EHM Theory and Structure Behavioural Labour Supply Modelling in DWP Alan Duncan, 6 th May 2009.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
The Economics of Childcare Alan Duncan University of Nottingham and Institute for Fiscal Studieshttp://
Advertisements

Estimating Net Child Care Price Elasticity Of Partnered Women With Preschool Children Using Discrete Structural Labour Supply-child Care Model Xiaodong.
3.3 Labour Supply Assumptions of the Model
Economics 20 - Prof. Anderson1 Multiple Regression Analysis y =  0 +  1 x 1 +  2 x  k x k + u 7. Specification and Data Problems.
Microsimulation at HM Treasury: methods and challenges David Roe and Doug Rendle ESRC/BSPS UK Microsimulation:
Chapter 6 Labour Market. Outline.  The perfectly competitive model of the labour market  Imperfect competition on the labour market  Further topics.
Spending time and money within the household Martin Browning University of Oxford Mette Gørtz AKF, Copenhagen IFS Family Workshop, September 2006.
© Institute for Fiscal Studies FORTAX: a tax and benefit microsimulation library Jonathan Shaw and Andrew Shephard PRELIMINARY RESULTS – DO NOT CITE.
ELM Part 2- Economic models Manuela Samek
Evaluating Alternative Representations of the Choice Set In Models of Labour Supply Rolf Aaberge, Ugo Colombino and Tom Wennemo Workshop on Discrete Choice.
A microeconometric model for analysing efficiency and distributional effects of tax reforms Evidence from Italy and Norway Rolf Aaberge (Research Department,
Career Progression and Formal versus on the Job Training Public Policy and life-cycle decisions C. Meghir UCL and IFS with J. Adda, C. Dustmann, J.-M.
Household Production and Life-Cycle and Labor Supply
Macroeconomics Chapter 91 Capital Utilization and Unemployment C h a p t e r 9.
9 Prepared by: Fernando Quijano and Yvonn Quijano © 2004 Prentice Hall Business PublishingPrinciples of Economics, 7/eKarl Case, Ray Fair Input Demand:
Hours Constraints and Unobserved Heterogeneity in Structural Discrete Choice Models of Labour Supply Alan Duncan CPE,
Theory of Consumer Behavior Basics of micro theory: how individuals choose what to consume when faced with limited income? Components of consumer demand.
Chapter 2 – Tools of Positive Analysis
The Theory of Aggregate Supply Chapter 4. 2 The Theory of Production Representative Agent Economy: all output is produced from labor and capital and in.
IFS Did the Working Families’ Tax Credit work? Analysing the impact of in-work support on labour supply and programme participation Mike Brewer, Alan Duncan,
Employment Decisions of European Women After Childbirth Chiara Pronzato (ISER) EPUNet Conference, May 9th 2006.
Tools of Analysis for International Trade Models
Measuring quality of life in Latin America Orazio P Attanasio (UCL & IFS)
Input Demand: The Labor and Land Markets
Economics of Gender Chapter 5 Assist.Prof.Dr.Meltem INCE YENILMEZ.
CHAPTER 10 Input Demand: The Labor and Land Markets © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair.
Modelling the labour market Labour supply decisions The effect of a minimum wage.
A2 Business Studies Objectives and Strategy –Unit 6 Decision Trees.
Centre for Market and Public Organisation Understanding the effect of public policy on fertility Mike Brewer (Institute for Fiscal Studies) Anita Ratcliffe.
Lecture # 2 Review Go over Homework Sets #1 & #2 Consumer Behavior APPLIED ECONOMICS FOR BUSINESS MANAGEMENT.
1 BBVA Foundation workshop November 2004 MADRID Aino Salomäki DG: Economic and Financial Affairs European Commission MICROSIMULATION AS A TOOL FOR.
Lecture 13: Expanding the Model with Labour Supply L11200 Introduction to Macroeconomics 2009/10 Reading: Barro Ch.8 22 February 2010.
5.1 Household Behavior and Consumer Choice We have studied the basics of markets: how demand and supply determine prices and how changes in demand and.
LABOR SUPPLY I. Consumer theory II. Labor supply by individuals III. What happens when wages change IV. Elasticity of labor supply.
Ch. 2: Economic Tools 1. Micro approach –A. Choices –B. Constraints –C. Maximization (best choice) –D. Comparative statics 2. Utility Function 3. Totals.
Welfare Reform and Lone Parents Employment in the UK Paul Gregg and Susan Harkness.
Tax-benefits indicators from a work incentives perspective Comments upon Christopher Heady and Herwig Immervoll – “Rewarding Jobs: Government Policy and.
Centre for Market and Public Organisation Using difference-in-difference methods to evaluate the effect of policy reform on fertility: The Working Families.
Supply of Labor. How do We Spend our Time? Working, playing, sleeping, eating, travelling, working out Simplify: work and leisure Time spent working is.
Entry and Regulation – Evidence from Health Care Professions Prof. Frank Verboven Presentation at DG-Competition 13 December 2006 “The Economic case for.
© 2007 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics 8e by Case and Fair Prepared by: Fernando & Yvonn Quijano 10 Chapter Input Demand: The.
1 Components of the Deterministic Portion of the Utility “Deterministic -- Observable -- Systematic” portion of the utility!  Mathematical function of.
Definitions: -Micro simulation as a means of modelling real life events by simulating the actions of the individual units that makes up the system where.
Population ageing and future tax burdens An integrated micro-macro analysis of possible taxation policy changes R Aaberge, Statistics Norway U Colombino,
Making work pay: evidence from Serbia S. Randjelović, M. Vladisavljević, S. Vujić, & J. Žarković-Rakić EUROMOD 2nd Research Workshop Bucharest, October.
Social Evaluation of Alternative Basic Income Schemes in Italy R. Aaberge (Statistics Norway, Oslo) U. Colombino (Department of Economics, Torino) S. Strøm.
Value of Time for Commercial Vehicle Operators in Minnesota by David Levinson and Brian Smalkoski University of Minnesota.
Economic Tools 1. Graphs: review basics –A. Plotting points. –B. Computing slope. 2. Micro approach –A. Choices –B. Constraints –C. Maximization (best.
Chapter 2: The Role of Economics
Designing Optimal Taxes with a Microeconometric Model of Labour Supply Evidence from Norway Rolf Aaberge, Ugo Colombino and Tom Wennemo WPEG Conference,
A model to generate lifetime incomes for a population cross-section The Lifetime INcome Distributional Analysis Model: LINDA Justin van de Ven
Results from the HMRC/HMT/ESRC Joint Research Programme on Taxation Analysis The influence of decision making costs on the effectiveness of tax incentives.
ILUTE A Tour-Based Mode Choice Model Incorporating Inter-Personal Interactions Within the Household Matthew J. Roorda Eric J. Miller UNIVERSITY OF TORONTO.
Derived demand is demand for resources (inputs) that is dependent on the demand for the outputs those resources can be used to produce. Inputs are demanded.
Assessing the Impact of Informality on Wages in Tanzania: Is There a Penalty for Women? Pablo Suárez Robles (University Paris-Est Créteil) 1.
Chapter 6. Supply of Labor to the Economy Importance of Labor Supply 1) Any country ’ s well-being in the long run heavily depends on the willingness of.
Behavioural microsimulation of employment responses to policy reforms Alan Duncan National Centre for Social and Economic Modelling (NATSEM), Institute.
February 2016 Dr. Gordon Cleveland, University of Toronto Scarborough
Carnegie Mellon University
Subject: Economics Class : 12TH HSC Board
Subject: Economics Class : 12TH HSC Board
Eco 3311 Lecture 12 One Period Closed Economy Model - Equilibrium
Wenliang Hou and Geoffrey T. Sanzenbacher
EFFICIENCY, MARKETS, AND GOVERNMENTS
The Labour Market.
the importance of behavioural Endogeneity for policy projections
Modelling with SAGE: lessons and future plans
Michal Horváth, Zuzana Siebertová Meeting of the Network of EU IFIs Workshop on Microsimulation Rome, 4th May, 2018.
Macroeconomics Chapter 9
Statement of intent Key Stage: 5 Subject: Economics
Presentation transcript:

EHM Theory and Structure Behavioural Labour Supply Modelling in DWP Alan Duncan, 6 th May 2009

2 Motivation Limitations to tax policy evaluation in the absence of behavioural responses  Static tax microsimulation models operate on the premise that individual behaviour remains fixed when simulating the effects of tax and welfare policy reform  this approach is perfectly appropriate for evaluating the ‘next day’ impact of tax or welfare policy reform, and for looking at reforms that aren’t likely to affect behaviour (..but how do we know?)  however, static methods are limited when evaluating reforms for which economic responses are likely (or indeed, intended)  this motivates an MDU project to add behaviour to the DWP Policy Simulation Model (PSM) to simulate the effects of policy reform on households’ employment choices

3 Adding Behaviour Modelling approach  empirical implementation of a structural economic model of household labour supply  uses information from static microsimulation: - for data in the estimation of the structural model - for input into the (micro)simulation of behavioural responses - find it best to use same static model for both Features of model  structural rather than reduced-form (explain rather than describe)  discrete rather than continuous (practicality, flexibility)  probabilistic (to accommodate preference heterogeneity)

4 Structural economic model – “as if...”  Characterise behaviour (in the first instance, employment choices) to be driven by an economic model of household labour supply Economic foundations l Households (more accurately, tax units) are allocated a preference function that ‘ranks’ choices over working hours & income in terms of ‘utility’ or ‘happiness’ l decisions are assumed to derive from the maximisation of this preference function subject to budget constraint that is affected by taxes and welfare payments l structure of decision-making is ‘rational’ in an economic sense (choose whichever outcome yields most ‘happiness’) l basic model can be adapted to accommodate other decisions: - welfare take-up (Moffitt & Keane, IER 1999) - childcare demand (Robins, Ribar)

the basic model l assumes that families choose the number of hours they want to work on the basis of ‘preferences’ over hours h and net income y, as an expression of ‘utility’ or ‘happiness’ U=U(y,h) l any hours choice implies a certain net income, comprising earned and unearned income, taking full account of the tax and welfare system (the ‘budget constraint’) y[h]=w.h +  h,w,  X) The decision rule: choose hours to maximise U subject to remaining on the constraint: max h U=U(y[h],h) subject to y[h]=w.h +  h,w,  X) Structural economic model – “as if...” 5

yhyh h U max budget constraint chosen h Structural economic model – “as if...” 6

l fit model parameters to the pattern of observed choices revealed in a large and representative sample of data (FRS) l estimation process acts to rationalise observed patterns of behaviour as if they derive from choosing the ‘best’ choice among the set of alternatives presumed to exist l requires a parameterisation of preferences, and for EHM we choose a quadratic direct utility: Blundell, Duncan, McCrae and Meghir, 1999 l all parameters allowed to vary with observed factors and unobserved heterogeneity l estimate using Simulated Maximum Likelihood max h U=U(y[h],h) subject to y[h]=w.h +  h,w,  X) Estimation 7

yhyh h Restricting hours choices (discrete) 8

yhyh h 9

yhyh h h * =max h U= U( h, y h | X ) Restricting hours choices (discrete) 10

l discrete approach offers practical advantages in adding behaviour (simplifying taxes in estimation/simulation, facilitating household choices, modelling take-up, adding childcare) l also allows for general forms of random heterogeneity to enter into the preference function: U(h) = U(y[h], h | X,v) +  h l for given distributions for each v and  h, this gives rise to a modelled probability Pr( h = h j | X,v) of choosing hours h j over other hours choices... l...and a probability distribution of hours responses to tax policy reform Probabilistic model 11

12 Probabilistic model Hours (reform) Hours (base) 0 Pr(0,0)Pr(0,10)Pr(0,16)Pr(0,20)Pr(0,24)Pr(0,30)Pr(0,40)Pr(0,48) 10 Pr(10,0)Pr(10,10)Pr(10,16)Pr(10,20)Pr(10,24)Pr(10,30)Pr(10,40)Pr(10,48) 16 Pr(16,0)Pr(16,10)Pr(16,16)Pr(16,20)Pr(16,24)Pr(16,30)Pr(16,40)Pr(16,48) 20 Pr(20,0)Pr(20,10)Pr(20,16)Pr(20,20)Pr(20,24)Pr(20,30)Pr(20,40)Pr(20,48) 24 Pr(24,0)Pr(24,10)Pr(24,16)Pr(24,20)Pr(24,24)Pr(24,30)Pr(24,40)Pr(24,48) 30 Pr(30,0)Pr(30,10)Pr(30,16)Pr(30,20)Pr(30,24)Pr(30,30)Pr(30,40)Pr(30,48) 40 Pr(40,0)Pr(40,10)Pr(40,16)Pr(40,20)Pr(40,24)Pr(40,30)Pr(40,40)Pr(40,48) 48 Pr(48,0)Pr(48,10)Pr(48,16)Pr(48,20)Pr(48,24)Pr(48,30)Pr(48,40)Pr(48,48)

l allows behavioural simulations to be compared with static benchmark l process guarantees that, wherever possible, model predictions line up with observed choices under the base (benchmark) policy regime l requires unobserved heterogeneity terms to be drawn from a conditionaI distribution to guarantee that simulations under the base system are aligned to observed patterns of data l Need to be careful - check calibration draws Calibration (‘alignment’) 13

14 Probabilistic model Hours (reform) Hours (base) 0 Pr(0,0)Pr(0,10)Pr(0,16)Pr(0,20)Pr(0,24)Pr(0,30)Pr(0,40)Pr(0,48) 10 Pr(10,0)Pr(10,10)Pr(10,16)Pr(10,20)Pr(10,24)Pr(10,30)Pr(10,40)Pr(10,48) 16 Pr(16,0)Pr(16,10)Pr(16,16)Pr(16,20)Pr(16,24)Pr(16,30)Pr(16,40)Pr(16,48) 20 Pr(20,0)Pr(20,10)Pr(20,16)Pr(20,20)Pr(20,24)Pr(20,30)Pr(20,40)Pr(20,48) 24 Pr(24,0)Pr(24,10)Pr(24,16)Pr(24,20)Pr(24,24)Pr(24,30)Pr(24,40)Pr(24,48) 30 Pr(30,0)Pr(30,10)Pr(30,16)Pr(30,20)Pr(30,24)Pr(30,30)Pr(30,40)Pr(30,48) 40 Pr(40,0)Pr(40,10)Pr(40,16)Pr(40,20)Pr(40,24)Pr(40,30)Pr(40,40)Pr(40,48) 48 Pr(48,0)Pr(48,10)Pr(48,16)Pr(48,20)Pr(48,24)Pr(48,30)Pr(48,40)Pr(48,48)

15 Probabilistic model (calibrated) Hours (reform) Hours (base) Pr(16,0)Pr(16,10)Pr(16,16)Pr(16,20)Pr(16,24)Pr(16,30)Pr(16,40)Pr(16,48)

l Validate the model - compare model simulations with ‘known’ evaluation evidence - estimate model over periods of tax policy reform l Be sensitive to model choice - ceteris paribus (‘as if...’) - ‘rational’ model better for some groups than others l Recognise limitations - model not configured to accommodate unemployment - wages and prices taken as exogenous - no interactions with demand side of labour market To Adam... Issues 16

EHM Practicalities Behavioural Labour Supply Modelling in DWP Adam Richardson, 6 th May 2009

18 Policy Simulation Model Static Microsimulation Model ­Models GB tax and benefit system ­Based on FRS With additional info drawn from admin data ­Uprated to current year Financial amounts draw-down of old benefits grossing / calibration ­Written in SAS, with graphical interface ­Takes less than a minute to run ­Used by analysts across DWP

19 Incorporating Behaviour Budget constraints (several hours) ­Requires entry wages for the unemployed Preference functions ­Calibration (30 – 40 minutes) ­Simulation (10 minutes) Probabilistic Results ­Validation Compare to known reforms Other indicators of incentives

20 Example Results Change: increase level of out-of-work benefits

21 Example Results Change in Total Employment

22 Example Results Change in Spending on Benefits

23 Example Results Employment Transitions (Lone Parents) Reform Hours Base Hours 0521,7781, , , , , , , , , , , , , ,804

24 Way Forward Validation Roll out to DWP analysts ­Stress-testing Expand scope of modelling

25 Questions?