Lecture 9: Antitrust Policy & Merger Analysis with Differentiated Products I.An Overview II.The Antitrust Framework. III.Simulation analysis in mergers.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Lecture #11: Introduction to the New Empirical Industrial Organization (NEIO) - What is the old empirical IO? The old empirical IO refers to studies that.
Advertisements

MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION, OLIGOPOLY, & GAME THEORY
Lesson 9-1 Market Structure – Market structures are a way to categorize businesses by the amount of competition they face. – Four basic market structures.
Competition and Monopolies
Michael R. Baye, Managerial Economics and Business Strategy, 3e. ©The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., 1999 Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter.
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy
Copyright © 2010 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9 Basic Oligopoly.
Monopolistic Competition
Basic Oligopoly Models
1 Unilateral Effects Federal Trade Commission and Justice Department Merger Workshop February 18, 2004 Joseph Kattan Gibson, Dunn & Crutcher LLP Washington,
CHAPTER 9 Basic Oligopoly Models Copyright © 2014 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written.
ECON 202: Principles of Microeconomics Review Session for Exam 3 Chapters
Antitrust Analysis Using Calibrated Economic Models Gregory J. Werden Senior Economic Counsel Antitrust Division U.S. Department of Justice The views expressed.
C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to Describe and identify monopolistic competition.
Simulating Mergers MSc Regulation and Competition March 2005.
© 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Economics R. Glenn Hubbard, Anthony Patrick O’Brien, 2e. Fernando & Yvonn Quijano Prepared by: Chapter 14 Monopoly.
Oligopoly chapter 19 Copyright © 2014 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written consent of.
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy
Economics: Principles in Action
1 Oligopoly. 2 By the end of this Section, you should be able to: Describe the characteristics of an oligopoly Describe the characteristics of an oligopoly.
Economics Chapter 7 Market Structures
Explorations in Economics
The Four Conditions for Perfect Competition
Case 2: Staples-Office Depot Merger
1 C H A P T E R 14 1 © 2001 Prentice Hall Business PublishingEconomics: Principles and Tools, 2/eO’Sullivan & Sheffrin Market Power and Public Policy:
Chpt 12: Perfect Competition 1. Quick Reference to Basic Market Structures Market StructureSeller Entry Barriers# of SellersBuyer Entry Barriers# Buyers.
Evaluating Monopoly Comparison with Perfect Competition.
Economics Chapter 9 Competition and Monopolies. Perfect Competition: Section 1 Market Structure- the amount of competition they face. Market Structure-
Monopolistic Competition & Oligopoly ECO 2023 Chapter 11 Fall 2007.
1 LECTURE #14: MICROECONOMICS CHAPTER 16 (Chapter 17 in 4 th Edition) Monopolistic Competition.
Chapter 7 Section 1 Perfect Competition
Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly
The Four Conditions for Perfect Competition
Microeconomics Unit III: The Theory of the Firm. The selling environment in which a firm produces and sells its product is called the market structure.
Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly Chapter 11.
Lecture 12Slide 1 Topics to be Discussed Oligopoly Price Competition Competition Versus Collusion: The Prisoners’ Dilemma.
Perfect competition, with an infinite number of firms, and monopoly, with a single firm, are polar opposites. Monopolistic competition and oligopoly.
A monopolistically competitive market is characterized by three attributes: many firms, differentiated products, and free entry. The equilibrium in a monopolistically.
© 2009 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Essentials of Economics Hubbard/O’Brien, 2e. Fernando & Yvonn Quijano Prepared by: Chapter 9 Monopoly and Antitrust.
The Last Word: Ch 9 Guided reading due Friday. Chapter 9.
Monopolistic Competition CHAPTER 16 C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to 1 Describe.
Today n Oligopoly Theory n Economic Experiment in Class.
© 2009 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Essentials of Economics Hubbard/O’Brien, 2e. Fernando & Yvonn Quijano Prepared by: Chapter 9 Monopoly and Antitrust.
Modeling the Market Process: A Review of the Basics Chapter 2 © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western.
ECON 201: Principles of Microeconomics Chapter 9 of McEachern: Monopoly What is Monopoly? A Single Seller is the Sole Supplier in a Market where the Product.
Investment Analysis Lecture 7 Industry Analysis.
Evaluating Monopoly Comparison with Perfect Competition.
Monopolistic Competition & Oligopoly. Characteristics of Monopolistic Competition A relatively large number of sellers (Small Market Share, No Collusion,
Microeconomics ECON 2302 May 2009 Marilyn Spencer, Ph.D. Professor of Economics Chapter 14.
Monopolistic competition and Oligopoly
An extension to Salop’s model Focused on variety differentiation: consumers differ on the most preferred variety Expands it to include quality differentiation:
Monopolistic Competition CHAPTER 16 C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to 1 Describe.
© 2004 West Legal Studies in Business, a Division of Thomson Learning 20.1 Chapter 20 Antitrust Law.
Perfect Competition Chapter 7. Competition How do you face it in your lives? How does it affect the economy? In Boxing, what would make competition perfect?
From Market Concentration to Market Outcome: The evolution of US antitrust agency horizontal merger guidelines Russell Pittman Antitrust Division, U.S.
Monopolistic Competition & Oligopoly. Unit Objectives Describe the characteristics of monopolistic competition and oligopoly Discover how monopolistic.
Monopolistic Competition CHAPTER 15 When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Describe.
Monopolistic Competition & Oligopoly
Microeconomics 1000 Lecture 13 Oligopoly.
16 Monopolistic Competition CHAPTER. 16 Monopolistic Competition CHAPTER.
Time Warner Rules Manhattan
Microeconomics I Perfect Competition
Today Oligopoly Theory Economic Experiment in Class.
BUS 525: Managerial Economics Basic Oligopoly Models
Bellwork What is the difference between a perfectly competitive firm, monopoly and oligopoly? Give examples of each.
Economics: Principles in Action
Perfect Competition What conditions must exist for perfect competition? What are barriers to entry and how do they affect the marketplace? What are prices.
Econ 100 Lecture 4.2 Perfect Competition.
Perfect Competition Econ 100 Lecture 5.4 Perfect Competition
Perfect Competition What conditions must exist for perfect competition? What are barriers to entry and how do they affect the marketplace? What are prices.
Presentation transcript:

Lecture 9: Antitrust Policy & Merger Analysis with Differentiated Products I.An Overview II.The Antitrust Framework. III.Simulation analysis in mergers involving differentiated products I. An Overview In 1998, completed mergers and acquisitions totaled $1.273 trillion, a new record. This amount was 50% above 1997 levels. Indeed, the merger wave of the 1980s peaked with completed mergers and acquisitions equivalent to 10% of GDP, before falling to 3% in Since then, the merger/GDP ratio has risen steadily each year, reaching 22% of GDP in Hence mergers are a significant part of economic activity.

The analysis of mergers using non-cooperative game theory seems very compelling. Yet up until the early 1980s, the dominant approach was based on the merger’s likely effect on collusion in the market. Now, the Antitrust division typically focuses on unilateral effects rather than the potential collusion effects. Early work using game theory treated firms as Cournot competitors, and a merger between two firms was equivalent to one of the firms exiting the market. This approach has been criticized in recent years. New merger analysis assumes differentiated products and models the firms as independently setting the prices of each of their brands. The typical assumption is that the merging firms continue to sell all products.

II. Mergers: The Antitrust Framework Mergers fall under section 7 of the Clayton Act and the general criterion for illegality is whether the effect of the merger would be to substantially lessen competition. For at least 50 years, the U.S. Courts have favored a structural test to see whether such an outcome was likely, i.e., a test based on concentration and market shares. By the 1960s mergers involving firms with small market shares were routinely being blocked by the courts. Because of inconsistent (and overly interventionist) decisions, the U.S. Dept. of Justice tried to codify the practice of merger enforcement with the issuance of a series of merger guidelines beginning in The first part of the guidelines involved concentration and safe harbors, based on measures of market concentration.

For example, the 1982 guidelines created safe harbors for mergers in markets with postmerger HHIs below 1000 and for mergers that increased the HHI by less than 50. Problem is that it was assumed that pre and post merger market shares would remain the same. The 1982 guidelines introduced a major innovation in the methodology of market definition. A market is defined “as a product or a group of products and a geographic area in which it is sold such that a hypothetical, profit-maximizing firm, not subject to price regulation, that was the only present and future seller of those products in that area would impose a small but significant and non-transitory increase in price above prevailing or likely future levels.” The purpose is to find a gap in the chain of substitute products.

The market that results from this test, is termed the relevant antitrust market and critical battles have been waged over this issue. One problem with the guidelines is that the focus was typically on a static oligopoly, that is, the guidelines did not place too much emphasis on the possible impact of technological change. Now, a requirement of the government as part of a consent order to a merger is that steps should be taken to maintain rivalry in innovation. This can be ensured via divestiture or licensing of a key proprietary technology. The 1992 revision to the Merger Guidelines added a new focus on the role of entry. The guidelines require that entry be timely, likely and sufficient enough to counteract the competitive effects of concern.

There is a growing emphasis on efficiencies. Without efficiency gains from a merger, prices will likely increase. Synergies are often critical if a merger is to increase total surplus. A 1997 revision to the guidelines states that the primary benefit of mergers to the economy is their potential to generate efficiencies. Only the efficiencies that cannot be achieved without mergers will be considered in the merger analysis.

So how does all of this work in practice? Case Study: Staples-Office Depot In September 1996, Staples and Office Depot, the two largest office superstar chains announced an agreement to merge. The FTC opposed the merger and presented one of the first cases to use modern economic and econometric analysis. This case established the use of unilateral-effects analysis (as opposed to coordinated-effects analysis). The case also confirmed that U.S. courts will primarily apply a price standard, that is, a contested merger will only be approved if the defendants can show that prices will not rise as a result of the merger. There is a minor role for efficiency gains arising from a merger.

The Case in Detail By the mid 1990s, there were only three effective competitors: Staples, Office Depot, and Office Max. Since these stores were not always in the same geographical market, larger cities consisted of monopolies, duopolies, and triopolies. (This variation was critical to enable the use of econometric analysis.) The FTC experts first established that Office Superstores (OSSs) were the relevant market. This was a key step, because OSSs only accounted for 6% of total office supply sales. Data obtained from the three firms indicated that they feared competition from the other two, but not traditional stores. By comparing prices in monopoly, duopoly, and triopoly markets, FTC economists obtained a crude measure of the likely effect of both a hypothetical monopoly and the proposed merger itself.

The FTC also constructed an econometric model of the industry, including both large and small non-OSS. The model predicted that a merger to monopoly would raise prices by 8.49%, more than needed for an antitrust market. Once the relevant market had been established, the FTC used the econometric model to predict the effect of the proposed Staples- Office Depot merger. The model predicted that the merger would increase prices by an average of 7.3% in in the two and three firm market cities where both firms were present. The FCC also used an event study of stock market prices immediately preceding and following the proposed merger announcement to show that their econometric estimates were consistent with (stock) market expectations of the possible merger.

The FCC also demonstrated that barriers to entry were very high in the OSS market. The defense claimed that efficiency gains (primarily from economies of scale) would cause prices to fall by 3.0% following a merger. (The defense also claimed that the gross price effect of a merger ignoring efficiencies was less than 1%. The FTC argued that economies of scale were nearly exhausted and that they would amount to less than 1%. The judge agreed with the FTC in almost every respect and the proposed merger was not approved.

III. The use of simulation analysis in mergers involving differentiated products Economic Analysis regarding the unilateral effects is more amenable to quantification than is economic analysis of the dangers of collusion. Ultimately, we are trying to measure the added incentive to raise price caused by the merger. Employing a combination of game-theoretic and econometric methods, we now have the capability to estimate consumer demand using industry data, and based on these demand estimates to derive specific predictions regarding post merger prices. This contrasts sharply with with the analysis of the dangers of collusion. While we can easily list the factors that facilitate collusion, there is no accepted method of quantifying the increased likelihood of collusion as a result of a merger.

In the mid 1990s, the Justice Department showed an interest in a completely new approach to conducting merger analysis. Pioneered by Froeb and Werden, the simulation methodology using discrete choice models of product differentiation removes the need for defining a relevant antitrust market. In the same way, market shares have no particular meaning. While we’ll focus on the methodology, it is important to keep the pitfalls in mind: One problem with this approach is that it may take decades before judges and antitrust lawyers become comfortable with the methodology. It remains to be seen that this approach leads to better decisions that an approach based on market definition and market shares.

Methodology Econometrically simulating the effects of differentiated product mergers involves four steps. 1.Make an assumption about the type of conduct (competition) in the industry. In most cases, Bertrand, or price competition is employed. 2.Econometrically estimate the relevant demand parameters. Here a specification needs to be chosen. (We will not do this now.) 3.Use the estimated demand parameters and information on prices and shares to get marginal cost estimates from first order conditions 4.Use demand and cost information to simulate the effect of a merger.

Estimating the Effects of a merger Suppose that two firms merge in a four firm industry where firms sell differentiated products: (Step 1: Assume Bertrand competition.) Before merger:  i =(p i – mc i ) q i, i=1,4. After merger:  12 =(p 1 – mc 1 ) q 1 + (p 2 – mc 2 ) q 2  3 =(p 3 – mc 3 ) q 3  4 =(p 4 – mc 4 ) q 4 Step 3: If we know the demand function and have information on prices and quantities, we can we can back out the marginal costs using the “before merger” industry structure. Step 4: Once we know marginal costs, we can simulate the effect of a merger, by solving for prices (and quantities) in “after merger” industry structure. Hence, we have estimated the effect of a merger.

Step 2: Estimating Demand Functions Following Berry (1994) we employ a random utility model of the form: x j vector of observable characteristics, p j is the observed price of automobile j,  and  : mean valuations of the observable characteristics, The last two terms of the above equation are error terms:  j is the average value of product j's unobserved characteristics  ij represents the distribution of consumer preferences around this mean. (  ij introduces heterogeneity and its distribution determines the substitution patterns among products.)

We’ll assume that the are i.i.d extreme value (Weibull) distribution function. This (multinomial logit) model is popular because of a closed form solution. The probabaility of choosing product j is: (2)

Demand: If we normalize the mean utility of the outside good (k=0) to be 0, and take logs of equation (2), we obtain the demand function for each product: (3) Where s 0 is the share of the outside good. Equation (3) will be estimated. This will yield estimates for  and .

Oligopoly (Bertrand) price competition Let p j =price of product j, q j =quantity of product i, The profits of a single product firm are:  j =(p j - mc j ) q j FOC for profit maximization imply: q j +(p j - mc j )  q j /  p j =0. For the logit model, the FOCs are: p j = mc j – 1/  (1-s j )  p j =0 (4) Given p j,s j, and , marginal costs can be estimated from (4).