Coherent Measures of Risk David Heath Carnegie Mellon University Joint work with Philippe Artzner, Freddy Delbaen, Jean-Marc Eber; research partially funded.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Introduction to Portfolio Selection and Capital Market Theory: Static Analysis
Advertisements

Chapter 12: Basic option theory
Asset Pricing. Pricing Determining a fair value (price) for an investment is an important task. At the beginning of the semester, we dealt with the pricing.
Mean-variance portfolio theory
Valuation of Financial Options Ahmad Alanani Canadian Undergraduate Mathematics Conference 2005.
Investment Science D.G. Luenberger
Ch.7 The Capital Asset Pricing Model: Another View About Risk
P.V. VISWANATH FOR A FIRST COURSE IN INVESTMENTS.
1 Risk, Returns, and Risk Aversion Return and Risk Measures Real versus Nominal Rates EAR versus APR Holding Period Returns Excess Return and Risk Premium.
Lecture 4 on Individual Optimization Risk Aversion
Planning under Uncertainty
Chapter 8 Portfolio Selection.
Lecture Presentation Software to accompany Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management Seventh Edition by Frank K. Reilly & Keith C. Brown Chapter.
Risk and Rates of Return
Diversification and Portfolio Management (Ch. 8)
© 2008 Pearson Education Canada13.1 Chapter 13 Hedging with Financial Derivatives.
Notes – Theory of Choice
Chapter 5 Risk and Rates of Return © 2005 Thomson/South-Western.
Defining and Measuring Risk
Risk Aversion and Capital Allocation to Risky Assets
Vicentiu Covrig 1 Portfolio management. Vicentiu Covrig 2 “ Never tell people how to do things. Tell them what to do and they will surprise you with their.
Risk, Return, and Discount Rates Capital Market History The Risk/Return Relation Application to Corporate Finance.
INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS ©2011 The McGraw-Hill Companies CHAPTER 6 Risk Aversion and Capital Allocation to Risky Assets.
Lecture 3: Arrow-Debreu Economy
Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management
AN INTRODUCTION TO PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT
Capital Asset Pricing Model Part 1: The Theory. Introduction Asset Pricing – how assets are priced? Equilibrium concept Portfolio Theory – ANY individual.
Yield Curves and Term Structure Theory. Yield curve The plot of yield on bonds of the same credit quality and liquidity against maturity is called a yield.
Investment Basics Clench Fraud Trust Investment Workshop October 24, 2011 Jeff Frketich, CFA.
Roman Keeney AGEC  In many situations, economic equations are not linear  We are usually relying on the fact that a linear equation.
Portfolio Management Lecture: 26 Course Code: MBF702.
Capital Allocation Survey. Purpose of Allocating Capital  Not a goal in itself  Used to make further calculations, like adequacy of business unit profits,
Alternative Measures of Risk. The Optimal Risk Measure Desirable Properties for Risk Measure A risk measure maps the whole distribution of one dollar.
Portfolio Management-Learning Objective
Lecture Presentation Software to accompany Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management Seventh Edition by Frank K. Reilly & Keith C. Brown Chapter 7.
Endogenous growth Sophia Kazinnik University of Houston Economics Department.
STOCHASTIC DOMINANCE APPROACH TO PORTFOLIO OPTIMIZATION Nesrin Alptekin Anadolu University, TURKEY.
Some Background Assumptions Markowitz Portfolio Theory
The Cost of Financing Insurance Version 2.0 Glenn Meyers Insurance Services Office Inc. CAS Ratemaking Seminar March 13, 2001.
A History of Risk and Return
Corporate Banking and Investment Risk tolerance and optimal portfolio choice Marek Musiela, BNP Paribas, London.
Chapter 3 Discrete Time and State Models. Discount Functions.
Chapter 10: Options Markets Tuesday March 22, 2011 By Josh Pickrell.
Risks and Rates of Return
Requests for permission to make copies of any part of the work should be mailed to: Thomson/South-Western 5191 Natorp Blvd. Mason, OH Chapter 11.
Lecture 10 The Capital Asset Pricing Model Expectation, variance, standard error (deviation), covariance, and correlation of returns may be based on.
Chapter 4 Risk and Rates of Return © 2005 Thomson/South-Western.
TOPIC THREE Chapter 4: Understanding Risk and Return By Diana Beal and Michelle Goyen.
Chapter McGraw-Hill/IrwinCopyright © 2012 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. A Brief History of Risk and Return 1.
Types of IP Models All-integer linear programs Mixed integer linear programs (MILP) Binary integer linear programs, mixed or all integer: some or all of.
Chapter 3 Arbitrage and Financial Decision Making
FIN437 Vicentiu Covrig 1 Portfolio management Optimum asset allocation Optimum asset allocation (see chapter 7 Bodie, Kane and Marcus)
@ A.C.F. Vorst - Rotterdam 1 Optimal Risk Taking under VaR Restrictions Ton Vorst Erasmus Center for Financial Research January 2000 Paris, Lunteren, Odense,
Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management First Canadian Edition By Reilly, Brown, Hedges, Chang 6.
Chapter 5 Choice Under Uncertainty. Chapter 5Slide 2 Topics to be Discussed Describing Risk Preferences Toward Risk Reducing Risk The Demand for Risky.
The Council’s Approach to Economic Risk Michael Schilmoeller Northwest Power and Conservation Council for the Resource Adequacy Technical Committee September.
Investment Performance Measurement, Risk Tolerance and Optimal Portfolio Choice Marek Musiela, BNP Paribas, London.
Risk Management with Coherent Measures of Risk IPAM Conference on Financial Mathematics: Risk Management, Modeling and Numerical Methods January 2001.
Levy, Solomon and Levy's Microscopic Simulation of Financial Markets points us towards the future of financial economics." Harry M. Markowitz, Nobel Laureate.
Chapter 11 Risk and Rates of Return. Defining and Measuring Risk Risk is the chance that an unexpected outcome will occur A probability distribution is.
Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 5th edition © 2002 by John C. Hull 16.1 Value at Risk Chapter 16.
Chapter 7 An Introduction to Portfolio Management.
Caps and Swaps. Floating rate securities Coupon payments are reset periodically according to some reference rate. reference rate + index spread e.g.1-month.
MTH 105. FINANCIAL MARKETS What is a Financial market: - A financial market is a mechanism that allows people to trade financial security. Transactions.
Security Markets V Miloslav S Vošvrda Theory of Capital Markets.
BASIC MATHS FOR FINANCE
Capital Allocation to Risky Assets
Risk and Return.
Portfolio Risk Management : A Primer
Capital Allocation to Risky Assets
Presentation transcript:

Coherent Measures of Risk David Heath Carnegie Mellon University Joint work with Philippe Artzner, Freddy Delbaen, Jean-Marc Eber; research partially funded by Société Generale

Measuring Risk u Purpose: –Manage and control risk –Make good risk/return tradeoff –“Risk adjust” traders’ profits u To help with: –Regulation of traders and banks –Portfolio selection –Motivating traders to reduce risk

How should a risk measure behave? u Should provide a basis for setting “capital requirements” u Should be “reasonable” –Encourage diversification –Should respect “more is better” u Should be useable as a management tool –Should be compatible with allocation of risk limits to desks –Should provide sensible way to “risk-adjust” gains of different investment strategies (desks)

The basic model u For now, think only of “market risk” u For now, assume liquid markets  A “state of the market”  is then a set of prices for all securities. (i.e., a copy of WSJ)  For a given portfolio  and a given state , set X  (  ) = market value of  in state .  A risk measure  assigns a number  (X) to each such (random variable) X.

More generally...  Notice  maps X’s (not  ’s) into numbers. u More complexity can be introduced through X –X should give the value of the firm if required to liquidate at the end of period, for every possible state of the world –State  can specify amount of liquidity –Can consider “active” management over period »  must describe evolution of markets over period »instead of portfolio , must consider strategy (e.g., rebalance each day using futures to stay hedged)

Let’s focus on   Want  to provide capital requirements. –Suppose firm is required to allocate additional capital - what do they do with it »Riskless investment (which, and how riskless)? »Risky investment? –We assume: some particular instrument is specified. It’s price today is 1, and at end is r 0 (  ). (Might be pdb, money market, S&P) –  (X) tells the number of shares of this security which must be added to the portfolio to make it “safe enough”.

Axioms for “coherent”  u Units: –  (X+  r 0 ) =  (X) -  (for all  ) u Diversification: –  ((X+Y)/2)  (  (X)+  (Y))/2 u More is better: – If X  Y then  (Y)   (X) u Scale invariance: –  (  X) =   (X) (for all   0)

An aside... u In the presence of the linearity axiom, the diversification axiom can be written  (X+Y)   (X) +  (Y) u This means that a risk limit can be “allocated” to desks u If the inequality failed for a firm desiring to hold X+Y, firm could reduce capital requirement by setting up two subsidiaries, one to hold X and the other Y.

Do any such  exist? u Do we want one? (Maybe not!)  There are many such  ’s: –Take any set A of outcomes Set   (X) = - inf{X(  )/r 0 (  ) |  A} »Think of A as set of scenarios;  gives worst case –Take any set of probabilities P Set  p (X) = - inf{E P (X/r 0 ) | P  P} »Think of each P as a “generalized scenario”

Are there any more?  Theorem: If  is a finite set, then every coherent risk measure can be obtained from generalized scenarios. u So: specifying a coherent risk measure is the same as specifying a set of generalized scenarios.

How can (or does) one pick generalized scenarios? u SPAN uses generalized scenarios: –To set margin on a portfolio consisting of shares of some futures contract and options on that contract, consider prices (scenarios) by: –Let the futures price change by -3/3, -2/3, -1/3, 0, 1/3, 2/3, 3/3 of some “range”, and vols either move up or move down. (These are scenarios.) –Let the futures go up or down by an “extreme” move, vols stay the same. Need cover only 35% of the loss. (These are generalized …)

Another method u Let each desk generate relevant scenarios for instruments it trades; pass these to firm’s risk manager u Risk manager takes all combinations of these scenarios and may add some more u Resulting set of scenarios is given back to each desk, which must value its portfolio for each u Results are combined by firm risk manager

What about VaR?  VaR specifies a risk measure  VaR   VaR is computed for an X as follows: For a given probability P (the best guess at the “true” (physical or martingale?) probability) Compute the.01 quantile of the distribution of X under P The negative of this quantile =  VaR (X) u (implicitly assumes r 0 = 1.)

VaR is not coherent! u VaR satisfies all axioms except diversification (and it uses r 0 = 1). u This means VaR limits can’t be allocated to desks: each desk might satisfy limit but total portfolio might not. u Firms avoid VaR restrictions by setting up subsidiaries

VaR says: don’t diversify! u Consider a CCC bond. Suppose: –Probability of default over a week is.005 –Value after default is 0 –Yield spread is.26/yr or.005/week u Consider the portfolio: –Borrow $300,000 at risk-free rate –Purchase $300,000 of this bond u Value at end if no default is $1500 u Probability of default is.005, so VaR says OK! –In fact, can do this to any scale!

If you diversify: u If there are 3 independent bonds like this Consider borrowing $300,000 and purchasing $100,000 of each bond u Probability distribution of worth at end: (Let’s pretend interest rate = 0) Probability Value VaR requires E E

Even scarier u Most firms want to “get the highest return per unit of risk.” u If they use VaR to measure risk, they’ll be led to pile up the losses on a “small” set of scenarios (a set with probability less than.01) u If they use “black box” approach to reducing VaR they’ll do the same, probably without realizing it!

Does anything like VaR work? u Suppose we have chosen a P which we’d use to compute VaR u Suppose X has a continuous distribution (under P)  Then set  (X) = -E P (X | X  -VaR(X))  This  is coherent! (requires a proof)  It’s the smallest coherent  which depends only on the P-distribution of X’s and which is bigger than VaR.

More about this VaR-like  u To compute a 1% VaR by simulation, one might generate 10,000 random scenarios (using P) and use -the 100th worst one.  The corresponding estimate of our  would be the negative of the average of the 100 worst ones  If X is normally distributed, this  (X) is very close to VaR u This may be a good first step toward coherence

What’s next? u What are the consequences of trying to maximize return per unit of risk when using a coherent risk measure? –We think that something like that does make sense u Could a bank perform well if each desk used such a measure? –We think so.

Conclusions (to part 1 of talk) u Good risk management requires the use of coherent risk measures u VaR is not a coherent risk measure –Can induce firms to arrange portfolio so that when the fail, they fail big –Discourages diversification u There is a substitute for VaR which is more conservative than VaR, is about as easy to compute, and is coherent

Ongoing research (results tentative!!) u Can coherent risk measures be used for –Firm-wide risk management? –In portfolio selection? u What criteria make one coherent risk measure (or one set of generalized scenarios) better than another? u Can such measures help with –Decentralized portfolio optimization? –“Risk adjusting” trading profits?

Maxing expected return per unit risk u Using VaR, problem is: –Maximize E(X) –subject to VaR(X)  K u Problem is (usually) unbounded –It is if there’s any X with E(X)>0 and VaR(X)  0 (like being short a far out-of- the-money put) u VaR constraint is satisfied for arbitrarily large position size!

With a coherent risk measure u We’ll see that –Firms can achieve “economically optimal” portfolios –Decision problem can be allocated to desks –Desks can each have their own P Desk –If these aren’t too inconsistent, still works! u But first -- in addition to regulators we need the firm’s owners

Meeting goals of shareholders u So far, risk measures were for regulation u Shareholders have a different point of view –Solvency isn’t enough –Don’t want too much risk of loss of investment u Shareholders may have different risk preferences than regulators u Firm must respect both regulators’ and shareholders’ demands

A “shareholders’” risk measure u Require firm to count shareholder’s investment as liability u This “desired shareholder value” may be –Fixed $ –Some index –In general, some random variable, say T (target) –Risk is the risk of missing target u Apply coherent risk measure to X-T.  Shareholders have risk measure  SH

The optimization problem  Let  Reg denote the regulator’s risk measure u Let P be some given probability measure u Let T be the “investor’s target”  Let  SH be the shareholders’ risk measure  Problem: Choose available X to maximize E P (X) subject to:  Reg (X)  0 and  SH (X-T)  0.

In liquid markets: Linear Program  In liquid markets the initial price of X,  0 (X) is a linear function of X. u Traded X’s form a linear space  Available X’s satisfy  0 (X) = K (capital) u Objective function (E P (X)) is linear in X u Constraints, written properly, are linear: –  Reg (X)  0 is same as E Q (X)  0 for all Q  Q Reg –  SH (X-T)  0 is same as E Q (X)  E Q (T) for all Q  Q SH

Is the resulting portfolio optimal? u Can firm get to shareholder’s optimal X? u Suppose: –Shareholders (or managers) have a utility function u, strictly increasing –Desired portfolio is solution X* to: »Maximize E P (u(X)) over all available X satisfying regulator’s constraints –Suppose such an X* exists –Can managers specify T and  SH so that X* is the solution to the above LP?

Forcing optimality u Theorem: Let T = X* and Q SH = set of all probability measures. Then the only feasible solution to the LP is X*. Proof: If X is feasible, then shareholder constraints require X  T (= X*). But if any available X  X* were actually larger (on a set with positive P-measure), E P (u(X)) would be bigger than E P (u(X*)), so X* wouldn’t have maximized expected utility

If the firm has trading desks  Let X 1, X 2, …, X D the spaces of random terminal worths available to desks 1, 2, …D  Then random variables available to firm are elements of X = X 1 + X 2 + … + X D. u Suppose target T* is allocated arbitrarily to desks so that T* = T 1 + T 2 + … + T D. u Suppose initial capital is arbitrarily allocated to desks: K = K 1 + … + K D

 and Regulator’s risk is assigned (for each regulator probability Q  Q Reg ) to desks: r Q,1, r Q,2, …, r Q,D summing to 0.

Let desk d try to solve  Choose X d *  X d to maximize E P (X d ) subject to: –  0 (X d ) = K d –E Q (X d )  E Q (T d ) for every Q  Q SH –EQ(X d )  r Q,d for every Q  Q Reg

Clearly...  X 1 * + X 2 * + … + X D * is feasible for the firm’s problem, so E P (X 1 *+…+X D *) is  E P (X*). –i.e., desks can’t get better total solution than firm could get  Since X* can be decomposed as X 1 + X 2 + … + X D where X d  X d, with appropriate “splitting of resources” as above desks will achieve optimal portfolio for the firm

How can firm do this allocation? u Set up an internal market for “perturbations” of all of the arbitrary allocations. Desks can trade such perturbations; i.e., can agree that one desk will lower the rhs of one of its constraints and the other will increase its. But this agreement has a price (to be set internally by this market). (Value of each desk’s objective function is lowered by the amount of its payments in this internal market.)

Market equilibrium u The only equilibrium for this market produces the optimal portfolio for the firm. –(Look at the firm’s dual problem; this tells the equilibrium internal prices associated with each constraint.)

What if each desk has its own P d ?  If there is some P such that E P d (X) = E P (X) for all X  X d then any market equilibrium solves the firm’s LP for this measure P. u If there isn’t then there is “internal arbitrage” and no market equilibrium exists.