Term Structure Driven by general Lévy processes Bonaventure Ho HKUST, Math Dept. Oct 6, 2005.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Chp.4 Lifetime Portfolio Selection Under Uncertainty
Advertisements

Appendix 27A: An Alternative Method to Derive The Black-Scholes Option Pricing Model (Related to 27.5) By Cheng Few Lee Joseph Finnerty John Lee Alice.
Change of Time Method in Mathematical Finance Anatoliy Swishchuk Mathematical & Computational Finance Lab Department of Mathematics & Statistics University.
Chap 11. Introduction to Jump Process
Arvid Kjellberg- Jakub Lawik - Juan Mojica - Xiaodong Xu.
Interest Rate Options Chapter 18. Exchange-Traded Interest Rate Options Treasury bond futures options (CBOT) Eurodollar futures options.
I.Generalities. Bruno Dupire 2 Market Skews Dominating fact since 1987 crash: strong negative skew on Equity Markets Not a general phenomenon Gold: FX:
Stochastic Volatility Modelling Bruno Dupire Nice 14/02/03.
Chapter 19 Volatility Smiles
MGT 821/ECON 873 Volatility Smiles & Extension of Models
L7: Stochastic Process 1 Lecture 7: Stochastic Process The following topics are covered: –Markov Property and Markov Stochastic Process –Wiener Process.
Paper Review:"New Insight into Smile, Mispricing, and Value at Risk: The Hyperbolic Model" by E. Eberlein, U. Keller and K. Prause (1998). Anatoliy Swishchuk.
Derivatives Inside Black Scholes
Chapter 27 Martingales and Measures
Numerical Methods for Option Pricing
Ch. 19 J. Hull, Options, Futures and Other Derivatives Zvi Wiener Framework for pricing derivatives.
24/05/2007 Maria Adler University of Kaiserslautern Department of Mathematics 1 Hyperbolic Processes in Finance Alternative Models for Asset Prices.
Derivatives Options on Bonds and Interest Rates Professor André Farber Solvay Business School Université Libre de Bruxelles.
5.4 Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing (2) 劉彥君.
Zvi WienerContTimeFin - 10 slide 1 Financial Engineering Interest Rate Models Zvi Wiener tel: following Hull and White.
5.2Risk-Neutral Measure Part 2 報告者:陳政岳 Stock Under the Risk-Neutral Measure is a Brownian motion on a probability space, and is a filtration for.
7.5 Asian Options 指導老師:戴天時 演講者:鄭凱允. 序 An Asian option is one whose payoff includes a time average of the underlying asset price. The average may be over.
Zvi WienerContTimeFin - 9 slide 1 Financial Engineering Risk Neutral Pricing Zvi Wiener tel:
The Lognormal Distribution
Chapter 8 Mean-Reverting Processes and Term Structure Modeling.
Diffusion Processes and Ito’s Lemma
JUMP DIFFUSION MODELS Karina Mignone Option Pricing under Jump Diffusion.
Risk Management and Financial Institutions 2e, Chapter 13, Copyright © John C. Hull 2009 Chapter 13 Market Risk VaR: Model- Building Approach 1.
Advanced Risk Management I Lecture 6 Non-linear portfolios.
Interest Rate Derivatives: More Advanced Models Chapter 24
HJM Models.
Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 5th edition © 2002 by John C. Hull 22.1 Interest Rate Derivatives: The Standard Market Models Chapter 22.
Derivative Pricing Black-Scholes Model
© 2011 Neil D. Pearson A Simulation Implementation of the Hull- White Model Neil D. Pearson.
Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull 22.1 Interest Rate Derivatives: More Advanced Models Chapter 22.
Testing Distributions of Stochastically Generated Yield Curves Gary G Venter AFIR Seminar September 2003.
5.4 Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing 報告者:何俊儒.
1 Derivatives & Risk Management: Part II Models, valuation and risk management.
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance Optimum Consumption and Portfolio Rules in a Continuous-Time Model Yuna Rhee Seyong Park Robert C. Merton (1971) [Journal.
Derivative Financial Products Donald C. Williams Doctoral Candidate Department of Computational and Applied Mathematics, Rice University Thesis Advisors.
Bond Valuation Professor Thomas Chemmanur. 2 Bond Valuation A bond represents borrowing by firms from investors. F  Face Value of the bond (sometimes.
Chapter 12 Modeling the Yield Curve Dynamics FIXED-INCOME SECURITIES.
Numerical option pricing in the Barndorff-Nielsen - Shephard stochastic volatility model. Martin Groth Centre of Mathematics for Applications University.
Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma.
9. Change of Numeraire 鄭凱允. 9.1 Introduction A numeraire is the unit of account in which other assets are denominated and change the numeraire by changing.
Option Pricing Models: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model aka Black – Scholes Option Pricing Model (BSOPM)
© K.Cuthbertson, D. Nitzsche FINANCIAL ENGINEERING: DERIVATIVES AND RISK MANAGEMENT (J. Wiley, 2001) K. Cuthbertson and D. Nitzsche Lecture Asset Price.
1 Martingales and Measures MGT 821/ECON 873 Martingales and Measures.
Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma. Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved Introduction Stock and other asset prices.
The Black-Scholes-Merton Model Chapter B-S-M model is used to determine the option price of any underlying stock. They believed that stock follow.
Chapter 28 Interest Rate Derivatives: The Standard Market Models Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 8th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull
S TOCHASTIC M ODELS L ECTURE 4 P ART II B ROWNIAN M OTIONS Nan Chen MSc Program in Financial Engineering The Chinese University of Hong Kong (Shenzhen)
Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull 21.1 Interest Rate Derivatives: Models of the Short Rate Chapter 21.
Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull 20.1 Interest Rate Derivatives: The Standard Market Models Chapter 20.
An Reexamination of Jump Effect on Credit Spreads with Noisy Information Lung-fu Chang, Department of Finance, National Taipei College of Business.
OPTIONS PRICING AND HEDGING WITH GARCH.THE PRICING KERNEL.HULL AND WHITE.THE PLUG-IN ESTIMATOR AND GARCH GAMMA.ENGLE-MUSTAFA – IMPLIED GARCH.DUAN AND EXTENSIONS.ENGLE.
Chapter 19 Volatility Smiles Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 8th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull
Fundamentals of Futures and Options Markets, 5 th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull Interest Rate Options Chapter 19.
Primbs, MS&E More Applications of Linear Pricing.
Primbs, MS&E Applications of the Linear Functional Form: Pricing Exotics.
Chapter 14 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model
ESTIMATING THE BINOMIAL TREE
Mathematical Finance An Introduction
Chapter 15 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model
Option prices and the Black-Scholes-Merton formula
Generalities.
Chapter 15 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model
Presentation transcript:

Term Structure Driven by general Lévy processes Bonaventure Ho HKUST, Math Dept. Oct 6, 2005

2 Outline Why do we need to model term structure? Going from Brownian motion to Lévy process Model assumption and bond price dynamics Markovian short rate and stationary volatility structure Comparison between Gaussian and Lévy setting Conclusion and Discussion

3 Why do we need to model term structure? Term structure is the information contained in the forward rate curve, short rate curve, and yield curve observed from market data. There are deterministic relationships among forward rates (f), short rates (instantaneous interest rate)(r) and zero-coupon bond prices (P). Usually, a model on fixed income assumes certain dynamics on the zero- coupon bond (eg. HJM) or on forward rates (eg. LIBOR). One can calculate the model price for f, r, and P under this model. Arbitrage opportunities arise when the predicted values for f, r, or P are different from the currently observed market data. Therefore, an arbitrage-free model should incorporate the term structure into itself.

4 History of the Gaussian model No-arbitrage  Existence of risk neutral measure What is risk neutral measure?  An equivalent probability measure under which all tradable securities, when discounted, are martingales.  Discount factor (numeraire) = Log-normal model  Initiated by Bachelier (1900), modeling the French government bonds using Brownian motion.  Samuelson (1965) gave the price process in exponential form  Black and Scholes (1973) framework of log-normality of stock prices Eg.)Heath-Jarrow-Morton model under the risk neutral measure where W is a standard Brownian motion Major shortcomings  Cannot generate volatility smile/skew as shown in the market data  Distribution itself does not fit the market data very well – fatter tail and high peak, jump!

5 Lévy Process Lévy process L t – a generalization to the Brownian motion.  stochastic process with stationary and independent increments  continuous in probability(P(|L u -L v |≥ε)  0, as u  v for all v)  L 0 =0 a.s.  viewed as Brownian motion with jump  associated Lévy measure F  characterized by ( , ,F) for drift, variance, and the Lévy measure for jump Examples of Lévy processes  Brownian motion W  BM with jump (Merton)Merton Jump Part (Compound Poisson jump) (Carr)Variance Gamma (Eberlein)Hyperbolic (used as an example in the paper)

6 Examples of Lévy Processes Driver’s nameLévy Measure Brownian motion Merton Jump Part Variance Gamma Hyperbolic Remarks:K 1 is the modified Bessel function of the third kind with index 1

7 Motivation to use Lévy processes To incorporate jump into the price dynamics.  Merton (1976) added an independent Poisson jump process with normal jump size.  Eberlein (author of the presenting paper) and Keller “It is in certain way opposite to the Brownian world, since its (Lévy process) paths are purely discontinuous. If one looks at real stock price movements on the intraday scale it is exactly this discontinuous behavior what one observes.” – Eberlein and Keller (1997), promoting the hyperbolic Lévy model. In 1995, they performed empirical studies and revealed a much better fit of return distributions on stock prices if the Brownian motion is replaced by a Lévy process. However, evidence for non-Gaussian behavior on bond prices is not as complete. In 2005, Eberlein & Özkan explore the LIBOR model using Lévy processes. Volatility smile/skew cannot be generated by the log-normal model  Jump and/or stochastic volatility can generate such smile/skew.  I will discuss the “jump” part as a component of Lévy processes in this presentation, based mostly on the paper by Eberlein and Raible.  Stochastic volatility can be generated by the “time-change” method, which will be my research topic. Idea: change the calendar time to a random “business-activity” clock.

8 Model assumptions 1.(initial bond prices) P(0,T) is deterministic, positive, and twice continuously differentiable function in T for all T  [0,T*] for a fixed time horizon T* 2.(boundary condition) P(T,T)=1 for all T  [0,T*] 3.(volatility bounds) Define  :={(s,T) : 0  s  T  T*}  (s,T)>0 for all (s,T) , s  T, and  (T,T)=0 for all T  [0,T*] 4.(integrability) There exists constants M,  >0 such that 5.(volatility smoothness)  (s,T), defined on , is twice continuously differentiable in both variables and is bounded by M from #4

9 Bond price dynamics In HJM model, the solution to the SDE is simply Note that the above solution of the SDE is evaluated under the risk neutral measure. Our generalization:  Replace W by L, thus source of randomness =  Replace the discount factor by a more general numéraire :  (t) Under this numéraire, P(t,T) is a martingale under this measure when expressed in terms of units of  (t).

10 Lemma 1.1 If f is left-continuous with limits from the right and bounded by M, then where denotes the log MGF of L 1  In particular, take f to be , we have  Here we relate the expected value of the source of randomness to the log MGF of the Lévy process, which is known when the process is specified. Basic Lemmas(1) Proof

11 Lemma 1.2 Forward rate process f( ,T) has the form where  2 denotes the partial derivative of  in its second variable (T) Lemma 1.3 The numéraire  (t) is given by, where  (t) is the usual money market account process Remark: Substituting the result back to our initial assumption, we obtain For Gaussian model,  (u)=u 2 /2, we obtain the usual case Basic Lemmas(2) Proof

12 Term structure of the volatility We want to explore the class of volatility structure so that the short rate process is Markovian. Furthermore, we want to restrict our volatility structure to be stationary. That is, . It will be proven that the volatility has either Vasiček volatility structure or Ho-Lee volatility structure! or for real constants

13 Proof steps(1) Lemma 2.1 Suppose the CF of L 1 is bounded, with real constants C, ,  >0, such that If f, g are continuous functions such that f(s)  k·g(s) for all s, then the joint distribution of X and Y is continuous w.r.t. Lebesgue measure 2 on  2, where Lemma 2.2 The short rate process r is Markovian if and only if where 0<T<U<T*, and note that  may depend on T and U, but not on t. Corollary: Proof

14 Proof steps(2) & Hull-White revisit Theorem 2.3 Further assume that the volatility structure is stationary, then it must be either of Vasiček or Ho-Lee structure. Corollary Under the above stationarity and Markovian assumptions, we can take the volatility to have the Vasiček volatility structure. Then the short rate process follows: If we take L to be W, we revert back to the Hull-White model (or the extended Vasiček model) Proof

15 Comparing forward rates Using similar steps, we can derive the forward rate process.  Comparing it to the Gaussian case, we obtain:

16 Examples using Lévy processes (hyperbolic) Eberlein and Keller (1995) used hyperbolic Lévy motion to model stock price dynamics. They claimed that the hyperbolic model allows an almost perfect statistical fit of stock return data. In order to compare with the Gaussian case, we restrict L 1 to be centered, symmetric, and with unit variance. That is, we pick K 1 and K 2 denotes the modified Bessel function of the third kind with index 1 and 2 respectively. We investigate the case  =10 (density close to normal) and  =0.01 (considerably heavier weight in the tails and in the center than normal). Vasiček volatility structure, Initial term structure: flat at f(0,t)=0.05 for all t

17 Hyperbolic vs normal Hyperbolic,  =0.01 Hyperbolic,  =10 Standard normal

18 Comparing forward rates Figure 1:Forward rate predicted by hyperbolic Lévy (  =0.01) Figure 2: f hyper (t,T)-f Gauss (t,T) Forward rates predicted by hyperbolic Lévy motion are marginally higher than that predicted by Brownian motion.

19 Comparing bond options Bond call option: current time = 0, option maturity = t, bond maturity = T, strike = K In the Gaussian case, there is an analytic solution: However, in the Lévy setting, the expectation becomes: Fortunately, a numerical solution is available because the joint density function for the last two stochastic terms can be found. (Very complicated) Comparison method: We compare the pricing difference against the various forward price/strike price ratio. Option maturity = 1yr, bond maturity = 2yr Note that at-the-money strike  0.951

20 Comparing bond options result Strike priceGaussian Hyperbolic (  =10)(  =0.01) Figure 3Differences in option pricing vs forward/strike price ratio As one can see, for  =10, the difference is minimal, but for  =0.01, At-the-money option is lower for the hyperbolic model (~10%) while the in-the-money and out-of- the-money prices are slightly higher, forming the W-shaped pattern as show in Figure 3.

21 Conclusion Lévy process – a generalization to Brownian motion that allows jumps, which is more realistic to model bond/stock price movements. Under the assumption of Markovian short rate and stationary volatility structure, the only possible volatility structures are Ho-Lee and Vasiček. We can re-derive the mean-reverting short rate process (Hull-White) when we utilize Vasiček volatility even under Lévy process. When we use hyperbolic model, forward rates predicted by Lévy model is always slightly higher than the Gaussian model. For bond option, the price differences form a W-shaped against the forward/strike price ratio, due to heavier weight in the center and in the tail for the hyperbolic distribution.

22 Discussion Future research on time-changed Lévy process, which can capture both jump and stochastic volatility. Apply time-changed Lévy process to the LIBOR model and explore the term structure under the model. Apply time-changed Lévy process to model stock/bond price movement for option pricing with correlation, or to model firm value movement for credit derivative pricing (for structural model evaluation)

23 References Carr, P. G´eman, H., Madan, D., Wu, L., Yor, M. (2003) Option Pricing using Integral Transforms. Stanford Financial Mathematics Seminar (Winter 2003). Carr, P., Wu, L. (2003) Time-Changed Lévy Processes and Option Pricing. Journal of Financial Economics, Elsevier, Vol 71(1), Eberlein, E., Baible, S. (1999). Term structure models driven by general Lévy processes. Mathematical Finance, Vol 9(1), Eberlein, E., Keller, U. (1995). Hyperbolic distributions in finance. Bernoulli, 1, Eberlein, E., Keller, U., Prause, K. (1998) New insights into smile, mispricing and value at risk: the hyperbolic model. Journal of Business 71. Eberlein, E., Özkan, F. (2005) The Lévy Libor Model. Finance and Stochastics 9,

THE END Thank you for participating.

25 Appendix Appendix 1.1 BACK

26 Appendix Appendix 1.2 From (1), and lemma 1.1, Take –log, we get, Differentiate w.r.t. T, we have, BACK

27 Appendix Appendix 1.3 From (1), and lemma 1.1, From (2), setting t  T Integrate r(T), BACK

28 Appendix Appendix 2.2 From (2), we can see that r is Markov iff Z(T) is Markov, where (  ) Assume r is Markov. Then is independent of because of the independent increments of L. Thus the last two terms are equal, implying the equality of the first two terms. BACK

29 Appendix Appendix 2.2 (con’t) Howeveris measurable w.r.t.. Therefore, is some function of Z(T), say. Then the joint distribution of X and Y, where is only defined on (x,G(x)), thus can’t be continuous w.r.t. 2 on  2. By lemma 2.1, BACK

30 Appendix Appendix 2.2 (con’t) (  )Assume, then BACK

31 Appendix Appendix 2.2 (con’t) For the corollary, simply take U=T*,  then we have  2 (t,T*)=   2 (t,T), where  is independent of t (yet it may depend on T and T*). If  =0, then  2 (t,T*)=0 for all t. However, this implies that  (t,T)=constant for all T, which violates the assumption that  (t,T)>0 for t  T and  (t,t)=0. Therefore,   0. Then we can define and obtain our desired result, where BACK

32 Appendix Appendix 2.3 Write. Then. Writing we have Rearranging terms, we have Since both sides cannot depend on t or T, it must equal to some constant a. If a=0, then (Ho-Lee) If a  0, then (Vasiček) BACK