Lecture on Local Government and Public Goods

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
1.4 Market failure 1.4a Positive externalities
Advertisements

4. Public Goods.
Public Goods and Tax Policy
Public Goods and Common Resources
In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
Unit VI: Market Failures
Government Goals & Policy
1 Chapter 14 Practice Quiz Environmental Economics.
Chapter 4 The Mixed Economy.
Fiscal Federalism and State and Local Government Finance
An Intro to Local Government, Public Goods and Land Markets Based on Chapters 19 and 10 in Urban Economics by Arthur O’Sullivan, 5 th edition Adapted and.
SMART Classes First Year Chapter (2) The Modern Mixed Economy
Natural Monopoly Natural Monopoly – an industry in which economies of scale are so important that only one firm can survive. In other words, it is more.
The role of government Today: Public goods; government failure; taxation.
Externalities and Property Rights
Harcourt, Inc. items and derived items copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. “The best things in life are free...” n When a good does not have a price, private.
16 CHAPTER Public Goods and Common Resources.
 Capitalism is associated with limited government, but government is necessary for three reasons:  Establish and maintain legal system to protect property.
When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Distinguish among private goods, public goods,
The U. S. Economy: Private and Public Sectors
McGraw-Hill/Irwin ©2009 The McGraw-Hill Companies, All Rights Reserved Chapter 15 The Role of Local Government.
Externalities and Public Goods
Chapter 14 Government spending and revenue
Chapter 16 The Role of Local Government McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2012 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
1 Circular Flow. 2 Technical efficiency: maximum value of output from a resource base Economic efficiency: when one person cannot be made better off without.
15 Monopoly.
Ch. 5: EFFICIENCY AND EQUITY
Monopoly While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker. A firm is considered a monopoly if it is the sole seller of.
Government and the Market. The Role of Government  Capitalism is associated with limited government, but government is necessary for three reasons: 
12 MONOPOLY CHAPTER.
Ch. 5: EFFICIENCY AND EQUITY
Lecture on Household Sorting, Local Government and Public Goods
Externalities © Allen C. Goodman 2009 Ideal Market Processes are desirable if … We accept the value judgment that “personal wants of individuals should.
A.S 3.3 Describe and illustrate resource allocation via the public sector to compensate market failure.
 Firm that is sole seller of product without close substitutes  Price Maker not a Price Taker  There are barriers to entry thru: Monopoly Resources,
State and Local Public Finance Spring 2013, Professor Yinger Lecture 11 User Fees (=Public Prices)
Market Failure.
Market Power: Monopoly
Copyright © 2004 South-Western Monopoly vs. Competition While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker. A firm is considered.
Chapter 15 notes Monopolies.
The Role of Government In a Market Economy.
Externalities and Public Goods
Copyright©2004 South-Western Monopoly. Copyright © 2004 South-Western While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker.
Chapter 5: Market Failure: A Role for Government
General Equilibrium and the Efficiency of Perfect Competition
Monopoly.
Chapter 22 Microeconomics Unit III: The Theory of the Firm.
PPA 723: Managerial Economics Lecture 17: Public Goods The Maxwell School, Syracuse University Professor John Yinger.
Professor: Keren Mertens Horn Office: Wheatley 5-78B Office Hours: TR 2:30-4:00 pm ECONOMICS OF THE METROPOLITAN AREA 212G,
1 of 35 C H A P T E R 1 0 ■ S T A T E A N D L O C A L G O V E R N M E N T E X P E N D I T U R E S Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Fourth.
Monopoly CHAPTER 12. After studying this chapter you will be able to Explain how monopoly arises and distinguish between single-price monopoly and price-discriminating.
CHAPTER 14 Government spending and revenue ©McGraw-Hill Education, 2014.
Chapter 181 Externalities and Public Goods. Chapter 182 Externalities Externalities are the effects of production and consumption activities not directly.
Economics of Crime and its Prevention How Much is too Much?
Ch. 11 General Equilibrium and the Efficiency of Perfect Competition
Ch 28. Gov’t and Market Failure. Public Goods Nonrivalry – Once a producer has produced a public good, everyone can obtain the benefit. Nonrivalry – Once.
Chapter 15: Externalities, Public Goods and Social Choice
Economics 101 – Section 5 Lecture #25 – April 22, 2004 Chapter 15 – Market Failures pp Natural monopolies Externalities Public goods.
Market Failure syllabus Candidates should be able to: Define market failure Assess different types of market failure - externalities, under-provision.
Markets, Maximizers and Efficiency
Copyright©2004 South-Western 15 Monopoly. Copyright © 2004 South-Western Monopoly While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price.
Chapter 22: The Competitive Firm Copyright © 2013 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin 13e.
Public Goods and Common Resources Chapter 17. A way to classify goods that predicts whether a good is a private good—a good that can be efficiently provided.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Chapter 5: Public Goods and Externalities Copyright © 2010 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
13 MONOPOLY. © 2012 Pearson Education A monopoly is a market:  That produces a good or service for which no close substitute exists  In which there.
Chapter 3 – Market Failure
Public goods and Externalities
The Role of Government Chapter 14
Role of the state.
Market Structures I: Monopoly
Presentation transcript:

Lecture on Local Government and Public Goods Based on Chapter 19 in Urban Economics by Arthur O’Sullivan, 5th edition Adapted and summarized by Austin Troy, University of Vermont

What is the role of government? Stabilization: monetary and fiscal policy used to control unemployment and inflation Redistribution: Taxation and transfers used to remedy inequities Resource allocation: makes production decisions either directly (e.g. through municipal utility) or indirectly (e.g. through subsidies or taxes on allocations). See Musgrave and Musgrave (1980)

Local Government Does not have the responsibility of fiscal stabilization for obvious reasons Does not have redistributive role because of mobility of citizens. Poor will immigrate and rich will emigrate to other city Both of these roles are better filled by national government Local government primarily fills third role

When does local government intervene in resource allocation? Provides goods produced under natural monopoly conditions Provides goods that generate positive externalities Provides public goods

Externalities Represent a “market failure” Where one person or firm’s consumption of a good creates benefits or costs for others Individual makes a personally efficient decision (I.e. consumes until MB=MC) but externality causes there to be a social cost or benefit that is not considered; socially inefficient Causes divergence between private and social benefits and/or costs The cost or benefit is not “internalized” by producer

Positive Externalities (e.g.education) Marginal social benefit E’=how much market would provide E*=socially optimal amount Marginal private benefit Marginal cost Subsidy amt E’ E*

Negative Externalities (e.g. pollution) P’=pollution produced in private market P*=optimal pollution amount K=amount of externality Marginal social benefit Marginal social cost K Marginal private cost Marginal private benefit P* P’

Natural Monopoly Where production of a good subject to large scale economics: that is, very big fixed costs, so those costs don’t get paid off until the scale of operation gets very large Natural monopolies have decline average costs throughout their range of production Private firms would underprovide service because high scale economies mean that average cost> marginal cost Marginal cost pricing means operates at loss City must step in and make up deficit

Natural Monopoly in Bus Service MR Demand= Marginal social Benefit P’ LRAC deficit P* LRMC Government sets this price Quantity S’ S*= optimum

Natural monopoly In absence of regulation, firm produces S’ and receives a price of P’ Problem is that firm producing at optimal point (S*) will lose money because D curve shows people not willing to pay that much But there is a social cost to not having enough bus service, so to get residents to buy the socially optimal amount, P must be lower than market price; locality subsidize this difference If set at P*, then socially optimal amount of S* is demanded. Because falls below Av Cost, government must make up the difference, equal to rectangle

Why Marginal Pricing? If profit = TR-TC, then want to produce where distance between two is maximized, which is where the slopes, or marginal values are the same P TR p TC Q

Marginal and Average Price Normally looks like this: MC gets bigger than AC P In natural monopoly the range where people are willing to pay is in the downward sloping area MC AC Normally MC=MR occurs where MC>AC but in Natural Monopoly large scale economies means one firm can set price higher and quantity lower that social optimum Q

Public Goods Provision Local governments provide goods that the market cannot provide either because they cannot price it, charge for it, or exclude

Public Good Characteristics Nonrivalrous: can be consumed by many at once, such as clean air Pure local public is were MC of additional user=0; does not decrease other’s utility Semi-rivalrous: where is non-rivalrous at small amounts or at certain times but not at others E.g. streets may be non-rivalrous at certain times of day but not others

Public Good Characteristics Nonexcludable: impossible/impractical to exclude any from consuming Examples: Defense, air waves, other examples? Hard to charge for the service Can’t tell who is willing to pay and who is not, who is benefiting and who not Some are non-excludable by choice, because alternative would be inequitable Examples fire service

Pure and Partial Public Goods A common situation is that goods are non-rival at smaller usage levels, but rivalrous at large usage levels Example: with a park, an additional household’s use does not diminish anyone’s enjoyment, until you reach carrying capacity C at which point each marginal user does impose additional costs

Local Public Goods These are public goods where the benefit is confined to a contained geographic area, like a city. Ideally, the size of jurisdictions would be determined by the level of “localness” of the public goods being provided The more extensive the benefits, the larger the jurisdiction needed to internalize those

Why provide certain public goods at the local level? Wallace Oates (1972) proposed three criteria: Diversity of Demand: “one size fits all” vs. local diversity of preferences Externalities/spillovers: are external effects locally contained or do they spill over? Scale economies: higher levels of government can leverage bigger scale economies The test for local provision of a public good is whether 1 outweighs 2 and 3

Tradeoff 1: Scale Economies v. Diversity of Demand Assume 1 public good (library service) and two municipalities in metro area High Demand in city H and low in L No externalities/spillovers between towns Scale economies: regional library can produce unit “literary services” cheaper than local library Identical services in towns

Who should make library allocation? If towns merge and form metro government, pool resources to build bigger library system, then good news is that cost/ unit service is lower, but bad news is that L is paying for more library service than they want and H is getting less library services/person than it had before. Only efficient to merge if savings due to scale economies are large relative to losses in efficiency from the uniformity of service provision

Empirical Results Moderate scale economies in things like sewer and water provision, because capital intensive Police, fire and schools, have scale economies (gains to scale) occurring until about 100,000 people, at which point fewer gains to consolidation Some areas have regional government entities that provide services with large scale economies

Tradeoff 2: Externalities vs. Demand Diversity Where service creates positive externalities that spill over into other jurisdictions, it will be underprovided, because they consider the costs but, not all the benefits Inefficiency occurs because boundaries of jurisdiction is too small to contain benefits

Example: Water pollution Town X in the Champlain Valley will underprovide stormwater management services (unless mandated) because benefits are realized by all Lake Champlain users, and they only consider local benefits

Example: Parks Provision Cities will tend to underprovide parks, because only consider benefits to local residents, when their parks could potentially be important resource for people regionally However, if a regional government takes over and DD is high, there will be too many parks for certain types of people and too few for others

Diversity of Demand and Spillovers If externalities small, S’ will be close to S*, M’ close to M*, etc. Then, municipal decisions are efficient. This is reinforced if DD is very large and S* is far from M* etc. Town M: medium parks Town L: large parks Town S: small parks MSB(l) MSB(s) MSB(m) MLB(l) MLB(s) MLB(m) S’ S* M’ M* L’ L*

Tradeoffs in level of PG provision: summary If DD is large relative to scale economies or spillovers, local is better If spillovers or scale economies are large relative to DD, then regional is better In previous slide, gaps between individual demanders are greater than gaps between MSB and MLB, so local provider is better

Examples Which category do these services fall into and why? Flood control Structural fire protection Wildfire protection Air quality University system Highway patrol

How much of a public good should a city provide? Park example: how big to make it? Assumptions: decisions made by majority rule, three-person city, no congestion, no spillover benefits Efficient amount: where MB of additional acre equals MC To get MB we add up everyone’s demand curves, which represent WTP

How big should park be? Cost/acre Marginal social benefit= MB1+MB2+MB3 Ideal amount is 70 acres MC $60 MB curves for three citizens MB1 MB2 MB3 70 acres Here WTP > MC of additional acre Here WTP < MC of additional acre

Methods for determining the amount of local public good Benefits taxation: ideal, but impractical Median voter: practical and common, but inefficient Household mobility and sorting: practical and efficient under some conditions, but not necessarily equitable. We’ll talk about this after Spring Break

Benefit taxation Tax people on their WTP for the optimum size of the good (e.g. park) ; the greater the WTP, the greater the tax This will yield optimum amount of the park, even if population is heterogeneous Impractical because must know shape of everyone’s demand curves and because there is no incentive for taxpayers with high WTP to reveal that willingness

Median Voter Approach Assuming there is no interjurisdictional mobility Often such decisions made through vote Will efficient size be chosen? No, not when charged by benefits taxation This is because the Q will be chosen where the median voter’s private MB= marginal private cost, or tax MC= $60/acre so each citizen pays $20/acre

Park provision under voting Cost/acre Marginal social benefit= MB1+MB2+MB3 Marginal social cost $60 MB1 Marginal private cost MB2 $20 MB3 10 55 70 acres 115

Median voter rule In election between 115 and 55 acres, 55 would win because person 3 and person 2 would vote for it. In election between 10 and 55, 55 would win because person 1 and person 2 would vote for it. Where spending level vs. service is being voted on the median voter’s desired outcome gets the most votes. Inefficient because everyone pays equally, but some want it more than others The magnitude of persons 1 and 2’s preferences don’t matter because median will always win

How do growth controls fit into this? Growth controls are another way for controlling the amount of public services provided by a municipality and the average cost to residents It is also a way of preventing transfers of wealth from existing residents to new.

Inflation and Services Imagine a community of 100 people and $10,000 repayment cost for municipal facilities= $100/household Now another 100 move into town; without inflation, all are equal. But with inflation, the nominal cost of the new infrastructure goes up to $20,000 for the same amount, which equals $200 per new resident. But that new burden must be shared equally, so everyone pays $150. Old residents are worse off Because new residents pay less than marginal cost, too many move to municipality and resource is congested Problem: no transparent means for charging marginal cost Old way (and Prop 13 in CA): limit reassessments on houses of long-time residents; only reassess for transfer. From Fischel chap 15

Inflation and services Strong motivation for growth controls when inflation The big question is: do the additional nominal costs of new development outweigh the benefits of increased economies of scale in service provision? Keep in mind that this only applies to fixed capital cost services, not variable cost items, like salaries of teachers Also, there are devices for recovering some additional costs from new residents, like exactions and impact fees Fischel: key goal is to eliminate fiscal incentive to exclude by state aid to moving in of new people Reduce reliance on property tax to finance local services Unintended consequence of inclusionary zoning is it gives incentive for wholesale exclusion of all development. Perhaps then inclusionary zoning is a ruse by many communities to give appearance of complying with law while being able to exclude fully. How does Act 60 fit in? From Fischel chap 15