalidity of Trident.s patents.1 In an amended complaint, it alleged that petitioners are engaged in illegal tying and monopolization in violation of §§1 and 2 of the Sherman Act. 15 U. S. C. §§1, 2.”

Sherman Act: Section One 15 U.S.C. § 1 Every contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations, is declared to be illegal. Every person who shall make any contract or engage in any combination or conspiracy hereby declared to be illegal shall be deemed guilty of a felony, and, on conviction thereof, shall be punished by fine not exceeding $10,000,000 if a corporation, or, if any other person, $350,000, or by imprisonment not exceeding three years, or by both said punishments, in the discretion of the court.

Sherman Act: Section One 15 U.S.C. § 2 Every person who shall monopolize, or attempt to monopolize, or combine or conspire with any other person or persons, to monopolize any part of the trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations, shall be deemed guilty of a felony, and, on conviction thereof, shall be punished by fine not exceeding $10,000,000 if a corporation, or, if any other person, $350,000, or by imprisonment not exceeding three years, or by both said punishments, in the discretion of the court.

Theoretical basis “Leverage theory” – Patents being improperly leveraged by various licensing practices For example, a tie-in

Tie-in example If you want my patented machine, you must buy (unpatented) materials used in the machine

Morton Salt case

“[R]espondent is making use of its patent monopoly to restrain competition in the marketing of unpatented articles, the salt tablets, for use with the patented machines...” -- P. 1351

Morton Salt Equity Relevant that illicit license is with 3 rd parties, not defendant/petitioner? – No

Leverage theory “Leveraging” monopoly in machine into (separate) market for salt

Chicago Critique No such thing as “leverage” Cannot charge more for [Tying + Tied] product bundle than buyers are willing to pay

More Chicago critique Look for more “positive” explanation of licensing practices – Patentees deserve a monopoly How might it be good for the patentee and consumers?

“Metering” Concept Relates back to price discrimination idea

Why is it good to allow tie-ins? Allow seller to capture value of bacon for consumers of bacon and eggs Prevent consumers from “substituting away” from bacon when price of bacon is raised

Price Quantity Demanded (000s) D $5 100 $3 170 Total Revenue Price Discrimination

Total Revenue High PriceLow Price $500 (100 x $5) $510 (170 x $3)

Price Quantity Demanded (000s) D $5 100 $3 170 Total Revenue Price Discrimination “Consumer Surplus” – lost to seller

Price Quantity Demanded (000s) D $5 100 $3 170 Price Discrimination Large canners Small canners

Total Revenue Without Price Discrimination With Price Discrimination $510$710 (100 x $5) + (70 x $3)

Solution: Metering by Tie-in Use salt sales to count how much buyer uses canning equipment Achieve price discrimination: high volume users will pay more for canning equipment

Precedent Loew’s, International Salt. These cases predate the Court’s articulation These cases predate the Court’s articulation of the market power requirement (ITS v. Kodak, Jefferson Parish v. Hyde).

Morton Salt

Salt and Canning Equipment

Nonprice Vertical Restraints: GTE Sylvania After reexamining the Schwinn rule, the U.S. Supreme Court in the present case rejected that rule and held that all nonprice vertical restraints of trade would be examined using the rule of reason. Only vertical price fixing (or resale price maintenance) would be examined using the per se rule. The Supreme Court held that Sylvania’s alleged restraint of trade in terminating Continental TV was a nonprice vertical restraint of trade that was to be examined using the rule of reason. The Supreme Court affirmed the Court of Appeals decision in favor of GTE Sylvania. Continental TV, Inc. v. GTE Sylvania, Inc., 433 U.S. 36, 97 S.Ct. 2549, 53 L.Ed.2d 568 (1977).

Limitations on Licensing 35 USC § 271(d)(5) No patent owner otherwise entitled to relief for infringement or contributory infringement of a patent shall be denied relief or deemed guilty of misuse or illegal extension of the patent right by reason of his having done one or more of the following:.... refused to license or use any rights to the patent; or

conditioned the license of any rights to the patent or the sale of the patented product on the acquisition of a license to rights in another patent or purchase of a separate product, unless, in view of the circumstances, the patent owner has market power in the relevant market for the patent or patented product on which the license or sale is conditioned.

Illinois Tool: District Court SJ for Accused Infringer

On appeal, the Federal Circuit reversed and remanded the district court’s grant of summary judgment in favor of Trident on the tying claim. According to the Appellate Court, Trident’s licenses are “explicit tying agreement[s]” because the sale of a patented product is conditioned on the sale of an unpatented one. Although the district court required affirmative proof of market power from the plaintiff, the Federal Circuit reiterated that the Supreme Court has clearly established a presumption of market power unique to patent and copyright tying cases, it holds that this presumption is rebuttable.

“Once the plaintiff establishes a patent tying agreement, it is the defendant’s burden to rebut the presumption of market power and consequent illegality that arises from patent tying.” Rebuttal evidence requires expert testimony or “credible economic evidence of the cross-elasticity of demand, the area of effective competition, or other evidence of lack of market power.” Furthermore, the Court admonishes the district court for not following clearly established Supreme Court precedent and for dismissing the High Court's holdings as “vintage.” Commenting that it may be time to abandon the doctrine, a significant portion of the opinion emphasizes that it is up to the Supreme Court or Congress to expressly overrule its own precedent -- this prerogative does not lie with the district courts.

Broad consensus that patents are property and are not monopolies. – USDOJ/FTC Antitrust Guidelines for Licensing of IP (noting difference between patentee’s power IP to exclude and market power) – Patent Misuse Reform Act (35 U.S.C. § 271(d)(5)) (tying arrangement does not constitute patent misuse in the absence of market power) Evolution of Areeda/Hovenkamp treatise Suggests that presumption of market power is not warranted.

Illinois Tool "Any conclusion that an arrangement is unlawful must be supported by proof of power in the relevant market rather than by a mere presumption thereof," the Court said "Congress, the antitrust enforcement agencies, and most economists have all reached the conclusion that a patent does not necessarily confer market power upon the patentee... Today, we reach the same conclusion, and therefore hold that, in all cases involving a tying arrangement, the plaintiff must prove that the defendant has market power in the tying product."

Illinois Tool The Supreme Court eliminated the presumption that a patent provides market power in a licensing agreement involving a tie-in The Court has signaled a willingness to revisit old precedent originating in the anti-patent era of the 1930s and 1940s when Congress and scholarly opinion had turned decisively against it

William O. Douglas