Externalities Today: The fundamentals of externality theory.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
15 CHAPTER Externalities.
Advertisements

1 CHAPTER.
15 EXTERNALITIES CHAPTER.
1 Chapter 14 Practice Quiz Environmental Economics.
A spillover cost or benefit that accrues from the consumption or production of a good. An externality is an effect on others who did not have a choice.
EXTERNALITIES Chapter 5.
In chapter 10, we look for the answers to these questions:
10 Externalities.
1 Chapter 3 Externalities and Public Policy. 2 Externalities Externalities are costs or benefits of market transactions not reflected in prices. Negative.
Externalities and Property Rights
 Capitalism is associated with limited government, but government is necessary for three reasons:  Establish and maintain legal system to protect property.
Intermediate Microeconomic Theory
Climate Change 1. What is climate change? IPCC: A change in the state of the climate that can be identified by changes in the mean and/or the variability.
I don’t care about you F*** you! - Guns N’ Roses
EXTERNALITIES Chapter 5.
The economics of externalities
Today: Positive externalities Highway congestion Problems
15 Externalities Notes and teaching tips: 4, 24, 28, and 40.
Taxation, income distribution, and efficiency
© 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Economics R. Glenn Hubbard, Anthony Patrick O’Brien, 2e. Fernando & Yvonn Quijano Prepared by: Chapter 5 Externalities,
Today: Positive externalities Highway congestion Problems
Government and the Market. The Role of Government  Capitalism is associated with limited government, but government is necessary for three reasons: 
Today: The fundamentals of externality theory
Externalities Today: Markets without ownership usually lead to inefficient outcomes.
Principles of Microeconomics 10. Introduction to Market Failures*
Externalities © Allen C. Goodman 2009 Ideal Market Processes are desirable if … We accept the value judgment that “personal wants of individuals should.
Tragedy of the Commons; Environment; Safety Today: Three applications of market failure without government intervention.
Sample Questions ECON 2420 Exam 1.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western Pollution Problems 4.
C. Government Role – Market Failure IF A market is a perfectly competitive (in buyers and sellers)THEN The market maximizes efficiencyTHEREFORE The government.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. CHAPTER 5 Externalities.
Principles of Micro Chapter 10: Externalities by Tanya Molodtsova, Fall 2005.
Harcourt, Inc. items and derived items copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. Market Efficiency - Market Failures The “invisible hand” leads self-interested.
Copyright©2004 South-Western 10 Externalities. Copyright © 2004 South-Western EXTERNALITIES AND MARKET INEFFICIENCY An externality refers to the uncompensated.
How can we limit climate change?
1 Externalities. 2 Externalities  Externalities are a market failure (so Government intervention may be advisable).  Externalities imply that there.
Unit II: The Nature and Function of Product Markets
Chapter 2 Externalities and the Environment McGraw-Hill/Irwin
CHAPTER 5 Externalities McGraw-Hill/Irwin
1 1 BA 210 Lesson III.4 ExternalitiesOverviewOverview.
Harcourt Brace & Company Chapter 10 Externalities (Lecture by D. Boldt on 10/18/01 in Econ
Review for Exam 1 Chapters 1 Through 5. Production Possibilities Frontiers and Opportunity Costs Learning Objective 2.1 Production possibilities frontier.
Principles of Microeconomics : Ch.10 Second Canadian Edition Externalities Chapter 10 © 2002 by Nelson, a division of Thomson Canada Limited.
Chapter 10 Externalities. Objectives 1.) Learn the concepts of external costs and external benefits. 2.) Understand why the presence of externalities.
Monopoly CHAPTER 12. After studying this chapter you will be able to Explain how monopoly arises and distinguish between single-price monopoly and price-discriminating.
Chapter 14 Economic Efficiency and the Competitive Ideal ECONOMICS: Principles and Applications, 4e HALL & LIEBERMAN, © 2008 Thomson South-Western.
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 17 The Economics of Environmental Protection.
Externalities and Public Policy
CHAPTER 5 Externalities Copyright © 2010 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
Copyright©2004 South-Western Mod Externalities as Market Failures & the “Fixes”
PPA 723: Managerial Economics Lecture 18: Externalities The Maxwell School, Syracuse University Professor John Yinger.
Modeling the Market Process: A Review of the Basics Chapter 2 © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western.
Chapter Nine Applying the Competitive Model. © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 9-2 Topics  Consumer Welfare.  Producer Welfare. 
Across the country, countless people have protested, even risking arrest, against the Keystone XL Pipeline. (Credit: modification of image by “NoKXL”/Flickr.
Externalities >> chapter: 17 Krugman/Wells Economics ©2009  Worth Publishers 1 of 32.
© 2010 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license.
Externalities as Market Failures & the “Fixes”
Modeling the Market Process: A Review of the Basics Chapter 2 © 2007 Thomson Learning/South-WesternCallan and Thomas, Environmental Economics and Management,
Macroeconomics ECON 2302 May 2009 Marilyn Spencer, Ph.D. Professor of Economics Chapter 5.
Externalities: Problems and Solutions
Policy Tools: Correcting Market Failures. What are the most serious problems we face? Climate change Agricultural production Peak oil Water supply Biodiversity.
Topics Externalities. The Inefficiency of Competition with Externalities. Regulating Externalities. Market Structure and Externalities. Allocating Property.
Chapter 3 – Market Failure
©2016 by McGraw-Hill Education Limited.
Unit 6 Chapter 17 Externalities.
C h a p t e r 3 EXTERNALITIES AND GOVERNMENT POLICY
Chapter 2 Externalities and the Environment McGraw-Hill/Irwin
©2014 by McGraw-Hill Education. All Rights Reserved.
CHAPTER 5 Externalities.
CHAPTER 5 Externalities.
Presentation transcript:

Externalities Today: The fundamentals of externality theory

Externalities Markets are well functioning for most private goods  Many buyers and sellers  Little or no market power by anybody  Example: When demand shifts right for a good, new equilibrium will have higher price and quantity Some markets do not have good mechanisms to account for everything in a market  Example: Talking on a cell phone in an airplane

Externalities Externalities are effects that are not incorporated into market quantities and prices  R/G (p.71) define an externality as “an activity of one entity that affects the welfare of another entity in a way that is outside the market mechanism” When markets have externalities, they are typically not efficient  This is the topic of Chapter 5

Public good versus externality Although public goods are often looked at as goods with externalities, we study the two topics separately  Know which analysis applies when you solve a problem

Negative externalities Some examples of negative externalities  Air pollution  Water pollution Sometimes you do not even think about polluting the water: Washing a car in your driveway  Noise pollution  Highway congestion  Standing at a concert or sporting event

Positive externalities Some externalities are benefits  Planting flowers in your front lawn  Scientific research  Vaccination Prevents others from getting a disease from you  Exercise? Yes, if it leads to lower health care insurance premiums for others More on the private health care market in Chapter 9

More externalities: Benefit or cost? Christmas decorations  Enjoyment or nuisance? A fan blowing in a warm office building  Cooling breeze or blowing your important papers? Use of perfume or cologne  Nice smell or allergen?

A simple example with externalities Suppose private MC equals quantity  MPC = Q Let demand be denoted by P = 100 – Q Let marginal damage be $10 per unit

A simple example with externalities Translate equations and external cost to our graphical example marginal damage per unit of $10 P = 100 – Q MPC = Q MSC = Q + 10

A simple example: Private equilibrium Inefficient equilibrium w/o controls: Set Q = 100 – Q  Q = 50 (quantity F) MPC = Q P = 100 – Q

A simple example: Optimal equilibrium Socially optimal quantity  Q + 10 = 100 – Q  Q = 45 (quantity E) P = 100 – Q MSC = Q + 10

An algebraic example: Price Inefficient equilibrium, P = Q  P = 50 Socially optimal quantity, P = Q + 10  P = 55 marginal damage per unit of $10 P = 100 – Q MPC = Q MSC = Q + 10 Price C = 50 Price B = 55 Recall E = 45 and F = 50

The externality problem With externalities, quantity produced is typically not optimal Finding optimal quantity when marginal damage is not constant Deadweight loss of inefficient production

Next… A more general analysis of externalities External cost per unit does not have to be constant Graphical analysis of externalities  See Figure 5.1, p. 74  See Figure 5.2, p. 76

Graphical analysis of externalities This is also the deadweight loss (or excess burden) when Q 1 is produced

Pollution Pollution is one of the biggest negative externalities around Multiple steps needed to try to find optimal amount of pollution  Which pollutants actually do damage?  Are there pollutants that indirectly cause damage? Example: CFCs on the ozone layer  How do we value the damage done? Very difficult to do, due to lack of markets

Pollution and empirical studies Empirical studies have been done to try to determine the damages caused by pollution Remember from Chapter 2 that we need to use events that prevent bias

Pollution and empirical studies Chay and Greenstone (2003, 2005)  Pollution on health 1 percent reduction in total suspended particulates resulted in a 0.35 percent reduction in infant mortality rate  Pollution on housing prices Improved air quality between 1970 and 1980 in pollution-regulated cities led to property value increases of $45 billion

The externalities of smoking Increased health care costs  Affects others through increased health care insurance premiums Lower workplace productivity due to smoking  Lowers non-smoker wages also if firms cannot discriminate against smokers Increased fires  Additional fire fighting cost on society The death benefit: A positive externality Secondhand smoke

The externalities of smoking All together, the externalities due to smoking lead to a net cost on society  Empirical estimates lead to a total cost that is probably somewhere between $0.50-$1.50 per pack Estimates can vary depending on factors such as discount rate, assumptions in a model, and value of life  Current cigarette taxes in the US are about $1 per pack

Why don’t we just negotiate? Negotiation is typically costly  Remember, time is worth something Even if a resource is owned by someone, costly negotiation can prevent better outcomes from occurring

Coase theorem The Coase theorem tells us the conditions needed to guarantee that efficient outcomes can occur  People can negotiate costlessly  The right can be purchased and sold Property rights Given the above conditions, efficient solutions can be negotiated Ronald Coase

Coase theorem Notice that the Coase theorem addresses efficiency To get to efficiency, the quantity of most goods and services produced is still positive  Example: It is not efficient to get rid of all pollution If all pollution was gone, we could not live (since we exhale CO 2 )

Bargaining and the Coase Theorem See Figure 5.3, p. 80  MB exceeds MPC in this range  Production will be Q1 without negotiation  MSC exceeds MB here  With costless bargaining, consumers will pay to reduce production from Q1 to Q*

Other private responses to externalities Mergers  When negative externalities only affect other firms, two firms can merge to internalize the externalities Social convention  Social pressure to be nice can lower the amount of certain negative externalities

Public responses to externalities Four public responses  Taxes Also known as emissions fee in markets with pollution  Subsidies  Command-and-control Government dictates standards without regard to cost  Cap-and-trade policies Also known as a permit system

Taxes: See Figure 5.4, p. 83 With no externalities, taxes on goods in complete and competitive markets lead to deadweight loss  Quantity is below the optimal amount with taxes With negative externalities, taxes can improve efficiency  The optimal tax is known as the Pigouvian tax Pigouvian tax equals marginal damage at the efficient output  Increased Pigouvian taxes can also lead to lower income taxes without sacrificing overall tax revenue Double dividend hypothesis (More in Chapter 15)

Emissions fee One way to implement Pigouvian taxes is to charge a tax on each unit of pollution, rather than on each unit of output  This kind of tax is known as an emissions fee  See Figure 5.6, p. 85

Subsidies: See Figure 5.5, p. 84 An alternative to taxes is providing a subsidy to each firm for every unit that it abates Problems with subsidies:  Efficient outcome only with a fixed number of firms Increased profits of firms in the industry will encourage new entrants into the industry  Positive economic profits if new entry is not allowed  Revenue is needed to provide subsidies Taxing income reduces inefficiencies  Ethical issues: Who has the right to pollute?

Command-and-control pollution reduction Two firms  Each would pollute 90 units if there are no pollution controls Suppose each firm was forced to reduce pollution by 50 units  Known as uniform pollution reduction  Usually not efficient

Inefficiencies of uniform reductions Notice that MC of Homer’s last unit of abatement is higher than Bart’s $$ MC is for abatement on these graphs Total abatement costs are in red for each firm

Inefficiencies of uniform reductions Overall abatement costs can be reduced if Homer reduces abatement by 1 unit and Bart increases abatement by 1 unit $$

Command-and-control regulation Command-and-control regulations can take many forms  Uniform reductions  Percentage reductions  Technology standards Each firm must use a certain type of technology This method may work best when emissions cannot be monitored easily  Performance standards Government sets emissions goal for each polluter Firm can use any technology it wants Less expensive than technology standards

Lowering abatement costs Going from command-and-control requirements to emissions fees can lower overall abatement costs Marginal cost of abatement of the last unit is equal for each firm with an emissions fee Emissions fee example  See Figure 5.9, p. 88

Cap-and-trade policies Policy in which a permit is needed for each unit of pollution emitted Permits can be traded Policy is efficient if  Bargaining costs are negligible  Competitive permit markets exist  Number of permits matches efficient pollution level Initial allocation of permits does not affect efficiency as long as the above criteria are met Example: See Figure 5.10, p. 90

Emissions fee versus cap-and-trade Given certain conditions, we notice that an emissions fee and cap-and-trade policies lead to the same result for efficiency  $50 fee for each unit polluted (implicit fee under permits)  Bart reduces pollution by 75 units  Homer reduces pollution by 25 units

In what direction are we heading? Command-and-control policies often rely on states to enforce  States do not always comply with these measures  Fees and permits can often be controlled on the national level US policies have generally moved from command-and-control to taxes and permits  Exceptions do still apply: Emissions hot spots

In a perfect world… …we would know everything with certainty The real world is not perfect  How does this complicate our analysis?

The real world is more complicated We do not live in a world with perfect economic assumptions Complicating factors  Inflation  Cost changes  Uncertainty  Distributional effects

Inflation If emissions fees do not represent real prices, the amount of pollution will change as real price changes Cap-and-trade policies do not need inflation factored in, since quantity limits are used

Cost changes Suppose cost to abate decreases every year  Optimal amount of abatement will increase each year If a new abatement technology is just being developed, future cost changes could be small or large  Potential solution: Impose a hybrid system Permit market Offer a high tax for pollution emitted without a permit

Uncertainty Costs and benefits are typically not known with certainty  With uncertainty, too much or too little pollution can be produced (relative to the efficient outcome) Two situations analyzed, with MC curve uncertain  Inelastic MSB: See Figure 5.11, p. 92  Elastic MSB: See Figure 5.12, p. 93

Distributional effects Firms…  Lose when they pay a tax  Win when they are given permits Government can generate revenue…  If a tax is imposed  If permits are sold Double dividend hypothesis supports taxes or selling permits Political pressure may encourage permit giveaways

Distributional effects Since efficiency relates to willingness to pay, poor neighborhoods should have more pollution than rich neighborhoods Displacement concerns  Job losses from environmental regulation: Does this increase income inequity? Who bears the cost of pollution control?  Depends on who uses the good that has the pollution control Example: Cars that are 15 or more years old

Summary Externalities lead to inefficient production of many goods and services Costless negotiation can lead to efficient outcomes in the presence of externalities  Not realistic in most markets There are many ways to implement government policies to improve efficiency

Wednesday Positive externalities An application of externalities  Highway travel Problems related to externalities