Product Variety and Quality under monopoly

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
AAEC 3315 Agricultural Price Theory
Advertisements

Perfect Competition 12.
Chapter Twenty-Five Monopoly Behavior. How Should a Monopoly Price? u So far a monopoly has been thought of as a firm which has to sell its product at.
Static Games and Cournot Competition
Chapter 5: Price Discrimination: Linear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Linear Pricing.
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy
1 Industrial Organization Product Differentiation Univ. Prof. dr. Maarten Janssen University of Vienna Summer semester Week 12.
Monopoly Outline: Outline: Characteristics of a monopoly Characteristics of a monopoly Why monopolies arise? Why monopolies arise? Production and pricing.
Chapter 9 Monopoly, Oligopoly, and Monopolistic Competition
Static Games and Cournot Competition
15 Monopoly.
Introduction A monopoly is a firm that is the sole seller of a product without close substitutes. In this chapter, we study monopoly and contrast it with.
12 MONOPOLY CHAPTER.
The Production Decision of a Monopoly Firm Alternative market structures: perfect competition monopolistic competition oligopoly monopoly.
12 MONOPOLY CHAPTER.
Chapter 5 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Linear Pricing.
1 Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly. 2 Introduction Most firms sell more than one product Products are differentiated in different ways –horizontally.
Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers. Introduction In a wide variety of markets firms compete sequentially –one firm makes a move new product advertising.
Imperfect Competition and Market Power: Core Concepts Defining Industry Boundaries Barriers to Entry Price: The Fourth Decision Variable Price and Output.
Third degree price discrimination Welfare Analysis.
Introduction to Monopoly. The Monopolist’s Demand Curve and Marginal Revenue Recall: Optimal output rule: a profit-maximizing firm produces the quantity.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2013 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
Economic Applications of Functions and Derivatives
Chapter 10: Price Competition
Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly. Introduction Most firms sell more than one product Products are differentiated in different ways –horizontally.
Five Sources Of Monopoly
Monopoly CHAPTER 15.
Copyright © 2004 South-Western Monopoly vs. Competition While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker. A firm is considered.
Econ Examples Plus Multimedia Welcome to this multimedia example. To navigate through this example you will need to click the appropriate green arrows.
Today Begin Monopoly. Monopoly Chapter 22 Perfect Competition = Many firms Oligopoly = A few firms Four Basic Models Monopoly = One firm Monopolistic.
1 Microeconomics, 2 nd Edition David Besanko and Ronald Braeutigam Chapter 12: Pricing to Capture Surplus Value Prepared by Katharine Rockett © 2006 John.
1 Monopoly and Antitrust Policy Chapter IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND MARKET POWER imperfectly competitive industry An industry in which single firms.
MONOPOLY Why do monopolies arise? Why is MR < P for a monopolist?
Perfect Competition Chapter 7
Econ 1711 Monopoly: No discrimination. Econ 1712 Marginal Revenue The only firm in the market –market demand is the firm’s demand –output decisions affect.
Monopoly Chapter 15.
Principles of Economics Ohio Wesleyan University Goran Skosples Monopoly 10. Monopoly.
Chapter 9: Static Games and Cournot Competition 1 Static Games and Cournot Competition.
Copyright © 2006 Pearson Education Canada Monopoly 13 CHAPTER.
PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University Monopoly 1 © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied,
7 Perfect Competition CHAPTER
© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley Chapter EightCopyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall. 1 Chapter 8-A Pricing and Output Decisions:
Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 1 Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly.
Monopoly CHAPTER 12. After studying this chapter you will be able to Explain how monopoly arises and distinguish between single-price monopoly and price-discriminating.
Chapter 7: Pure Competition. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright  2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. What is a Pure Competition? Pure.
Chapter 7: Pure Competition Copyright © 2007 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
Chapter 7: Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly 1 Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly.
1. THE NATURE OF MONOPOLY Learning Objectives 1.Define monopoly and the relationship between price setting and monopoly power. 2.List and explain the.
MONOPOLY 12 CHAPTER. Objectives After studying this chapter, you will able to  Explain how monopoly arises and distinguish between single-price monopoly.
Lecture 8 Product differentiation. Standard models thus far assume that every firm is producing a homogenous good; that is, the product sold by In the.
1 Chapter 10 Price Competition 2 In a wide variety of markets firms compete in prices –Internet access –Restaurants –Consultants –Financial services.
Product and Pricing Strategies for the Multiproduct Monopolist
Industrial Organization: Chapter 31 Chapter 3 Basic Monopoly Pricing and Product Strategies.
Competitors and Competition
Chapter 11 Monopoly.
Perfect Competition CHAPTER 11. What Is Perfect Competition? Perfect competition is an industry in which  Many firms sell identical products to many.
© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. What Is Perfect Competition? Perfect competition is an industry in which  Many firms sell identical products to many.
© 2010 Pearson Education Canada Monopoly ECON103 Microeconomics Cheryl Fu.
Monopoly Chapter 7 Copyright © 2011 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
Chapter Monopoly 15. In economic terms, why are monopolies bad? Explain. 2.
Chapter 25 Monopoly Behavior. How Should a Monopoly Price? So far a monopoly has been thought of as a firm which has to sell its product at the same price.
1 Product Variety under Monopoly. 2 Introduction Most firms sell more than one product Products are differentiated in different ways  horizontally goods.
Monopoly CCE ECO 211 REMEDIAL. Section3.1 MONOPOLY A monopoly is a type of an imperfect market. It is a market structure in which a single seller is the.
12 PERFECT COMPETITION. © 2012 Pearson Education.
Five Sources Of Monopoly
Product Variety and Quality under Monopoly
ECON4100 Industrial Organization
Lecture 6 Additional topics on monopoly
Lecture 10 The Bertrand Model
Presentation transcript:

Product Variety and Quality under monopoly Chapter 7 Product Variety and Quality under monopoly

Introduction Most firms sell more than one product Products are differentiated in different ways horizontally goods of similar quality targeted at consumers of different types how is variety determined? is there too much variety vertically consumers agree on quality differ on willingness to pay for quality how is quality of goods being offered determined?

Horizontal product differentiation 2, Suppose that consumers differ in their tastes firm has to decide how best to serve different types of consumer offer products with different characteristics but similar qualities This is horizontal product differentiation firm designs products that appeal to different types of consumer products are of (roughly) similar quality Questions: how many products? of what type? how do we model this problem?

A spatial approach to product variety The spatial model (Hotelling) is useful to consider pricing design variety Has a much richer application as a model of product differentiation “location” can be thought of in space (geography) time (departure times of planes, buses, trains) product characteristics (design and variety) consumers prefer products that are “close” to their preferred types in space, or time or characteristics

A Spatial Approach to Product Variety (cont.) Assume N consumers living equally spaced along Main Street – 1 mile long. Monopolist must decide how best to supply these consumers Consumers buy exactly one unit provided that price plus transport costs is less than V. Consumers incur there-and-back transport costs of t per unit The monopolist operates one shop reasonable to expect that this is located at the center of Main Street

1, Suppose that the monopolist The spatial model 1, Suppose that the monopolist sets a price of p1 Price Price p1 + t.x p1 + t.x V V 2, All consumers within distance x1 to the left and right of the shop will by the product t t 3, What determines x1? p1 x = 0 x1 x1 x = 1 1/2 Shop 1 p1 + t.x1 = V, so x1 = (V – p1)/t

The spatial model Price Price 2, Then all consumers within distance x2 p1 + t.x p1 + t.x V V 2, Then all consumers within distance x2 of the shop will buy from the firm p1 p2 x = 0 x2 x1 x1 x2 x = 1 1/2 Shop 1 1, Suppose the firm reduces the price to p2?

The spatial model Suppose that all consumers are to be served at price p. The highest price is that charged to the consumers at the ends of the market Their transport costs are t/2 : since they travel ½ mile to the shop So they pay p + t/2 which must be no greater than V. So p = V – t/2. (4.3) Suppose that marginal costs are c per unit. Suppose also that a shop has set-up costs of F. Then profit is p(N, 1) = N(V – t/2 – c) – F. (4.4) Why this single shop should be located in the center of town? (page 167)

Monopoly Pricing in the Spatial Model What if there are two shops? The monopolist will coordinate prices at the two shops With identical costs and symmetric locations, these prices will be equal: p1 = p2 = p Where should they be located? What is the optimal price p*?

Location with Two Shops 1, Suppose that the entire market is to be served 7, Delivered price to consumers at the market center equals their reservation price 2, If there are two shops they will be located symmetrically a distance d from the end-points of the market 5, Now raise the price at each shop Price Price V p(d) 6, The maximum price the firm can charge is determined by the consumers at the center of the market p(d) 8, What determines p(d)? d 1/2 1 - d x = 0 x = 1 4, Start with a low price at each shop Shop 1 Shop 2 9, The shops should be moved inwards 3, Suppose that d < 1/4

Product variety (cont.) d < 1/4 We know that p(d) satisfies the following constraint: p(d) + t(1/2 - d) = V So, p(d) = V - t/2 + t.d Aggregate profit is then: p(d) = (p(d) - c)N = (V - t/2 + t.d - c)N p(d) is increasing in d. So if d < 1/4 then d should be increased.

Location with Two Shops 5, Delivered price to consumers at the end-points equals their reservation price 4, The maximum price the firm can charge is now determined by the consumers at the end-points of the market Price Price V p(d) p(d) 6, Now what determines p(d)? 3, Now raise the price at each shop 2, Start with a low price at each shop d 1/2 1 - d x = 0 x = 1 Shop 1 Shop 2 1, Now suppose that d > 1/4 7, The shops should be moved outwards

Product variety (cont.) d > 1/4 We know that p(d) satisfies the following constraint: p(d) + td = V So, p(d) = V - t.d Aggregate profit is then: p(d) = (p(d) - c)N = (V - t.d - c)N p(d) is decreasing in d. So if d > 1/4 then d should be decreased.

Location with Two Shops 1,It follows that shop 1 should be located at 1/4 and shop 2 at 3/4 2, Price at each shop is then p* = V - t/4 Price Price V V - t/4 V - t/4 3, Profit at each shop is given by the shaded area c c 1/4 1/2 3/4 x = 0 x = 1 Shop 1 Shop 2 4, Profit is now p(N, 2) = N(V - t/4 - c) – 2F (4.6)

4, Profit is now p(N, 3) = N(V - t/6 - c) – 3F Three Shops 1, What if there are three shops? 2, By the same argument they should be located at 1/6, 1/2 and 5/6 Price Price V 3, Price at each shop is now V - t/6 V - t/6 V - t/6 x = 0 1/6 1/2 5/6 x = 1 Shop 1 Shop 2 Shop 3 4, Profit is now p(N, 3) = N(V - t/6 - c) – 3F

Optimal Number of Shops A consistent pattern is emerging. Assume that there are n shops. They will be symmetrically located distance 1/n apart. How many shops should there be? We have already considered n = 2 and n = 3. When n = 2 we have p(N, 2) = V - t/4 When n = 3 we have p(N, 3) = V - t/6 It follows that p(N, n) = V - t/2n Aggregate profit is then p(N, n) = N(V - t/2n - c) – n.F

Optimal number of shops (cont.) Profit from n shops is p(N, n) = (V - t/2n - c)N - n.F and the profit from having n + 1 shops is: p*(N, n+1) = (V - t/2(n + 1)-c)N - (n + 1)F Adding the (n +1)th shop is profitable if p(N,n+1) - p(N,n) > 0 This requires tN/2n - tN/2(n + 1) > F which requires that n(n + 1) < tN/2F. (4.12)

An example Suppose that F = $50,000 , N = 5 million and t = $1 Then t.N/2F = 50 So we need n(n + 1) < 50. This gives n = 6 There should be no more than seven shops in this case: if n = 6 then adding one more shop is profitable. But if n = 7 then adding another shop is unprofitable.

Some Intuition What does the condition on n tell us? Simply, we should expect to find greater product variety when: there are many consumers. (N is large) set-up costs of increasing product variety are low. ( F is small) consumers have strong preferences over product characteristics and differ in these. ( t is large)

How Much of the Market to Supply Should the whole market be served? Suppose not. Then each shop has a local monopoly Each shop sells to consumers within distance r How is r determined? it must be that p + tr = V so r = (V – p)/t so total demand is 2N(V – p)/t profit to each shop is then p = 2N(p – c)(V – p)/t – F differentiate with respect to p and set to zero: dp/dp = 2N(V – 2p + c)/t = 0 So the optimal price at each shop is p* = (V + c)/2 If all consumers are to be served then price is p(N,n) = V – t/2n Only part of the market should be served if p(N,n) < p* This implies that V < c + t/n. (4.13)

Partial Market Supply If c + t/n > V supply only part of the market and set price p* = (V + c)/2 If c + t/n < V supply the whole market and set price p(N,n) = V – t/2n Supply only part of the market: if the consumer reservation price is low relative to marginal production costs and transport costs if there are very few outlets

Social Optimum 1, Are there too many shops or too few? What number of shops maximizes total surplus? Total surplus is consumer surplus plus profit Consumer surplus is total willingness to pay minus total revenue Profit is total revenue minus total cost Total surplus is then total willingness to pay minus total costs Total willingness to pay by consumers is N.V Total surplus is therefore N.V - Total Cost So what is Total Cost?

Social optimum (cont.) 1, Assume that there are n shops Price Price V 4, Transport cost for each shop is the area of these two triangles multiplied by consumer density 2, Consider shop i 3, Total cost is total transport cost plus set-up costs t/2n t/2n 1/2n 1/2n x = 0 x = 1 Shop i This area is t/4n2

Social optimum (cont.) Total cost with n shops is, therefore: C(N,n) = n(t/4n2)N + n.F = tN/4n + n.F Total cost with n + 1 shops is: C(N,n+1) = tN/4(n+1)+ (n+1).F Adding another shop is socially efficient if C(N,n + 1) < C(N,n) This requires that tN/4n - tN/4(n+1) > F which implies that n(n + 1) < tN/4F (4.17) If t = $1, F = $50,000, N = 5 million then this condition tells us that n(n+1) < 25 There should be five shops: with n = 4 adding another shop is efficient The monopolist operates too many shops and, more generally, provides too much product variety

Monopoly, Product Variety and Price Discrimination Suppose that the monopolist delivers the product. then it is possible to price discriminate What pricing policy to adopt? charge every consumer his reservation price V the firm pays the transport costs this is uniform delivered pricing it is discriminatory because price does not reflect costs Should every consumer be supplied? suppose that there are n shops evenly spaced on Main Street cost to the most distant consumer is c + t/2n supply this consumer so long as V (revenue) > c + t/2n (4.18) This is a weaker condition than without price discrimination. Price discrimination allows more consumers to be served.

Price Discrimination and Product Variety How many shops should the monopolist operate now? Suppose that the monopolist has n shops and is supplying the entire market. Total revenue minus production costs is N.V – N.c Total transport costs plus set-up costs is C(N, n)=tN/4n + n.F So profit is p(N,n) = N.V – N.c – C(N,n) (4.19) But then maximizing profit means minimizing C(N, n) The discriminating monopolist operates the socially optimal number of shops.

Monopoly and product quality Firms can, and do, produce goods of different qualities Quality then is an important strategic variable The choice of product quality determined by its ability to generate profit; attitude of consumers to q uality Consider a monopolist producing a single good what quality should it have? determined by consumer attitudes to quality prefer high to low quality willing to pay more for high quality but this requires that the consumer recognizes quality also some are willing to pay more than others for quality

Demand and quality We might think of individual demand as being of the form Qi = 1 if Pi < Ri(Z) and = 0 otherwise for each consumer i Each consumer buys exactly one unit so long as price is less than her reservation price the reservation price is affected by product quality Z Assume that consumers vary in their reservation prices Then aggregate demand is of the form P = P(Q, Z) An increase in product quality increases demand

Demand and quality (cont.) 6,Then an increase in product quality from Z1 to Z2 rotates the demand curve around the quantity axis as follows 1, Begin with a particular demand curve for a good of quality Z1 2, If the price is P1 and the product quality is Z1 then all consumers with reservation prices greater than P1 will buy the good Price R1(Z2) P(Q, Z2) 5, Suppose that an increase in quality increases the willingness to pay of inframarginal consumers more than that of the marginal consumer P2 R1(Z1) P1 4, These are the inframarginal consumers P(Q, Z1) 7, Quantity Q1 can now be sold for the higher price P2 Q1 Quantity 3,This is the marginal consumer

Demand and quality (cont.) 2, Then an increase in product quality from Z1 to Z2 rotates the demand curve around the price axis as follows 1,Suppose instead that an increase in quality increases the willingness to pay of marginal consumers more than that of the inframarginal consumers Price R1(Z1) 3,Once again quantity Q1 can now be sold for a higher price P2 P2 P1 P(Q, Z2) P(Q, Z1) Q1 Quantity

Demand and quality (cont.) The monopolist must choose both price (or quantity) quality Two profit-maximizing rules marginal revenue equals marginal cost on the last unit sold for a given quality marginal revenue from increased quality equals marginal cost of increased quality for a given quantity This can be illustrated with a simple example: P = Z( - Q) where Z is an index of quality

Demand and quality: an example P = Z(q - Q) Assume that marginal cost of output is zero: MC(Q) = 0 This means that quality is costly and becomes increasingly costly Cost of quality is D(Z) = aZ2 Marginal cost of quality = dD(Z)/d(Z) = 2aZ The firm’s profit is: p(Q, Z) =P.Q - D(Z) = Z(q - Q)Q - aZ2 The firm chooses Q and Z to maximize profit. Take the choice of quantity first: this is easiest. Marginal revenue = MR = Zq - 2ZQ MR = MC  Zq - 2ZQ = 0  Q* = q/2  P* = Zq/2

The example continued Total revenue = P*Q* = (Zq/2)x(q/2) = Zq2/4 So marginal revenue from increased quality is MR(Z) = q2/4 MC(Z) = 2aZ Marginal cost of quality is Equating MR(Z) = MC(Z) then gives Z* = q2/8a Does the monopolist produce too high or too low quality? Is it possible that quality is too high? Only in particular constrained circumstances.

Demand and quality (cont.) Price When quality is Z2 price is Z2q/2 Z2q P(Q, Z2) How does increased quality affect demand? MR(Z2) When quality is Z1 price is Z1q/2 Z1q P2 = Z2q/2 P1 = Z1q/2 MR(Z1) P(Q,Z1) q/2 q Quantity Q*

Demand and quality (cont.) So an increase is quality from Z1 to Z2 increases surplus by this area minus the increase in quality costs Price Z2q Social surplus at quality Z2 is this area minus quality costs An increase in quality from Z1 to Z2 increases revenue by this area Z1q Social surplus at quality Z1 is this area minus quality costs P2 = Z2q/2 P1 = Z1q/2 The increase is total surplus is greater than the increase in profit. The monopolist produces too little quality q/2 q Quantity Q*

Demand and quality: multiple products What if the firm chooses to offer more than one product? what qualities should be offered? how should they be priced? Determined by costs and consumer demand An example: (Vertical product differentiation) two types of consumer each buys exactly one unit provided that consumer surplus is nonnegative if there is a choice, buy the product offering the larger consumer surplus types of consumer distinguished by willingness to pay for quality

Vertical differentiation Indirect utility to a consumer of type i from consuming a product of quality z at price p is Vi = qi(z – zi) – p where qi measures willingness to pay for quality; zi is the lower bound on quality below which consumer type i will not buy assume q1 > q2: type 1 consumers value quality more than type 2 assume z1 > z2 = 0: type 1 consumers only buy if quality is greater than z1: never fly in coach never shop in Wal-Mart only eat in “good” restaurants type 2 consumers will buy any quality so long as consumer surplus is nonnegative

Vertical differentiation 2 Firm cannot distinguish consumer types Must implement a strategy that causes consumers to self-select persuade type 1 consumers to buy a high quality product z1 at a high price and type 2 consumers to buy a low quality product z2 at a lower price, which equals their maximum willingness to pay Firm can produce any product in the range MC = 0 for either quality type

Vertical differentiation 4 Take the equation p1 = q1z1 – (q1 – q2)z2 this is increasing in quality valuations increasing in the difference between z1 and z2 quality can be prices highly when it is valued highly firm has an incentive to differentiate the two products’ qualities to soften competition between them monopolist is competing with itself What about quality choice? prices p1 = q1z1 – (q1 – q2)z2; p2 = q2z2 check the incentive compatibility constraints suppose that there are N1 type 1 and N2 type 2 consumers

Vertical differentiation 3 Suppose that the firm offers two products with qualities z1 > z2 For type 2 consumers charge maximum willingness to pay for the low quality product: p2 = q2z2 Now consider type 1 consumers: firm faces an incentive compatibility constraint Type 1 consumers prefer the high quality to the low quality good q1(z1 – z1) – p1 > q1(z2 – z1) – p2 q1(z1 – z1) – p1 > 0 These imply that p1 < q1z1 – (q1 - q2)z2 There is an upper limit on the price that can be charged for the high quality good Type 1 consumers have nonnegative consumer surplus from the high quality good

Vertical differentiation 5 Profit is P = N1p1 + N2p2 = N1q1z1 – (N1q1 – (N1 + N2)q2)z2 This is increasing in z1 so set z1 as high as possible: z1 = For z2 the decision is more complex (N1q1 – (N1 + N2)q2) may be positive or negative

Vertical differentiation 6 Case 1: Suppose that (N1q1 – (N1 + N2)q2) is positive Then z2 should be set “low” but this is subject to a constraint Recall that p1 = q1z1 – (q1 - q2)z2 So reducing z2 increases p1 But we also require that q1(z1 – z1) – p1 > 0 Putting these together gives: The equilibrium prices are then:

Vertical differentiation 7 Offer type 1 consumers the highest possible quality and charge their full willingness to pay Offer type 2 consumers as low a quality as is consistent with incentive compatibility constraints Charge type 2 consumers their maximum willingness to pay for this quality maximum differentiation subject to incentive compatibility constraints

Vertical differentiation 8 Case 1: Now suppose that (N1q1 – (N1 + N2)q2) is negative Then z2 should be set as high as possible The firm should supply only one product, of the highest possible quality What does this require? From the inequality offer only one product if: Offer only one product: if there are not “many” type 1 consumers if the difference in willingness to pay for quality is “small” Should the firm price to sell to both types in this case? Yes!