The Market for Health Insurance

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
21 Health Care McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2012 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
Advertisements

RESOURCE ALLOCATION & THE MARKET Demand, supply and the market Sources of failure in the market for health care The insurance system of funding health.
Managed Care 1.The Emergence of Managed Care plan 2.Development and Growth of Managed Care-Why did it take so long 3.Modeling Managed Care 4.where Managed.
Managed Care in the US: Under New Management Robert E. Hurley, Ph.D. Department of Health Administration Virginia Commonwealth University.
Teleconference 2 1.Guest speakers in May 2.Policy Brief Project The Employer and Health Insurance.
Interactions of Tax and Nontax Costs n Uncertainty u Symmetric uncertainty u Strategic uncertainty (information asymmetry) F Hidden action (moral hazard)
Health Insurance October 19, 2006 Insurance is defined as a means of protecting against risk. Risk is a state in which multiple outcomes are possible and.
Chapter 9 Managed Care and Managed Care Organizations (MCOs)
Government and Health Care Roughly 15 cents of every dollar spent in US is on health care US health care spending equaled $5841 per person in 2002 Governments.
317_L15, Feb 8, 2008, J. Schaafsma 1 Review of the Last Lecture began our discussion of why there is a demand for health insurance basic reason => people.
Chapter 9 THE ECONOMICS OF INFORMATION Copyright ©2002 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. MICROECONOMIC THEORY BASIC.
More Insurance How much insurance We started talking about insurance. Question now is “how much?” Recall that John’s expected utility involves his wealth.
Government and Health Care Roughly 15 cents of every dollar spent in US is on health care US health care spending equaled $5841 per person in 2002 Governments.
Wrapping UP Insurance Let’s Review Moral Hazard With health insurance, the amount of expenditures may depend on whether you have insurance. Suppose that.
The Demand for Health Insurance Why do people want health insurance? -To avoid or reduce risk -Risks of illness or injury that causes health status to.
1 INS301 Chp16 Employee Benefits: Overview and Group Medical Coverage Overview of employ benefits Group medical insurance Background of health care market.
The role of insurance in health care Today: Why health care is important to study; The advantages and disadvantages of private insurance.
Fair Premiums, Insurability of Risk and Contractual Provisions
The role of insurance in health care, part 1
How insurance affects the demand for medical care
Health Care; Information Today: More topics to help you think like an economist.
Chapter 6: Health Insurance Chapter 6 Health Insurance Copyright © 2009 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
Entrepreneurship and Public Policy Lecture 8: The Implications of the U.S. Health Insurance System for Entrepreneurship.
The Private Health Insurance Market. Insurance Design Insurance is designed to spread risk Individuals can self-insure and face chance of paying for costs.
Managed Care. Overview Health Insurance tends to lead to an overconsumption of healthcare by the insured because the insured person only considers out-of-pocket.
Trends In Health Care Industry KNH 413. Difficult questions What is health insurance? What is health care versus health insurance? Is one or both a right.
1 Managed Health Care Pricing for Provider Arrangements Presented by Vanessa Olson Seminar on Health and Managed Care October 18, 1999.
Government and Health Care
THE HEALTH CARE MARKET Chapter 9.
T6.1 H&N, Ch. 6 Chapter Outline 6.1Insurance Costs and Fair Premiums 6.2Expected Claim Costs Homogeneous buyers Heterogeneous buyers Competition, Risk.
1 Fourth: Health Care Plans: 1. 2 The Economics of Health Care: Price rationing occurs because buyers base purchasing decisions on the relative quality.
Employee Benefits & ERISA Health Insurance August 20, 2011 R. B. Drennan, Ph.D. Associate Professor and Chairman Department of Risk, Insurance and Healthcare.
Chapter 6: The Demand for Medical Insurance Health Economics
Ch. 8: COMPENSATING WAGE DIFFERENTIALS AND LABOR MARKETS
Asymmetric Information
Health Insurance. Objectives for today Explain the origins of insurance Differentiate among types of insurance Explain reimbursement mechanisms Explain.
1 Chapter 10 – Social Insurance II: Health Care Public Finance McGraw-Hill/Irwin © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., All Rights Reserved.
Chapter 8 Insurance Pricing.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. 7-1 Defining Competitiveness Chapter 7.
Agribusiness Library LESSON: HEALTH INSURANCE. Objectives 1. Determine the function of health insurance, and define common health insurance terms. 2.
Employee Choice of a Consumer Driven Health Plan in a Multi-Plan, Multi-Product Setting Stephen T. Parente, Roger Feldman, Jon B. Christianson University.
A Theory of Prepayment, Managed Care, Deductibles and Copayments Allen C. Goodman, Wayne State U. Maia Platt, U. of Detroit – Mercy Seminar University.
Insurance. Health Insurance  Many people in the US are uninsured – assume all responsibility for health care costs.  Insurance decreases out of pocket.
1 Chapter 9 Government and Health Care. 2 Government Health Care Spending Government spending represents 45% of the $1.3 trillion spent on Health Care.
The Health Insurance Industry A health insurer pays all or a portion of medical bills in return for a fixed premium Consumers are willing to pay premiums.
1 The Games Economists Play: Interactive Public Policy Capital Campus Texas July 9, 2008 copies of this presentation can be found at
Copyright © 2002 by Thomson Learning, Inc. Chapter 9 Government and Health Care Copyright © 2002 Thomson Learning, Inc. Thomson Learning™ is a trademark.
QR 24 Economics Review Session 12/3/2009. Agenda Demand curves Supply curves Equilibrium Market failures – Moral hazard – Adverse selection Net Present.
Health Care Financing: Insurance Health Economic Course Series: 3 of 12
What is ‘Managed Care’? A ‘type’ of health insurance –combines both the financing of care (insurance) with the provision of care –variations in MC plans.
Ch. 8: COMPENSATING WAGE DIFFERENTIALS AND LABOR MARKETS A compensating wage differential –an increment in wages required to attract workers into.
Chapter 7 Physicians as Providers of Health Care.
More on managed care. Demand for MCOs Patients and/or employers may wish lower cost alternative. BUT, they might not like to have their options limited.
Employer-Sponsored Insurance The Search for “Value”
McGraw-Hill/Irwin © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. 7-1 Defining Competitiveness Chapter 7.
Chapter 22 Health Care Copyright © 2015 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written consent of.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2004 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Chapter 2 Objective and Risk Management.
Private Health Insurance
Adverse Selection. What Is Adverse Selection Adverse selection in health insurance exists when you know more about your likely use of health services.
HEALTH INSURANCE PLANS. BACKGROUND INFO Cost is a major concern Health care is over 15% of gross national product Without insurance, the cost of an illness.
Premium Sensitivity Among Workers Chapter What Is the Relevant Premium? The “risk premium”? The “risk premium”? The “loading fee”? The “loading.
Why are those who most need health insurance least able to buy it? Juniper Moore, RN Management of Health Care Resources NUR 5304.
Chapter 3 An Overview of the Healthcare Financing System Copyright 2015 Health Administration Press1.
THE UNITED STATES HEALTH CARE SYSTEM Combining Business, Health, and Delivery CHAPTER Copyright ©2012 by Pearson Education, Inc. All rights reserved. The.
Potential Effects of CDHPs on Health Spending and Outcomes Philip Ellis Congressional Budget Office September 27, 2007.
Announcements HW #1 on the website 1/12/2015. How do we finance medical care? Federal expenditures in 2013: $586B in Medicare $265B in Medicaid (+ 1/3.
24 Health Care McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Introduction to Risk Management
Chapter 22 This chapter addresses the rising cost of health care in the United States. We will discuss both the economic and noneconomic costs associated.
Chapter 22 This chapter addresses the rising cost of health care in the United States. We will discuss both the economic and noneconomic costs associated.
Presentation transcript:

The Market for Health Insurance Is the insurance market stable? Buyers hold the information advantage: -Likely to know more than insurers about their health status and habits -Insurers worry that if they offer a particular plan at a particular price, enrollees might be an adverse selection of risk types in the population

Uncontrolled Adverse Selection - If insurer underestimates risk, claims experience will be worse than anticipated - Premiums rise in the next period - Even more good risks drop out - Adverse selection “death spiral” possible: only the high risk people remain insured (at a premium consistent with their high expected costs)

Adverse Selection Example All consumers have the same U(I) and incomes of $25,000 - Half are low risk (25% probability of $20,000 loss) and half are high risk (75% probability)  50% average risk -Insurer cannot identify risk types -No loading or moral hazard -AFP = $10,000 -Insurance guarantees income = $15,000 (utility = U*)

Example (cont.) - For Hs, U* > EUH, so they buy the policy - For Ls, U* < EUL, so they do not buy even though they’re risk averse and we’ve assumed no loading

Adverse selection in choice of plan Suppose: -1 insurance plan (full coverage & community rating) -Low risks prefer this plan to being uninsured -No moral hazard & no loading Compare the equilibrium in a competitive insurance market under full information vs. asymmetric information

Full information (insurers can identify risk types) Community-rated plan can’t be an equilibrium: -Another insurer has an incentive to charge a lower rate but only accept Ls -Ls have an incentive to enroll in this plan to avoid cross-subsidizing Hs -In equilibrium, there will be 2 types of plans: each risk type gets full coverage for a premium = their own AFP, eliminating cross subsidy from Ls to Hs -Full coverage is optimal (efficient) because of risk aversion and lack of moral hazard; EU maximized by having the insurer bear all of the financial risk

Asymmetric information (insurers can’t identify risk types) -Again, CR won’t be an equilibrium -2nd insurer will try to attract Ls. However, if they offer full coverage at Ls’ AFP, Hs will also enroll and the plan will lose money. -2nd insurer tries to design a plan preferred to the CR plan only by Ls -Lower premium plus coinsurance: Ls opt for the new plan to avoid cross-subsidizing Hs, but Hs may prefer high coverage plan even at the higher premium (coinsurance is less desirable to Hs)

Welfare Implications of Asymmetric Information Equilibrium -Compared to full information equilibrium, Hs are no worse off -Ls worse off as they bear substantial risk while full insurance would be optimal -Like FFS plan with coinsurance, managed care may provide alternative plan designs that separate the market by risk type: restrictions on access to specialists and other care management tools may be less bothersome to Ls than to Hs

Evidence of Adverse Selection Cutler and Zeckhauser (Handbook, 2000) review the evidence: -8 of 12 studies of FFS vs. Managed Care find AS into FFS (2 show AS into Managed Care) -3 of 4 studies of the decision to be insured vs. not find AS into insurance -14 of 14 studies of choice between high option and low option plans find AS

AS in Medicare managed care (Mello et al., HSR, 2003) -HMOs receive favorable selection of newcomers -Favorable selection persists over time for some, but not all, health status measures -Risk-adjusted payments to health plans are appropriate

Other ways insurers avoid adverse selection -Medical underwriting -Basing premiums on observable characteristics (age, smoking status) -Pre-existing conditions clauses -Public programs face difficult issue of risk-adjustment -Clinton plan: mandatory CR, but plans enrolling a disproportionate share of persons with high cost characteristics would receive higher payments -HMOs in Medicare and Medicaid managed care -Ability to forecast expenditures from readily available data (age, sex, etc.) is poor

Ex ante vs. ex post risk Private insurance market equilibrium has premiums that reflect each risk type’s expected loss -Not controversial for auto or life insurance -Conversely, many people would like health insurance to provide cross-subsidies from the young and healthy to the old and sickly

Ex ante vs. ex post risk (cont.) -Desire for health insurance to make transfers not only ex post, but also ex ante -Insurance markets tend towards avoiding the ex ante transfers -Even in large employer groups where the ex ante transfers are apparently made, compensating wage differentials may erase the transfer -Thus, accomplishing ex ante transfers likely requires regulation. Because health insurance is voluntary, low risks can avoid paying the cross-subsidy by dropping out or by selecting plans unattractive to high risks.

So, why do we have managed care? -Lowering OOP price causes overuse, creating a welfare loss that offsets part of the welfare gain from risk-spreading -FFS dilemma: better protection from financial risk implies more distorted post-illness incentives. Patient C-sharing, the only FFS tool to control overuse, defeats the purpose of insurance. -Managed care’s fundamental tools are: -Selective contracting/price negotiation -Steering enrollees to selected providers -Utilization review/management/monitoring -Non-traditional provider payment mechanisms (e.g., capitation, salary, holdbacks)

So, why do we have managed care? (cont.) MCOs’ tools have the potential to control overuse without placing the consumer at greater financial risk: -For most goods, the price the consumer pays is exactly what the producer receives -OOP price paid by consumers can be different than the price paid to providers -Overconsumption can be controlled using traditional D-side cost-sharing and incentives to influence provider behavior

Example: Conventional FFS Insurance Suppose objective is to provide incentives to consume m* W/o cost-sharing, mH will be demanded; imposing cost-sharing such that consumer pays p* reduces demand to m* but consumer bears substantial risk

Example: Managed care -Charge nothing out-of-pocket  demand mH -If providers are paid  pH, they supply all units demanded -Suppose MCO negotiates lower rate with providers (the important part is a lower marginal payment rate; e.g., salaried physician’s marginal payment = 0) -If price = pL, providers supply only m* and moral hazard is controlled without imposing risk on patients -Optimal payment is not “fully prospective”; if providers were paid 0, they’d undertreat

Patients and Providers: Allies or Enemies? Imposing financial (or non-financial) disincentives on providers puts patients and providers in conflict: -If patients pay 0 out-of-pocket, they’d like more care than providers are willing to deliver -We’ll consider supplier induced demand later

Fundamental economic difference between FFS insurance and managed care Conventional FFS Insurance: Patients unconstrained at point of care, but have to pay for the expected costs up-front with a higher premium Managed Care: Patients receive less care than desiree given their cost-sharing, but pay lower premium since moral hazard is reduced; may get better protection from financial risk since S-side incentives help limit care

So, which is better? Managed care may raise consumer welfare by limiting inefficient consumption without imposing additional D-side cost-sharing Risks of “overtreatment” replaced by risks of “undertreatment” “Management” isn’t free: Negotiating contracts, monitoring providers, running UR, implementing practice guidelines, etc. Some financial arrangements (e.g., capitation or holdbacks) place providers at risk; due to limited practice sizes they can’t diversify risk as effectively as insurers HIE showed that D-side cost-sharing discourages care to a greater extent in lower income groups; thus, S-side cost-sharing may be preferable on equity grounds - By changing incentives, S-side cost-sharing can affect development and diffusion of technologies: cost-reducing techs become attractive

Product differentiation in health insurance Nearly all plans now use some “management” techniques: -By 1989, 65% of conventional insurers (those that pay FFS and do not restrict choice of provider) required preadmission certification for at least some hospitalizations, 54% had UR and large minorities had second opinion or case management programs

MCOs shift the locus of “shopping” from the consumer to the health plan - Individuals have little incentive to price shop, little bargaining power and often are unable to shop around even if they would want to (e.g., heart attack) - MCOs have incentive to negotiate lower prices, and ability to steer large #s of patients to providers; some control costs by providing services directly - Success in negotiating discounts depends on competition among providers (i.e., competition in physician and hospital markets is needed to make MCOs effective competitors in the insurance market) - Before MC, providers had little reason to compete on price. With Medicare’s move to DRGs and MC’s growth, “excess capacity” developed in the hospital market and in some physician specialties, helping MCOs win discounts

Competition and managed care discounts -Melnick et al. (JHE, 1992): -Greater PPO discounts in more competitive hospital markets (more hospitals and more empty beds) -Smaller discounts when the PPO was more dependent on 1 hospital -Kaiser owns its hospitals -Allowed Kaiser to bypass the high prices of other hospitals, providing competitive advantage in the ‘70s and ‘80s when there was little price competition -Recently, Kaiser enrollment has been flat while IPAs and PPOs, which contract for services, have grown. With low hospital occupancy, these plans can negotiate substantial discounts.

Health plan choice: responsiveness to premiums - Many employees face a “menu” of plan options - Increasingly, employees are charged different co-premiums for different plans (employer contribution is a fixed dollar amount, so employees pay the marginal cost of more expensive plans) - Willingness to switch is crucial to the success of competitive strategies for controlling costs - If enrollees became “locked into” their plans, price competition between insurers would be reduced

Evidence on plan choice Short and Taylor (JHE, 1989): -$100 decrease in the HMO premium relative to traditional coverage led to 2.6 percentage point rise in HMO enrollment -$100 decrease in the price of FFS with high cost-sharing relative to a more generous traditional plan led to 5.3 percentage point rise in enrollment in high cost-sharing plan Buchmueller and Feldstein (HA, 1996): -“Natural experiment” in which the U Cal changed the way it priced health plans to employees -Employees facing small premium increases ($1-10 per month) 5 times as likely to switch than those facing constant premiums (25.2% vs. 4.8%); 42% of facing $50- 60 monthly increases switched

Evidence on plan choice (cont.) Buchmueller (HA, 1998) -Shift of enrollment to cheaper plans substantially reduced UC outlay -AS death spiral for FFS plan Wholey, Feldman and Christianson (JHE, 1995): -Increased competition in HMO market lowered group/staff/network model HMO premiums and IPA premiums -Provides some hope that competition between insurance plans will help reduce premiums -Helps explain why the large profits enjoyed by many HMOs in the mid-1990s were transient

Uninsurance and the Labor Market Measures of the uninsured vary, but 45M is a reasonable figure (15% of the US population) 63% have at least one full time worker in their household 27% have household incomes > 3 x FPL

Uninsurance and the Labor Market (cont.) One quarter of working uninsured were offered coverage but declined -Reflects low WTP for insurance; even substantial subsidies may not have much effect on take-up If workers with low demand for HI sort into firms that do not offer insurance, non-offering firms are not likely to begin offering insurance in response to a subsidy -Several studies are consistent with a weak response to employer subsidies State coverage mandates make insurance more expensive, encouraging firms and workers to drop coverage -Particularly true for small firms, because large firms often escape state mandates by self-insuring