 Economic Foundations of Insurance Pricing UNSW Actuarial Research Symposium 14 November 2003

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Valuation of Financial Options Ahmad Alanani Canadian Undergraduate Mathematics Conference 2005.
Advertisements

Introduction to Derivatives and Risk Management Corporate Finance Dr. A. DeMaskey.
© 2003 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Return, Risk, and the Security Market Line Chapter Thirteen.
Lecture Presentation Software to accompany Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management Seventh Edition by Frank K. Reilly & Keith C. Brown Chapter.
Risk and Rates of Return
1 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles 1 Part 2 : Asset Valuation & Portfolio theory (6 hrs) 2.1. Case study 1 : buy side & sell side.
Diversification and Portfolio Management (Ch. 8)
© 2002 South-Western Publishing 1 Chapter 10 Foreign Exchange Futures.
AN INTRODUCTION TO PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT
Picking the Right Investments Choosing the Right Discount Rate
L9: Consumption, Saving, and Investments 1 Lecture 9: Consumption, Saving, and Investments The following topics will be covered: –Consumption and Saving.
The Capital Asset Pricing Model P.V. Viswanath Based on Damodaran’s Corporate Finance.
Chapter 6 An Introduction to Portfolio Management.
Basic Tools of Finance Finance is the field that studies how people make decisions regarding the allocation of resources over time and the handling of.
Lecture 3: Arrow-Debreu Economy
Investment Analysis Lecture: 21 Course Code: MBF702.
Valuation and levered Betas
Investment Analysis and Portfolio management
AN INTRODUCTION TO PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT
This module identifies the general determinants of common share prices. It begins by describing the relationships between the current price of a security,
1 Finance School of Management Chapter 13: The Capital Asset Pricing Model Objective The Theory of the CAPM Use of CAPM in benchmarking Using CAPM to determine.
Portfolio Management Lecture: 26 Course Code: MBF702.
Why study Managerial Finance?
Version 1.2 Copyright © 2000 by Harcourt, Inc. All rights reserved. Requests for permission to make copies of any part of the work should be mailed to:
Lecture Presentation Software to accompany Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management Seventh Edition by Frank K. Reilly & Keith C. Brown Chapter 7.
1 DISCOUNTED CASH FLOW MODELS (MIS-45&46) Seminar on Ratemaking Nashville, TNRuss Bingham March 11-12, 1999Hartford Financial Services.
Some Background Assumptions Markowitz Portfolio Theory
Investment and portfolio management MGT 531.  Lecture #31.
Chapter 3 Discrete Time and State Models. Discount Functions.
© 2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc. BZUPAGES.COM 1-1 Overview of Corporate Finance Hashim Ali Shah
TOPIC THREE Chapter 4: Understanding Risk and Return By Diana Beal and Michelle Goyen.
Ch.8 Valuation and Rates of Return Goal: 1) Definitions of values 2) Intrinsic Value Calculation 3) Required rate of return 4) Stock valuation.
Chapter 06 Risk and Return. Value = FCF 1 FCF 2 FCF ∞ (1 + WACC) 1 (1 + WACC) ∞ (1 + WACC) 2 Free cash flow (FCF) Market interest rates Firm’s business.
Chapter 10 Capital Markets and the Pricing of Risk
1 Portfolio Analysis Global Financial Management Campbell R. Harvey Fuqua School of Business Duke University
Skewness in Stock Returns: Reconciling the Evidence on Firm versus Aggregate Returns Rui Albuquerque Discussion by: Marcin Kacperczyk (NYU and NBER)
Mr. Weiss Unit 3 Vocabulary Words 1. law of demand; 2. law of diminishing marginal utility; 3. price elasticity of demand; 4. equilibrium price; _____the.
Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management First Canadian Edition By Reilly, Brown, Hedges, Chang 6.
Return and Risk The Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM)
Comments on “Counterparty Risk in Financial Contracts: Should the Insured Worry about the Insurer?” Erik Heitfield Federal Reserve Board FDIC/JFSR 8 th.
1 CHAPTER ONE: MM Theory and No Arbitrage 1.MM Theory Two measurements of value Accounting: book value — historic cost Finance: market value — net present.
Chapter Outline 9.1Principals of Business Valuation Valuation Formula Components of the Opportunity Cost of Capital Compensation for Risk 9.2Risk Management.
Profit Margins In General Insurance Pricing (A Critical Assessment of Approaches) Nelson Henwood, Caroline Breipohl and Richard Beauchamp New Zealand Society.
Chapter McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Risk and Capital Budgeting 13.
Pricing insurance contracts: an incomplete market approach ACFI seminar, 2 November 2006 Antoon Pelsser University of Amsterdam & ING Group.
Risk and Return: Portfolio Theory and Assets Pricing Models
Decision theory under uncertainty
1 THE FUTURE: RISK AND RETURN. 2 RISK AND RETURN If the future is known with certainty, all investors will hold assets offering the highest rate of return.
T4.1 H&N, Ch. 4 Chapter Outline 4.1CONTRACTING COSTS OF RISK POOLING ARRANGEMENTS Types of Contracting Costs Ex Ante Premium Payments vs. Ex Post Assessments.
1 The economics of insurance demand and portfolio choice Lecture 1 Christian Gollier.
1 CHAPTER THREE: Portfolio Theory, Fund Separation and CAPM.
Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) Dr. BALAMURUGAN MUTHURAMAN Chapter
MTH 105. FINANCIAL MARKETS What is a Financial market: - A financial market is a mechanism that allows people to trade financial security. Transactions.
15-1 Chapter 15 Required Returns and the Cost of Capital © 2001 Prentice-Hall, Inc. Fundamentals of Financial Management, 11/e Created by: Gregory A. Kuhlemeyer,
1 RISK AND RETURN: DEBATING ALTERNATIVE MODELING “APPROACHES” (FIN - 10) Russ Bingham Vice President and Director of Corporate Research Hartford Financial.
Proceedings Paper Value Creation in Insurance – A Finance Perspective Russ Bingham CAS Annual Meeting Vice President andNov , 2004 Director.
F9 Financial Management. 2 Designed to give you the knowledge and application of: Section F: Cost of capital F1. Sources of finance and their short-term.
Chapter 5 Understanding Risk
CHAPTER 11 COST OF CAPITAL 1.
Capital Market Theory: An Overview
Key Concepts and Skills
Decisions Under Risk and Uncertainty
PROFIT AND CONTINGENCIES (FIN-28)
Risk and Rates of Return
Principles of Investing FIN 330
Saif Ullah Lecture Presentation Software to accompany Investment Analysis and.
The Stochastic Discount Factor for the Capital Asset Pricing Model
Global Equity Markets.
Overview of Working Capital Management
Chapter 8 Overview of Working Capital Management
Presentation transcript:

 Economic Foundations of Insurance Pricing UNSW Actuarial Research Symposium 14 November 2003

PricewaterhouseCoopers Introduction The economic foundations of insurance pricing are being debated actively at present –Regulators and insurance companies are seeking a sound economic basis to guide pricing decisions Myers and Cohn (1981) applied the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) to an insurance firm Many insurance professionals are uncomfortable with the conclusions of the Myers-Cohn approach, as it implies premiums should be set at levels below those considered viable

PricewaterhouseCoopers Outline of this presentation We have re-visited the foundations of insurance pricing, using modern economic valuation methods (SDF approach) –Conclusions intuitive to insurance practitioners, within a rigorous economic framework In this presentation, we: –review the Myers-Cohn approach –review economic valuation methods –outline the approach we have taken –summarise our key conceptual findings, and –illustrate how our approach might be applied to guide the setting of insurance premiums

PricewaterhouseCoopers Summary of our conclusions (1) Policyholders will, in aggregate, place a different value on a portfolio of insurance policies than shareholders will This value difference – the insurance surplus – gives rise to a range of premiums that policyholders and shareholders will be happy with – the feasible range of premiums Our approach, in contrast to CAPM-based approaches, allows the relationship between capital strength and premium to be determined, leading to the determination of the set of feasible combinations of these factors - the feasible region

PricewaterhouseCoopers Summary of our conclusions (2) The feasible region exists due to consumers’ assumed aversion to the insured risks, and the fact that these risks cannot be offset by traded securities – capital market incompleteness Consequently, “fair” premiums cannot be determined with reference to capital markets alone – pricing information from consumer insurance markets must be considered also

PricewaterhouseCoopers What did Myers and Cohn do ? 1.Discussed premiums with reference to the values of the components of the insurer’s balance sheet 2.Proposed a “fair premium principle”: The premium that makes entering into the insurance contract NPV-zero for shareholders 3.Employed CAPM to calculate the values of the components of the insurer’s balance sheet

 Economic Valuation – a brief refresher

PricewaterhouseCoopers Basic terminology and notation An asset is defined by the payoff (x) it provides to its owner The payoff typically: –occurs in the future –is uncertain (a random variable) The price or value (V) of an asset is the amount of cash we would pay today for the right to the asset’s risky future payoff e.g. The call option, with payoff distribution shown here, has a value of $0.09

PricewaterhouseCoopers Asset Pricing 101 (single time-period) Old way: “Risk-adjusted discount rate” New way: “Stochastic discount factor” Cash flow info required Expected payoff E(x) Payoff distribution x Discount factor Deterministic – but different for each asset: 1 / (1 + r j ) Stochastic – but prices all assets of interest: m Pricing formulaV = E(x) / (1 + r j )V = E(m x)

PricewaterhouseCoopers The risk premium is a covariance – with consumption Economic derivation says… Definition of covariance says… u’ – marginal utility; c* - optimal consumption; R f – gross risk-free return

PricewaterhouseCoopers A nested set of equilibrium models ModelAssumptionsDiscount factor Stochastic discount factor Expected utility, smooth utility function u m = A u’(c*) c* = agent’s optimal consumption Buhlmann’s model (1980) Exponential utility, closed market m = A exp(- c), c = total consumption Wang’s specialisation of Buhlmann’s model (2003) Total consumption normal, normal copula with assets m x = A x exp(- x h -1 (x)) x = h(z), z unit normal, x =  z, = (E(R c ) – R f ) /  (R c ) Capital Asset Pricing Model (1965-ish) Asset payoffs normalm = A x exp(- x (x-  x )/  x )

 The Insurance Surplus

PricewaterhouseCoopers The shareholders’ perspective Insurance companies take risk from policyholders for a fee, and offer the aggregate risk to shareholders –Any risk premium shareholders place on this aggregate risk will be based on its contribution to the variance of their entire asset portfolio (as a proxy for their consumption)

PricewaterhouseCoopers Consumers are willing to pay a risk premium for insurance Some aspects of individuals’ behaviour are not explained by economic valuation models: –We observe individuals holding concentrations of wealth in particular assets, like the family home –They also have exposure to concentrations of liability, such as obligations when injury is caused to another person while driving This gives rise to risks that can’t be offset in the securities market –There can in no practical sense be traded securities that replicate the payoff of a particular individual’s house burning down, for example; Accordingly, individuals will be willing to pay a risk premium for instruments that mitigate such risks – such as insurance

PricewaterhouseCoopers The insurance surplus To understand the impact of the different valuation perspectives of policyholders and shareholders, we introduce the notion of the insurance surplus –This is defined as the difference between the sum of the values placed by consumers upon a portfolio of insurance policies, and the market value of this portfolio It is clear that in practice there must be a positive surplus at the raw liability level – that’s where the expenses and taxes are paid from –Without a surplus, the insurance industry would not exist The existence of a positive surplus implies the existence of a range of premiums that consumers and shareholders will be happy with

PricewaterhouseCoopers The feasible range of premiums Myers and Cohn defined the “fair premium” to be the premium that makes entering into an insurance contract an NPV-zero proposition for shareholders –They claimed that setting premiums any higher than this would involve a wealth transfer from policyholders to shareholders –This is not the case – both shareholders and policyholders can (and must) have their expected utility improved through entering into an insurance contract (a win-win situation) We introduce the notion of the feasible range of insurance premiums –This range is defined as the set of premiums that make entering into the insurance contract NPV-positive for both shareholders and policyholders

PricewaterhouseCoopers Position in the feasible range is determined by competition In a “typical” or “realistic” un-regulated insurance market, we would expect premiums to be set in the interior of the feasible range, as there are barriers to entry, such as licensing, capital requirements, systems and skills, and the scale necessary to achieve diversification If a regulator has aims other than price minimisation (e.g. stability, accessibility), prices above the lower end will need to be allowed Low Premium High Premium NPV S = 0 NPV P > 0 NPV S > 0 NPV P = 0 NPV S > 0 NPV P > 0 Perfect Competition MonopolyTypical Market ?

PricewaterhouseCoopers Insurance surplus, mathematically... Consumer k faces a set of payoffs X k, employs a discount factor m k All consumers can trade a set of assets X (the securities market) –there exists a market discount factor m –each m k agrees with m on X –m k may be decomposed as m k = m + m k  Consumer k’s insurance policy has a payoff w k Insurance surplus is:  =  k E(m k w k ) – E(m  k w k ) Can show that  =  k cov(m k, w k  ) (if R f traded) So insurance surplus will be positive if: –The securities market is incomplete (w k  != 0), and –Consumers are averse to the non-traded part of their insured risk (cov(m k, w k  ) > 0)

 Implications for a corporate insurance firm

PricewaterhouseCoopers A simple limited-liability insurance firm Cash InCash Out Shareholders’ FundsQExpensesX0X0 PremiumPInvestmentsA0A0 Cash InCash Out InvestmentsA T = (P + Q - X 0 ) * R f Claims paidL T = min(C T, A T ) TaxesG T = … Equity cash flowA T – L T – G T Time 0 Time T The firm will take on a portfolio of policies to be resolved at time T –The underlying uncertainty is the total amount claimed, denoted C T –We’ll assume an insurance surplus would exist if claims were guaranteed to be paid

PricewaterhouseCoopers Market value of the claim portfolio (unlimited liability) Discount factor (m) indicates how much weight the market places on each loss outcome Payout distribution (  ( C T )) describes what we could lose Value = C 0 = E(m C T ) =  m(c) c  (c) dc The discount factor shown here places greater weighting on high payouts than low payouts, which makes the liability value bigger

PricewaterhouseCoopers We can value the liabilities as derivatives on the claims The payout is capped by the level of asset backing: L T = min(C T, A T ) e.g. NPV from shareholders’ point of view (ignoring tax) is: NPV S (P, Q)=  m(c) max(0, A T (P,Q) –c)  (c) dc – Q...and then calculate the NPV’s for stakeholders, as functions of the initial funds contributed:

PricewaterhouseCoopers We can determine the impact of variation in asset backing… Both premiums and shareholders’ funds provide asset backing: Insurance surplus is larger when asset backing is higher

PricewaterhouseCoopers …and expenses and taxes Expenses eat away initial funding, and require a certain minimum feasible level of asset backing Taxes eat away profits, and force a certain maximum feasible level of asset backing

PricewaterhouseCoopers Putting it all together gives the structure of the feasible region Taxes and expenses diminish the surplus, and can wipe it out –the surplus is wiped out by tax if the firm is too strongly capitalised Policyholders require a certain strength of asset backing before they will pay for insurance

PricewaterhouseCoopers Relationship with the Myers- Cohn approach The Myers-Cohn principle yields the lowest premium in the feasible region, for each level of shareholders’ funds Myers-Cohn / CAPM calculation method only applies under assumptions of unlimited liability and normally-distributed portfolio payoff –in which case it would produce the diagonal dashed line

PricewaterhouseCoopers Next step: attempt to calibrate the model to observed prices For example, assume: Log-normal claims with Coeff. of var. 24%, expenses 17%, tax 25% “zero-beta” liability Power-law discount factor …and suppose we observe these combinations of sufficiency and premium: (99.9%, 1.48), (99.5%, 1.43), (98.0%, 1.41) Then we can infer the “minimal” aggregate discount factor that the policyholders are using

PricewaterhouseCoopers Summary We have argued that policyholders will, in aggregate, place a different value on a portfolio of insurance policies than shareholders will This value difference – the insurance surplus – gives rise to a range of premiums that policyholders and shareholders will be happy with We have examined how this surplus is affected by the structure of a corporate insurance firm –Our model has produced insights into the workings of such firms, showing endogenously, for example, that asset backing should be high, but not too high “Fair” premiums cannot be determined with reference to capital markets alone – pricing information from consumer insurance markets must be considered also The author would like to thank Tim Jenkins for many helpful discussions during the development of this paper, Tony Coleman for suggesting the area of research and providing helpful references, and Insurance Australia Group for sponsoring this research.