Utility.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Preferences. Rationality in Economics u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker always chooses its most preferred alternative from its set of available.
Advertisements

Chapter Four Utility. Preferences - A Reminder u x y: x is preferred strictly to y.  x  y: x and y are equally preferred. u x y: x is preferred at least.
Chapter 4 Utility Functions. Utility Ordinal Utility: The only property of a utility assignment is “how it orders the bundles of goods.” The size of the.
Chapter 3. * Prerequisite: A binary relation R on X is said to be Complete if xRy or yRx for any pair of x and y in X; Reflexive if xRx for any x in X;
Tastes/Preferences Indifference Curves.
Combinations (X1, Y1) and (X2, Y2) provide the same level of utility
Chapter Four Consumer Choice.
PREFERENCES AND UTILITY
Axioms of Rational Choice
Chapter Four Utility. Utility Functions   A utility function U(x) represents a preference relation if and only if: x’ x” U(x’) > U(x”) x’ x” U(x’)
Chapter Three Preferences.
Axioms of Rational Choice
Utility Functions A utility function U(x) represents a preference relation if and only if: x’ x” U(x’) > U(x”) x’ x” U(x’) < U(x”) x’  x” U(x’) = U(x”).
Chapter Three Preferences. Rationality in Economics u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker always chooses its most preferred alternative from its set.
Chapter Four Utility. Utility Functions u A preference relation that is complete, reflexive, transitive and continuous can be represented by a continuous.
Utility.
Chapter Three Preferences. Rationality in Economics u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker always chooses its most preferred alternative from its set.
Preferences. Preference Relation The consumer strictly prefers bundle X to bundle Y: The consumer is indifferent between X and Y:
Chapter Four Utility.
1 Chapter 3 PREFERENCES AND UTILITY Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
Utility. Utility Functions u Utility is a concept used by economists to describe consumer preferences. u Utility function is a function that assigns a.
Course: Microeconomics Text: Varian’s Intermediate Microeconomics 1.
Chapter Three Preferences. Rationality in Economics u Behavioral Postulate: An economic decisionmaker always chooses her most preferred alternative from.
The Indifference Curve Analysis is an alternative explanation of the consumer’s behaviour. It is an alternative in two respects : Different assumptions.
Chapter 5 Choice.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 4 Utility. © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 2 Preferences - A Reminder u x y: x is preferred strictly to y.  x.
Consumer behaviour: Ordinal approach Now, we go to the ordinal approach. Ordinalist cares only about ranking. It doesn’t matter if we say U(A) = 20, U(B)
Chapter 4 Utility.
Course: Microeconomics Text: Varian’s Intermediate Microeconomics 1.
Chapter 3: Consumer Preferences and the Concept of Utility
Chapter 3 Consumer Preferences.
Rational Choice. CHOICE 1. Scarcity (income constraint) 2. Tastes (indifference map/utility function)
Consumer Preferences and the Concept of Utility
1 Chapter 3 PREFERENCES AND UTILITY Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
Chapter 3 Preferences.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 3 Preferences.
1 Preferences Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 – Spring 2009.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 4 Utility. © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 2 Preferences - A Reminder u x y: x is preferred strictly to y.  x.
Chapter Three Preferences. u Consumer behavior is best understood in three distinct steps: 1. Consumer Preferences: The first step is to find a practical.
CDAE Class 4 Sept. 6 Last class: 1.Introduction 2.Preferences and choice Class exercise 1 Today: 2. Preferences and choice Next class: 2.Preferences.
Consumer Choice Preferences, Budgets, and Optimization.
L03 Utility. Big picture u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from the set of affordable alternatives. u Budget.
Chapter 4 UTILITY.
Chapter Four Utility 效用.
Budgetary and Other Constraints on Choice
L04 Choice. Big picture u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from the set of affordable alternatives. u Budget.
L02 Preferences. Rationality in Economics u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from the set of affordable alternatives.
L03 Utility. Quiz How much do you like microeconomics A: I love it (unconditionally) B: I cannot live without it C: I would die for it D: All of the above.
Chapter 4 Utility Utility: conceptually an indicator of a person’s overall well-being How do we quantify? Can we do interpersonal comparisons? What does.
 This will explain how consumers allocate their income over many goods.  This looks at individual’s decision making when faced with limited income and.
UTILITY. Chapter 11 What is Utility? A way of representing preferences Utility is not money (but it is a useful analogy) Typical relationship between.
Preferences and Utility
Chapter 3 Preferences Intermediate Microeconomics:
4 Utility.
L03 Utility.
L03 Utility.
3 Preferences.
Chapter 4 Utility Key Concept: Utility, an indicator of a person’s overall well-being We only use its ordinal property in most cases. Marginal utility.
Chapter Three Preferences.
Preferences and Utility
Chapter Four Utility.
L03 Utility.
L03 Utility.
L02 Preferences.
Chapter 3 Preferences.
L03 Utility.
Utility Functions f ~ p p
Subject:Economics Class:1st Semester
Presentation transcript:

Utility

UTILITY FUNCTIONS A preference relation that is complete, reflexive, transitive and continuous can be represented by a continuous utility function (as an alternative, or as a complement, to the indifference “map” of the previous lecture). Continuity means that small changes to a consumption bundle cause only small changes to the preference (utility) level.

UTILITY FUNCTIONS f ~ p p A utility function U(x) represents a preference relation if and only if: x0 x1 U(x0) > U(x1) x0 x1 U(x0) < U(x1) x0 ~ x1 U(x0) = U(x1) ~ f p p

UTILITY FUNCTIONS Utility is an ordinal (i.e. ordering or ranking) concept. For example, if U(x) = 6 and U(y) = 2 then bundle x is strictly preferred to bundle y. However, x is not necessarily “three times better” than y.

UTILITY FUNCTIONS and INDIFFERENCE CURVES Consider the bundles (4,1), (2,3) and (2,2). Suppose (2,3) > (4,1) ~ (2,2). Assign to these bundles any numbers that preserve the preference ordering; e.g. U(2,3) = 6 > U(4,1) = U(2,2) = 4. Call these numbers utility levels.

UTILITY FUNCTIONS and INDIFFERENCE CURVES An indifference curve contains equally preferred bundles. Equal preference  same utility level. Therefore, all bundles on an indifference curve have the same utility level.

UTILITY FUNCTIONS and INDIFFERENCE CURVES So the bundles (4,1) and (2,2) are on the indifference curve with utility level U º 4 But the bundle (2,3) is on the indifference curve with utility level U º 6

UTILITY FUNCTIONS and INDIFFERENCE CURVES x2 (2,3) > (2,2) = (4,1) x2 U º 6 U º 4 x1 xx11

UTILITY FUNCTIONS and INDIFFERENCE CURVES Comparing more bundles will create a larger collection of all indifference curves and a better description of the consumer’s preferences.

UTILITY FUNCTIONS and INDIFFERENCE CURVES x2x2 U º 6 U º 4 U º 2 xx1 1

UTILITY FUNCTIONS and INDIFFERENCE CURVES Comparing all possible consumption bundles gives the complete collection of the consumer’s indifference curves, each with its assigned utility level. This complete collection of indifference curves completely represents the consumer’s preferences.

UTILITY FUNCTIONS and INDIFFERENCE CURVES The collection of all indifference curves for a given preference relation is an indifference map. An indifference map is equivalent to a utility function; each is the other.

UTILITY FUNCTIONS If (i) U is a utility function that represents a preference relation; and (ii) f is a strictly increasing function, then V = f(U) is also a utility function representing the original preference function. Example? V = 2.U

GOODS, BADS and NEUTRALS A good is a commodity unit which increases utility (gives a more preferred bundle). A bad is a commodity unit which decreases utility (gives a less preferred bundle). A neutral is a commodity unit which does not change utility (gives an equally preferred bundle).

GOODS, BADS and NEUTRALS Utility Utility function Units of water are goods Units of water are bads Water x’ Around x’ units, a little extra water is a neutral.

UTILITY FUNCTIONS Cobb-Douglas Utility Function Perfect Substitutes Utility Function Note: MRS = (-)a/b Perfect Substitutes: Example X1 = pints; X2 = half-pints; and U(X1, X2) = 2X1 + 1X2. U(4,0) = U(0,8) = 8. MRS = -(2/1), i.e. individual willing to give up two units of X2 (half-pints) in order to receive one more unit of X1 (pint). Perfect Complements Utility Function Note: MRS = ?

UTILITY Preferences can be represented by a utility function if the functional form has certain “nice” properties Example: Consider U(x1,x2)= x1.x2 u/x1>0 and u/x2>0 Along a particular indifference curve x1.x2 = constant  x2=c/x1 As x1   x2 i.e. downward sloping indifference curve

UTILITY Example U(x1,x2)= x1.x2 =16 X1 X2 MRS 1 16 2 8 (-) 8 1 16 2 8 (-) 8 3 5.3 (-) 2.7 4 4 (-) 1.3 5 3.2 (-) 0.8 3. As X1  MRS  (in absolute terms), i.e convex preferences

COBB DOUGLAS UTILITY FUNCTION Any utility function of the form U(x1,x2) = x1a x2b with a > 0 and b > 0 is called a Cobb-Douglas utility function. Examples U(x1,x2) = x11/2 x21/2 (a = b = 1/2) V(x1,x2) = x1 x23 (a = 1, b = 3)

COBB DOUBLAS INDIFFERENCE CURVES x2 All curves are “hyperbolic”, asymptoting to, but never touching any axis. x1

PERFECT SUBSITITUTES Instead of U(x1,x2) = x1x2 consider V(x1,x2) = x1 + x2.

PERFECT SUBSITITUTES x2 x1 + x2 = 5 x1 + x2 = 9 x1 + x2 = 13 V(x1,x2) = x1 + x2 5 9 13 x1 All are linear and parallel.

PERFECT COMPLEMENTS Instead of U(x1,x2) = x1x2 or V(x1,x2) = x1 + x2, consider W(x1,x2) = min{x1,x2}.

PERFECT COMPLEMENTS x2 45o W(x1,x2) = min{x1,x2} 8 min{x1,x2} = 8 5 3 min{x1,x2} = 3 3 5 8 x1 All are right-angled with vertices/corners on a ray from the origin.

MARGINAL UTILITY Marginal means “incremental”. The marginal utility of product i is the rate-of-change of total utility as the quantity of product i consumed changes by one unit; i.e.

 x2/x1 {= MRS} = (-)MU1/MU2 MARGINAL UTILITY U=(x1,x2) MU1=U/x1  U=MU1.x1 MU2=U/x2  U=MU2.x2 Along a particular indifference curve U = 0 = MU1(x1) + MU2(x2)  x2/x1 {= MRS} = (-)MU1/MU2

MARGINAL UTILITY E.g. if U(x1,x2) = x11/2 x22 then

MARGINAL UTILITY E.g. if U(x1,x2) = x11/2 x22 then

MARGINAL UTILITY E.g. if U(x1,x2) = x11/2 x22 then

MARGINAL UTILITY E.g. if U(x1,x2) = x11/2 x22 then

MARGINAL UTILITY So, if U(x1,x2) = x11/2 x22 then

MARGINAL UTLITIES AND MARGINAL RATE OF SUBISITUTION The general equation for an indifference curve is U(x1,x2) º k, a constant Totally differentiating this identity gives

MARGINAL UTLITIES AND MARGINAL RATE OF SUBISITUTION rearranging

MARGINAL UTLITIES AND MARGINAL RATE OF SUBISITUTION rearranging This is the MRS.

MU’s and MRS: An example Suppose U(x1,x2) = x1x2. Then so

MU’s and MRS: An example U(x1,x2) = x1x2; x2 8 MRS(1,8) = - 8/1 = -8 MRS(6,6) = - 6/6 = -1. 6 U = 36 U = 8 x1 1 6

MONOTONIC TRANSFORMATIONS AND MRS Applying a monotonic transformation to a utility function representing a preference relation simply creates another utility function representing the same preference relation. What happens to marginal rates-of-substitution when a monotonic transformation is applied? (Hopefully, nothing)

MONOTONIC TRANSFORMATIONS AND MRS For U(x1,x2) = x1x2 the MRS = (-) x2/x1 Create V = U2; i.e. V(x1,x2) = x12x22 What is the MRS for V? which is the same as the MRS for U.

MONOTONIC TRANSFORMATIONS AND MRS More generally, if V = f(U) where f is a strictly increasing function, then So MRS is unchanged by a positive monotonic transformation.