GENERAL COMPETITIVE EQUILIBRIUM

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE
Advertisements

Equity, Efficiency and Need
Factor Markets and the Distribution of Income
1 Chapter 3 – Tools of Normative Analysis Public Finance McGraw-Hill/Irwin © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., All Rights Reserved.
General Equilibrium Theory
International Economics Tenth Edition
Basic Concepts in Economics: Theory of Demand and Supply
Microeconomics General equilibrium Institute of Economic Theories - University of Miskolc Mónika Kis-Orloczki Assistant lecturer.
1 of 62 Copyright © 2011 Worth Publishers· International Economics· Feenstra/Taylor, 2/e. Chapter 2: Trade and Technology: The Ricardian Model Trade and.
The Theory of Aggregate Demand Classical Model. Learning Objectives Understand the role of money in the classical model. Learn the relationship between.
Chapter 11 PRODUCTION FUNCTIONS Copyright ©2002 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. MICROECONOMIC THEORY BASIC PRINCIPLES.
PREFERENCES AND UTILITY
Goods Prices and Factor Prices: The Distributional Consequences of International Trade Nothing is accomplished until someone sells something. (popular.
Microeconomic Theory Basic Principles and Extensions, 9e
THE MATHEMATICS OF OPTIMIZATION
Chapter 12 © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western General Equilibrium and Welfare.
DEMAND RELATIONSHIPS AMONG GOODS
Chapter 15 APPLIED COMPETITIVE ANALYSIS Copyright ©2002 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. MICROECONOMIC THEORY BASIC.
PRODUCTION.
Chapter 12 © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western General Equilibrium and Welfare.
The Theory of Aggregate Supply Chapter 4. 2 The Theory of Production Representative Agent Economy: all output is produced from labor and capital and in.
The Theory of Aggregate Supply Classical Model. Learning Objectives Understand the determinants of output. Understand how output is distributed. Learn.
Part 7 Further Topics © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western.
Part 4 © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western Production, Costs, and Supply.
THE MATHEMATICS OF OPTIMIZATION
Factor Endowments and the Heckscher-Ohlin Theory
1 Chapter 12 GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM AND WELFARE Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
1 Chapter 3 PREFERENCES AND UTILITY Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
Chapter 1 Economic Models © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western.
INCOME AND SUBSTITUTION EFFECTS
Applied Economics for Business Management
© 2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc Chapter 13 Competitive General Equilibrium.
ECON 101: Introduction to Economics - I Lecture 3 – Demand and Supply.
General Equilibrium and Market Efficiency
Utility Maximization and Choice
1 Chapter 10: General Equilibrium So far, we have studied a partial equilibrium analysis, which determines the equilibrium price and quantities in one.
Chapter 6 Production. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 62 Topics to be Discussed The Technology of Production Production with One Variable Input.
Production Chapter 6.
5.1 Household Behavior and Consumer Choice We have studied the basics of markets: how demand and supply determine prices and how changes in demand and.
INCOME AND SUBSTITUTION EFFECTS
DEMAND RELATIONSHIPS AMONG GOODS
Trade: Factor Availability and Factor Proportions Are Key
Perfect Competition A perfectly competitive industry is one that obeys the following assumptions:  there are a large number of firms, each producing the.
Chapter 2 Theoretical Tools of Public Finance © 2007 Worth Publishers Public Finance and Public Policy, 2/e, Jonathan Gruber 1 of 43 Theoretical Tools.
Household Behavior and Consumer Choice
GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM AND WELFARE
Total Output, x “Stylized” view of production functions – long run and short run Long-run Production with 2 variable inputs (v 1, v 2 ): v1v1 v2v2 v11v11.
Chapter 9 Production Functions
Part 4 © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western Production, Costs, and Supply.
1 Resource Markets CHAPTER 11 © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
1 Exchange. 2 Two consumers, A and B. Their endowments of goods 1 and 2 are E.g. The total quantities available and units of good 1 units of good 2. and.
Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior. Chapter 32©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Introduction How are consumer preferences used to determine demand? How do consumers.
1 Consumer Choice and Demand CHAPTER 6 © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Third Edition Copyright © 2010 Worth Publishers 1 of 44 Theoretical Tools of Public Finance F ERNANDO.
1 Chapter 3 PREFERENCES AND UTILITY Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 4 Resources, Comparative Advantage, and Income Distribution.
International Economics Tenth Edition
Lecture 4 Consumer Behavior Recommended Text: Franks and Bernanke - Chapter 5.
Slide 1Copyright © 2004 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited Chapter 16 General Equilibrium and Market Efficiency.
Introduction to Neoclassical Trade Theory: Tools to Be Employed Copyright © 2010 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
1 Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization CHAPTER 6 Appendix © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
5 © 2004 Prentice Hall Business PublishingPrinciples of Economics, 7/eKarl Case, Ray Fair Household Behavior and Consumer Choice Appendix: Indifference.
NJUIED Chapter 12 GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM AND WELFARE 吴福象 南京大学 商学院 产业经济学系 电子信箱: 电话: ( 办公室 安中楼 1505) 课件:
Chapter 6 Production.
Efficiency and Equity in a Competitive Market
GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM AND WELFARE
Theoretical Tools of Public Finance
Introduction to Neoclassical Trade Theory: Tools to Be Employed
International Economics Twelfth Edition
Presentation transcript:

GENERAL COMPETITIVE EQUILIBRIUM Chapter 16 GENERAL COMPETITIVE EQUILIBRIUM MICROECONOMIC THEORY BASIC PRINCIPLES AND EXTENSIONS EIGHTH EDITION WALTER NICHOLSON Copyright ©2002 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Perfectly Competitive Price System We will assume that all markets are perfectly competitive There is some number of homogeneous goods in the economy both consumption goods and factors of production Each good has an equilibrium price There are no transaction or transportation costs Everyone has perfect information

Law of One Price A homogeneous good trades at the same price no matter who buys it or who sells it if one good traded at two different prices, demanders would rush to buy the good where it was cheaper and firms would try to sell their output where the price was higher these actions would tend to equalize the price of the good

Assumptions of Perfect Competition There are a large number of people buying any one good each person takes all prices as given each person seeks to maximize utility given his budget constraint There are a large number of firms producing each good each firm attempts to maximize profits each firm takes all prices as given

General Equilibrium Assume that there are only two goods, X and Y All individuals have identical preferences can be represented by an indifference map The production possibility curve can be used to show how outputs and inputs are related

Edgeworth Box Diagram Construction of the production possibility curve for X and Y starts with the assumption that the amounts of K and L are fixed An Edgeworth box shows every possible way the existing K and L might be used to produce X and Y Any point in the box represents a fully employed allocation of the available resources to X and Y

Edgeworth Box Diagram Labor in Y production Capital in Y OY production Labor in X production Capital in Y production in X Capital for X Capital for Y Labor for Y Labor for X OY Total Capital A  OX Total Labor

Edgeworth Box Diagram Many of the allocations in the Edgeworth box are inefficient it is possible to produce more X and more Y by shifting capital and labor around We will assume that competitive markets will not exhibit inefficient input choices We want to find the efficient allocations they illustrate the actual production outcomes

Edgeworth Box Diagram We will use isoquant maps for the two goods the isoquant map for good X uses OX as the origin the isoquant map for good Y uses OY as the origin The efficient allocations will occur where the isoquants are tangent to one another

Edgeworth Box Diagram Point A is inefficient because, by moving along Y1, we can increase X from X1 to X2 while holding Y constant OY Total Capital Y1 Y2 X2  A X1 OX Total Labor

Edgeworth Box Diagram We could also increase Y from Y1 to Y2 while holding X constant by moving along X1 OY Total Capital Y1 Y2 X2  A X1 OX Total Labor

Edgeworth Box Diagram At each efficient point, the RTS (of K for L) is equal in both X and Y production OY Total Capital P4 P3 P2 P1 X2 X1 X4 X3 Y1 Y2 Y3 Y4 OX Total Labor

Production Possibility Frontier The locus of efficient points shows the maximum output of Y that can be produced for any level of X we can use this information to construct a production possibility frontier shows the alternative outputs of X and Y that can be produced with the fixed capital and labor inputs

Production Possibility Frontier Each efficient point of production becomes a point on the production possibility frontier Quantity of Y OX P1 Y4 P2 Y3 The negative of the slope of the production possibility frontier is the rate of product transformation (RPT) P3 Y2 P4 Y1 Quantity of X X1 X2 X3 X4 OY

Rate of Product Transformation The rate of product transformation (RPT) between two outputs is the negative of the slope of the production possibility frontier

Rate of Product Transformation The rate of product transformation shows how X can be technically traded for Y while continuing to keep the available productive inputs efficiently employed

Shape of the Production Possibility Frontier The production possibility frontier shown earlier exhibited an increasing RPT this concave shape will characterize most production situations RPT is equal to the ratio of MCX to MCY

Shape of the Production Possibility Frontier As production of X rises and production of Y falls, the ratio of MCX to MCY rises this occurs if both goods are produced under diminishing returns increasing the production of X raises MCX, while reducing the production of Y lowers MCY this could also occur if some inputs were more suited for X production than for Y production

Shape of the Production Possibility Frontier But we have assumed that inputs are homogeneous We need an explanation that allows homogeneous inputs and constant returns to scale The production possibility frontier will be concave if goods X and Y use inputs in different proportions

Opportunity Cost The production possibility frontier demonstrates that there are many possible efficient combinations of two goods Producing more of one good necessitates lowering the production of the other good this is what economists mean by opportunity cost

Opportunity Cost The opportunity cost of one more unit of X is the reduction in Y that this entails Thus, the opportunity cost is best measured as the RPT (of X for Y) at the prevailing point on the production possibility frontier note that this opportunity cost rises as more X is produced

Production Possibilities Suppose that guns (X) and butter (Y) are produced using only labor according to the following production functions: If labor supply is fixed at 100, then LX + LY = 100 or X2 + 4Y2 = 100

Production Possibilities Taking the total differential, we get 2XdX + 8YdY = 0 or Note that RPT increases as X rises and Y falls

Determining Equilibrium Prices We can use the production possibility frontier along with a set of indifference curves to show how equilibrium prices are determined the indifference curves represent individuals’ preferences for the two goods

Determining Equilibrium Prices If the prices of X and Y are PX and PY, society’s budget constraint is C Quantity of Y C Output will be X1, Y1 Y1 Individuals will demand X1’, Y1’ Y1’ U3 U2 C U1 Quantity of X X1 X1’

Determining Equilibrium Prices Thus, there is excess demand for X and excess supply of Y Quantity of Y C The price of X will rise and the price of Y will fall Y1 excess supply Y1* Y1’ U3 U2 C U1 Quantity of X X1 X1* X1’ excess demand

Determining Equilibrium Prices The equilibrium prices will be PX* and PY* Quantity of Y C* C The equilibrium output will be X1* and Y1* Y1 Y1* Y1’ U3 U2 C U1 C* Quantity of X X1 X1* X1’

General Equilibrium Pricing Suppose that the production possibility frontier can be represented by X 2 + 4Y 2 = 100 Suppose also that the community’s preferences can be represented by

General Equilibrium Pricing Under perfect competition, profit-maximizing firms will equate RPT and the ratio of PX /PY For consumers, utility maximization requires that

General Equilibrium Pricing Equilibrium requires that firms and individuals face the same price ratio or X 2 = 4Y 2

General Equilibrium Pricing The equilibrium should also be on the production possibility frontier X 2 + 4Y 2 = 2X 2 = 100

Comparative Statics Analysis The equilibrium price ratio will tend to persist until either preferences or production technologies change If preferences were to shift toward good X, PX /PY would rise and more X and less Y would be produced we would move in a clockwise direction along the production possibility frontier

Comparative Statics Analysis Technical progress in the production of good X will shift the production possibility curve outward this will lower the relative price of X more X will be consumed assuming that X is a normal good the effect on Y is ambiguous

Technical Progress in the Production of X Technical progress in the production of X will shift the production possibility curve out Quantity of Y The relative price of X will fall Y1 Y0 More X will be consumed U3 U2 U1 Quantity of X X0 X1

The Corn Laws Debate High tariffs on grain imports were imposed by the British government after the Napoleonic wars Economists debated the effects of these “corn laws” between 1829 and 1845 what effect would the elimination of these tariffs have on factor prices?

The Corn Laws Debate Quantity of manufactured goods (Y) If the corn laws completely prevented trade, output would be X0 and Y0 The equilibrium prices will be PX* and PY* Y0 U2 U1 Quantity of Grain (X) X0

The Corn Laws Debate Quantity of manufactured goods (Y) Removal of the corn laws will change the prices to PX’ and PY’ Output will be X1’ and Y1’ Y1’ Individuals will demand X1 and Y1 Y0 Y1 U2 U1 Quantity of Grain (X) X1’ X0 X1

The Corn Laws Debate Grain imports will be X1 – X1’ Quantity of manufactured goods (Y) Grain imports will be X1 – X1’ These imports will be financed by the export of manufactured goods equal to Y1’ – Y1 Y1’ exports of goods Y0 Y1 U2 U1 Quantity of Grain (X) X1’ X0 X1 imports of grain

The Corn Laws Debate We can use an Edgeworth box diagram to see the effects of the elimination of the corn laws on the use of labor and capital If the corn laws were repealed, there would be an increase in the production of manufactured goods and a decline in the production of grain

The Corn Laws Debate A repeal of the corn laws would result in a movement from P3 to P1 where more Y and less X is produced OY Total Capital P4 P3 P2 P1 X2 X1 X4 X3 Y1 Y2 Y3 Y4 OX Total Labor

The Corn Laws Debate If we assume that grain production is relatively capital intensive, the movement from P3 to P1 causes the ratio of K to L to rise in both industries the relative price of capital will fall the relative price of labor will rise The repeal of the corn laws will be harmful to capital owners and helpful to laborers

Political Support for Trade Policies Trade policies may affect the relative incomes of various factors of production In the United States, exports tend to be intensive in their use of skilled labor whereas imports tend to be intensive in their use of unskilled labor free trade policies will result in rising relative wages for skilled workers and in falling relative wages for unskilled workers

Existence of General Equilibrium Prices Beginning with 19th century investigations by Leon Walras, economists have examined whether there exists a set of prices that equilibrates all markets simultaneously if this set of prices exists, how can it be found?

Existence of General Equilibrium Prices Suppose that there are n goods in fixed supply in this economy Let Si (i =1,…,n) be the total supply of good i available Let Pi (i =1,…n) be the price of good i The total demand for good i depends on all prices Di (P1,…,Pn) for i =1,…,n

Existence of General Equilibrium Prices We will write this demand function as dependent on the whole set of prices (P) Di (P) Walras’ problem: Does there exist an equilibrium set of prices such that Di (P*) = Si for all values of i ?

Excess Demand Functions The excess demand function for any good i at any set of prices (P) is defined to be EDi (P) = Di (P) – Si This means that the equilibrium condition can be rewritten as EDi (P*) = Di (P*) – Si = 0

Excess Demand Functions Note that the excess demand functions are homogeneous of degree zero this implies that we can only establish equilibrium relative prices in a Walrasian-type model Walras also assumed that demand functions (and excess demand functions) were continuous small changes in price lead to small changes in quantity demanded

Walras’ Law A final observation that Walras made was that the n excess demand equations are not independent of one another Walras’ law shows that the total value of excess demand is zero at any set of prices

Walras’ Law Walras’ law holds for any set of prices (not just equilibrium prices) There can be neither excess demand for all goods together nor excess supply

Walras’ Proof of the Existence of Equilibrium Prices The market equilibrium conditions provide (n-1) independent equations in (n-1) unknown relative prices Can we solve the system for an equilibrium condition? the equations are not necessarily linear all prices must be nonnegative To attack these difficulties, Walras set up a complicated proof

Walras’ Proof of the Existence of Equilibrium Prices Start with an arbitrary set of prices Holding the other n-1 prices constant, find the equilibrium price for good 1 (P1’) Holding P1’ and the other n-2 prices constant, solve for the equilibrium price of good 2 (P2’) in changing P2 from its initial position to P2’, the price calculated for good 1 need no longer be an equilibrium price

Walras’ Proof of the Existence of Equilibrium Prices Using the provisional prices P1’ and P2’, solve for P3’ proceed in this way until an entire set of provisional relative prices has been found In the 2nd iteration of Walras’ proof, P2’,…,Pn’ are held constant while a new equilibrium price is calculated for good 1 proceed in this way until an entire new set of prices is found

Walras’ Proof of the Existence of Equilibrium Prices The importance of Walras’ proof is its ability to demonstrate the simultaneous nature of the problem of finding equilibrium prices Because it is cumbersome, it is not generally used today More recent work uses some relatively simple tools from advance mathematics

Brouwer’s Fixed-Point Theorem Any continuous mapping [F(X)] of a closed, bounded, convex set into itself has at least one fixed point (X*) such that F(X*) = X*

Brouwer’s Fixed-Point Theorem Suppose that f(x) is a continuous function defined on the interval [0,1] and that f(x) takes on the values also on the interval [0,1] f (x) Any continuous function must cross the 45 line 1 This point of crossing is a “fixed point” because f maps this point (x*) into itself x* f (x*)  45 x 1

Brouwer’s Fixed-Point Theorem A mapping is a rule that associates the points in one set with points in another set Let X be a point for which a mapping (F) is defined the mapping associates X with some point Y = F(X) If a mapping is defined over a subset of n-dimensional space (S), and if every point in S is associated (by the rule F) with some other point in S, the mapping is said to map S into itself

Brouwer’s Fixed-Point Theorem A mapping is continuous if points that are “close” to each other are mapped into other points that are “close” to each other The Brouwer fixed-point theorem considers mappings defined on certain kinds of sets closed (they contain their boundaries) bounded (none of their dimensions is infinitely large) convex (they have no “holes” in them)

Proof that Equilibrium Prices Exist Because only relative prices matter, it is convenient to assume that prices have been defined so that the sum of all prices is equal to 1 Thus, for any arbitrary set of prices (P1,…,Pn), we can use normalized prices of the form

Proof that Equilibrium Prices Exist These new prices will retain their original relative values and will sum to 1 These new prices will sum to 1

Proof that Equilibrium Prices Exist We will assume that the feasible set of prices (S) is composed of all nonnegative numbers that sum to 1 S is the set to which we will apply Brouwer’s theorem S is closed, bounded, and convex We will need to define a continuous mapping of S into itself

Free Goods Equilibrium does not really require that excess demand be zero for every market Goods may exist for which the markets are in equilibrium where supply exceeds demand (negative excess demand) it is necessary for the prices of these goods to be equal to zero “free goods”

Proof that Equilibrium Prices Exist The equilibrium conditions are EDi (P*) = 0 for Pi* > 0 EDi (P*)  0 for Pi* = 0 Note that this set of equilibrium prices continues to obey Walras’ law

Proof that Equilibrium Prices Exist In order to achieve equilibrium, prices of goods in excess demand should be raised, whereas those in excess supply should have their prices lowered

Proof that Equilibrium Prices Exist We define the mapping F(P) for any normalized set of prices (P), such that the ith component of F(P) is given by F i(P) = Pi + EDi (P) The mapping performs the necessary task of appropriately raising or lowering prices

Proof that Equilibrium Prices Exist Two problems exist with this mapping First, nothing ensures that the prices will be nonnegative the mapping must be redefined to be F i(P) = Max [Pi + EDi (P),0] the new prices defined by the mapping must be positive or zero

Proof that Equilibrium Prices Exist Second, the recalculated prices are not necessarily normalized they will not sum to 1 it will be simple to normalize such that we will assume that this normalization has been done

Proof that Equilibrium Prices Exist Thus, F satisfies the conditions of the Brouwer fixed-point theorem it is a continuous mapping of the set S into itself There exists a point (P*) that is mapped into itself For this point, Pi* = Max [Pi* + EDi (P*),0] for all i

Proof that Equilibrium Prices Exist This says that P* is an equilibrium set of prices For Pi* > 0, Pi* = Pi* + EDi (P*) EDi (P*) = 0 For Pi* = 0, Pi* + EDi (P*)  0 EDi (P*)  0

A General Equilibrium with Three Goods The economy of Oz is composed only of three precious metals: (1) silver, (2) gold, and (3) platinum there are 10 (thousand) ounces of each metal available The demands for gold and platinum are

A General Equilibrium with Three Goods Equilibrium in the gold and platinum markets requires that demand equal supply in both markets simultaneously

A General Equilibrium with Three Goods This system of simultaneous equations can be solved as P2/P1 = 2 P3/P1 = 3 In equilibrium: gold will have a price twice that of silver platinum will have a price three times that of silver the price of platinum will be 1.5 times that of gold

A General Equilibrium with Three Goods Because Walras’ law must hold, we know P1ED1 = – P2ED2 – P3ED3 Substituting the excess demand functions for gold and silver and substituting, we get

Money in General Equilibrium Models Competitive market forces determine only relative and not absolute prices To examine how the absolute price level is determined, we must introduce money into our models

Money in General Equilibrium Models Money serves two primary functions in any economy it facilitates transactions by providing an accepted medium of exchange it acts as a store of value so that economic actors can better allocate their spending decisions over time

Money in General Equilibrium Models One of the most important functions played by money is to act as an accounting standard A competitive market system for n goods can generally arrive at an equilibrium set of prices (P1,…,Pn) these prices are unique only up to a common multiple only relative prices can be determined

Money in General Equilibrium Models In principle, any good (k) could be chosen as the accounting standard the prices of the other n-1 goods would be referred to in terms of the price of k the relative prices of the goods will be unaffected by the choice of k Societies generally adopt fiat money as the accounting standard

Money in General Equilibrium Models In an economy where money is produced in a way similar to any other good (commodity money), the relative price of money is determined by the forces of demand and supply if gold is used, new discoveries will increase the supply of gold, lower its relative price, and increase the relative prices of other goods

Money in General Equilibrium Models With fiat money, the government is the sole supplier of money and can generally choose how much it wishes to produce Classical economists suggested that the economy can be dichotomized into two sectors real: where relative prices are determined monetary: where the absolute price level is set

Money in General Equilibrium Models Classical economists argued that the quantity of money available has no effect on the real sector This “classical dichotomy” only holds if: individuals’ MRS between two real commodities is independent of the amount of money available firms’ RPT between two real commodities is independent of the amount of money available

Money in General Equilibrium Models The classical dichotomy will hold if firms and individuals only choose to hold money in order to perform transactions money yields no utility or productivity If there are two nonmonetary goods (X and Y) in the economy, total transactions will be PX*X + PY*Y

Money in General Equilibrium Models Conducting these transactions requires that a fraction () of their total value be available as circulating money The demand for money will be DM = (PX*X + PY*Y) Monetary equilibrium requires that DM = SM

Money in General Equilibrium Models A doubling of the money supply would throw this system into disequilibrium there would be an excess supply of money according to Walras’ law, this would be balanced by a net excess demand for goods

Money in General Equilibrium Models Equilibrium could be restored by a precise doubling of equilibrium nominal prices the transactions demand for money would double but relative prices would not change

Important Points to Note: Simple Marshallian models of supply and demand in several markets may not in themselves be adequate for addressing general equilibrium questions they do not provide a direct way to tie markets together and illustrating the feedback effects that occur when market equilibria change

Important Points to Note: A simple general equilibrium model of relative price determination for two goods can be developed using an indifference curve map to represent demands for the goods and the production possibility frontier to represent supply this model is useful for examining comparative statics in a general equilibrium context

Important Points to Note: Construction of the production possibility frontier from the Edgeworth box diagram permits an integration of factor markets into a simple general equilibrium model the shape of the production possibility frontier shows how reallocating factors of production among outputs affects the marginal costs associated with those outputs the slope of the production possibility frontier (RPT) measures the ratio of marginal costs

Important Points to Note: Whether a set of competitive prices exists that will equilibrate many markets simultaneously is a complex theoretical question such a set of prices will exist if demand and supply functions are suitably continuous and if Walras’ law (which requires that net excess demand be zero at any set of prices) holds

Important Points to Note: Incorporating money into a general equilibrium model is a major focus of macroeconomic research in some cases, such monetary models will exhibit the classical dichotomy in the monetary forces will have no effect on relative prices observed in the “real” economy these cases are rather restrictive so the extent to which the classical dichotomy holds in the real world remains an unresolved issue