Investor Behavior and Capital Market Efficiency

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved. Chapter 13 Investor Behavior and Capital Market Efficiency.
Advertisements

Draft lecture – FIN 352 Professor Dow CSU-Northridge March 2012.
The Arbitrage Pricing Theory (Chapter 10)  Single-Factor APT Model  Multi-Factor APT Models  Arbitrage Opportunities  Disequilibrium in APT  Is APT.
P.V. VISWANATH FOR A FIRST COURSE IN INVESTMENTS.
Chapter 11 Optimal Portfolio Choice
Pricing Risk Chapter 10.
Arbitrage Pricing Theory and Multifactor Models of Risk and Return
Risk and Rates of Return
INVESTMENT PLANNING LECTURE 17: CAPM & OTHER MODELS MARCH 16, 2015 Vandana Srivastava.
Market Efficiency Chapter 10.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., All Rights Reserved. The Efficient Market Hypothesis CHAPTER 8.
5 - 1 CHAPTER 5 Risk and Return: Portfolio Theory and Asset Pricing Models Portfolio Theory Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) Efficient frontier Capital.
Mutual Investment Club of Cornell Week 8: Portfolio Theory April 7 th, 2011.
Capital Asset Pricing and Arbitrary Pricing Theory
Portfolio Analysis and Theory
Return, Risk, and the Security Market Line
Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved. Chapter 10 Capital Markets and the Pricing of Risk.
Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved. Chapter 10 Capital Markets and the Pricing of Risk.
Modern Portfolio Concepts
McGraw-Hill/Irwin © 2008 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., All Rights Reserved. Capital Asset Pricing and Arbitrage Pricing Theory CHAPTER 7.
© 2003 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Return, Risk, and the Security Market Line Chapter Thirteen.
Chapter 7 The Stock Market, The Theory of Rational Expectations, and the Efficient Market Hypothesis.
Chapter 7: Capital Asset Pricing Model and Arbitrage Pricing Theory
Portfolio Theory Capital Asset Pricing Model and Arbitrage Pricing Theory.
Copyright © 2003 Pearson Education, Inc. Slide 5-1 Chapter 5 Risk and Return.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2013 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Capital Asset Pricing and Arbitrage Pricing Theory 7 Bodie,
Presented by: Lauren Rudd
McGraw-Hill/Irwin © 2008 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., All Rights Reserved. Capital Asset Pricing and Arbitrage Pricing Theory CHAPTER 7.
Efficient Capital Markets Objectives: What is meant by the concept that capital markets are efficient? Why should capital markets be efficient? What are.
CHAPTER 5: Risk and Return: Portfolio Theory and Asset Pricing Models
Class Business Homework Upcoming Midterm – Review Session Wed (5/18) 5 – 6 pm 270 TNRB.
Return, Risk, and the Security Market Line
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2002 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved Corporate Finance Ross  Westerfield  Jaffe Sixth Edition.
Arbitrage Pricing Theory and Multifactor Models of Risk and Return
INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS Copyright © 2011 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin CHAPTER 10 Arbitrage Pricing.
Chapter 13 Alternative Models of Systematic Risk.
1 Chapter 7 Portfolio Theory and Other Asset Pricing Models.
Investments, 8 th edition Bodie, Kane and Marcus Slides by Susan Hine McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2009 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights.
Arbitrage Pricing Theorem Chapter 7 1. Learning Objectives Develop an understanding of multi-factor pricing models Use the APT to identify mispriced securities.
Finance - Pedro Barroso
Risks and Rates of Return
Chapter 3 Arbitrage and Financial Decision Making
STRATEGIC FINANCIAL MANAGEMENT Hurdle Rate: The Basics of Risk II KHURAM RAZA.
Chapter 06 Risk and Return. Value = FCF 1 FCF 2 FCF ∞ (1 + WACC) 1 (1 + WACC) ∞ (1 + WACC) 2 Free cash flow (FCF) Market interest rates Firm’s business.
Chapter 10 Capital Markets and the Pricing of Risk.
Chapter 10 Capital Markets and the Pricing of Risk
Pricing Risk. Outline Short Class Exercise Measuring risk and return – Expected return and return Variance – Realized versus expected return – Empirical.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2005 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Chapter 11 Arbitrage Pricing Theory and Multifactor Models of.
Chapter 7 The Stock Market, the Theory of Rational Expectations, and the Efficient Market Hypothesis.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., All Rights Reserved. Capital Asset Pricing and Arbitrage Pricing Theory CHAPTER 7.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., All Rights Reserved. Capital Asset Pricing and Arbitrage Pricing Theory CHAPTER 7.
Capital Asset Pricing and Arbitrage Pricing Theory
Introductory Investment Analysis Part II Course Leader: Lauren Rudd January 12, weeks.
CHAPTER 3 Risk and Return: Part II
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved. Chapter 8 Investor Choice: Risk and Reward.
Copyright © 2014 Pearson Canada Inc. Chapter 7 THE STOCK MARKET, THE THEORY OF RATIONAL EXPECTATIONS, AND THE EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS Mishkin/Serletis.
Slide 9-1 Market Efficiency 1. Performance of portfolio managers 2. Anomalies 3. Behavioral Finance as a challenge to the EMH 1/7/
12-1. Copyright © 2005 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin 12 Return, Risk, and the Security Market Line.
CAPM Testing & Alternatives to CAPM
Chapter 12 Estimating the Cost of Capital. Copyright ©2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All rights reserved The Equity Cost of Capital The Capital.
Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) Dr. BALAMURUGAN MUTHURAMAN Chapter
Chapter 7 Capital Asset Pricing and Arbitrage Pricing Theory Copyright © 2010 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
Portfolio risk and return
Pricing Risk.
Arbitrage Pricing Theory and Multifactor Models of Risk and Return
Arbitrage Pricing Theory and Multifactor Models of Risk and Return
Arbitrage Pricing Theory and Multifactor Models of Risk and Return
Arbitrage Pricing Theory and Multifactor Models of Risk and Return
Investor Behavior and Capital Market Efficiency
Presentation transcript:

Investor Behavior and Capital Market Efficiency Chapter 13 Investor Behavior and Capital Market Efficiency

13.1 Competition and Capital Markets (cont'd) Profiting from Non-Zero Alpha Stocks Investors can improve the performance of their portfolios by buying stocks with positive alphas and by selling stocks with negative alphas.

Figure 13.1 An Inefficient Market Portfolio

Figure 13.2 Deviations from the Security Market Line

13.1 Competition and Capital Markets Identifying a Stock’s Alpha To improve the performance of their portfolios, investors will compare the expected return of a security with its required return from the security market line.

Alpha The difference between a stock’s expected return and its required return according to the security market line is called the stock’s alpha. When the market portfolio is efficient, all stocks are on the security market line and have an alpha of zero.

Textbook Example 13.1

13.2 Information and Rational Expectations (cont’d) All investors correctly interpret and use their own information, as well as information that can be inferred from market prices or the trades of others. Regardless of how much information an investor has access to, he can guarantee himself an alpha of zero by holding the market portfolio.

13.2 Information and Rational Expectations (cont’d) Because the average portfolio of all investors is the market portfolio, the average alpha of all investors is zero. If no investor earns a negative alpha, then no investor can earn a positive alpha, and the market portfolio must be efficient.

13.2 Information and Rational Expectations (cont’d) The market portfolio can be inefficient only if a significant number of investors either: Misinterpret information and believe they are earning a positive alpha when they are actually earning a negative alpha, or Care about aspects of their portfolios other than expected return and volatility, and so are willing to hold inefficient portfolios of securities.

13.3 The Behavior of Individual Investors Underdiversification and Portfolio Biases There is much evidence that individual investors fail to diversify their portfolios adequately. Familiarity Bias Investors favor investments in companies they are familiar with Relative Wealth Concerns Investors care more about the performance of their portfolios relative to their peers.

13.3 The Behavior of Individual Investors (cont’d) Excessive Trading and Overconfidence According to the CAPM, investors should hold risk-free assets in combination with the market portfolio of all risky securities. In reality, a tremendous amount of trading occurs each day.

Figure 13.3 NYSE Annual Share Turnover, 1970–2008 Source: www.nyxdata.com

13.3 The Behavior of Individual Investors (cont’d) Excessive Trading and Overconfidence Overconfidence Bias Investors believe they can pick winners and losers when, in fact, they cannot; this leads them to trade too much. Sensation Seeking An individual’s desire for novel and intense risk-taking experiences.

Figure 13.4 Individual Investor Returns Versus Portfolio Turnover Source: B. Barber and T. Odean, “Trading Is Hazardous to Your Wealth: The Common Stock Investment Performance of Individual Investors,” Journal of Finance 55 (2000) 773–806.)

13.3 The Behavior of Individual Investors (cont’d) Individual Behavior and Market Prices If individuals depart from the CAPM in random ways, then these departures will tend to cancel out. Individuals will hold the market portfolio in aggregate, and there will be no effect on market prices or returns.

13.4 Systematic Trading Biases Hanging on to Losers and the Disposition Effect Disposition Effect When an investor holds on to stocks that have lost their value and sell stocks that have risen in value since the time of purchase. Investor Attention, Mood, and Experience Studies show that individuals are more likely to buy stocks that have recently been in the news, engaged in advertising, experienced exceptionally high trading volume, or have had extreme returns. Sunshine generally has a positive effect on mood, and studies have found that stock returns tend to be higher when it is a sunny day at the location of the stock exchange.

13.4 Systematic Trading Biases (cont’d) Investor Attention, Mood, and Experience Investors appear to put too much weight on their own experience rather than considering all the historical evidence. As a result, people who grew up and lived during a time of high stock returns are more likely to invest in stocks than people who experienced times when stocks performed poorly.

13.5 The Efficiency of the Market Portfolio If the market portfolio is efficient, securities should not have alphas that are significantly different from zero. For most stocks the standard errors of the alpha estimates are large, so it is impossible to conclude that the alphas are statistically different from zero. However, it is not difficult to find individual stocks that, in the past, have not plotted on the SML.

13.4 Systematic Trading Biases (cont’d) Herd Behavior When investors make similar trading errors because they are actively trying to follow each other’s behavior Informational Cascade Effects Where traders ignore their own information hoping to profit from the information of others

13.4 Systematic Trading Biases (cont’d) Implications of Behavioral Biases If individual investors are engaging in strategies that earn negative alphas, it may be possible for more sophisticated investors to take advantage of this behavior and earn positive alphas

13.5 The Efficiency of the Market Portfolio Trading on News or Recommendations Takeover Offers If you could predict whether the firm would ultimately be acquired or not, you could earn profits trading on that information

Figure 13.5 Returns to Holding Target Stocks Subsequent to Takeover Announcements Source: Adapted from M. Bradley, A. Desai, and E. H. Kim, “The Rationale Behind Interfirm Tender Offers: Information or Synergy?” Journal of Financial Economics 11 (1983) 183–206.

13.5 The Efficiency of the Market Portfolio (cont’d) Trading on News or Recommendations Stock Recommendations Jim Cramer makes numerous stock recommendations on his television show, Mad Money For stocks with news, it appears that the stock price correctly reflects this information the next day, and stays flat (relative to the market) subsequently On the other hand, for the stocks without news, there appears to be a significant jump in the stock price the next day, but the stock price then tends to fall relative to the market, generating a negative alpha, over the next several weeks

Figure 13.6 Stock Price Reactions to Recommendations on Mad Money Source: Adapted from J. Engelberg, C. Sasseville, J. Williams, “Market Madness? The Case of Mad Money,” SSRN working paper, 2009.

13.5 The Efficiency of the Market Portfolio (cont’d) The Performance of Fund Managers Numerous studies report that the actual returns to investors of the average mutual fund have a negative alpha Superior past performance is not a good predictor of a fund’s future ability to outperform the market

13.6 Style-Based Anomalies and the Market Efficiency Debate Researchers have studied whether portfolios of stocks plot on this line and have searched for portfolios that would be most likely to have nonzero alphas. Researchers have identified a number of characteristics that can be used to pick portfolios that produce high average returns.

The Size Effect Size Effect Stocks with lower market capitalizations have been found to have higher average returns. Portfolios based on size were formed. Portfolios consisting of small stocks had higher average excess returns than those consisting of large stocks.

Figure 13.9 Excess Return of Size Portfolios, 1926–2008 Source: Data courtesy of Kenneth French.

Figure 13.10 Excess Return of Book-to-Market Portfolios, 1926–2008 Source: Data courtesy of Kenneth French.

The Size Effect (cont'd) Data Snooping Bias The idea that given enough characteristics, it will always be possible to find some characteristic that by pure chance happens to be correlated with the estimation error of a regression

The Size Effect (cont'd) However, The size effect did not seem to disappear This is evidence against the efficiency of the market portfolio (Berk, 1995)

Example Problem Suppose two firms, ABC and XYZ, are both expected to pay a dividend stream $2.2 million per year in perpetuity. ABC’s cost of capital is 12% per year and XYZ’s cost of capital is 16%. Which firm has the higher market value? Which firm has the higher expected return? 33

Example Problem Now assume both stocks have the same estimated beta, either because of estimation error or because the market portfolio is not efficient. Based on this beta, the CAPM would assign an expected return of 15% to both stocks. Which firm has the higher alpha? How do the market values of the firms relate to their alphas? 34

Past Returns Momentum Strategy Buying stocks that have had past high returns (and shorting stocks that have had past low returns) When the market portfolio is efficient, past returns should not predict alphas. However, researchers found that the best performing stocks had positive alphas over the next six months. This is evidence against the efficiency of the market portfolio.

Implications of Positive Alphas If the CAPM correctly computes the risk premium, an investment opportunity with a positive alpha is a positive-NPV investment opportunity, and investors should flock to invest in such strategies.

Implications of Positive Alphas If the CAPM correctly computes risk premiums, but investors are ignoring opportunities to earn extra returns without bearing any extra risk, it is because Investors are systematically ignoring positive-NPV investment opportunities. The positive-alpha trading strategies contain risk that investors are unwilling to bear but the CAPM does not capture. This would suggest that the market portfolio is not efficient.

Three main reasons why the CAPM fails Proxy Error Investors do not care about mean-variance Non-tradeable Wealth

13.7 Multifactor Models of Risk The expected return of any marketable security is: When the market portfolio is not efficient, we have to find a method to identify an efficient portfolio before we can use the above equation. However, it is not actually necessary to identify the efficient portfolio itself. All that is required is to identify a collection of portfolios from which the efficient portfolio can be constructed.

Factor Portfolios Assume that there are two portfolios that can be combined to form an efficient portfolio. RF1 and RF2 are factor portfolios. The efficient portfolio consists of some (unknown) combination of these two factor portfolios, represented by portfolio weights x1 and x2: To find βs of stock s, use multiple regression: This means that if we form a portfolio where we buy stock s, short each of the factor portfolio according to its respective β, and invest in the risk free asset. We will get , which translates to αs risk premium and ε s risk.

Factor Portfolios Factor Beta Setting αs equal to zero and taking expectations of both sides (step 2), the result is the following two-factor model of expected returns: Factor Beta The sensitivity of the stock’s excess returns to the excess return of a factor portfolio.

Using Factor Portfolios (cont'd) Single-Factor versus Multi-Factor Model A singe-factor model uses one portfolio while a multi- factor model uses more than one portfolio in the model. The CAPM is an example of a single-factor model while the Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT) is an example of a multifactor model.

Building a Multifactor Model Given N factor portfolios with returns RF1, . . . , RFN, the expected return of asset s is defined as: β1…. βN are the factor betas.

Building a Multifactor Model (cont'd) If all factor portfolios are self-financing then:

Selecting the Portfolios A trading strategy that each year buys a portfolio of small stocks and finances this position by short selling a portfolio of big stocks has historically produced positive risk-adjusted returns. This self-financing portfolio is widely known as the small-minus-big (SMB) portfolio.

Selecting the Portfolios (cont'd) A trading strategy that each year buys an equally- weighted portfolio of stocks with a book-to-market ratio less than the 30th percentile of NYSE firms and finances this position by short selling an equally-weighted portfolio of stocks with a book- to-market ratio greater than the 70th percentile of NYSE stocks has historically produced positive risk-adjusted returns. This self-financing portfolio is widely known as the high-minus-low (HML) portfolio.

Selecting the Portfolios (cont'd) Each year, after ranking stocks by their return over the last one year, a trading strategy that buys the top 30% of stocks and finances this position by short selling bottom 30% of stocks has historically produced positive risk-adjusted returns. This self-financing portfolio is widely known as the prior one-year momentum (PR1YR) portfolio. This trading strategy requires holding the portfolio for a year and the process is repeated annually.

Selecting the Portfolios (cont'd) Currently the most popular choice for the multifactor model uses the excess return of the market, SMB, HML, and PR1YR portfolios. Fama-French-Carhart (FFC) Factor Specifications

Back to the basic Why is the inefficiency of the CAPM important? For someone who wants to construct a portfolio For a corporate manager trying to assess the NPV of a project.

Calculating the Cost of Capital Using the Fama-French-Carhart Factor Specification

Problem You are considering making an investment in a project in the semiconductor industry. The project has the same level of non-diversifiable risk as investing in Intel stock. Assume you have calculated the following factor betas for Intel stock: Determine the cost of capital by using the FFC factor specification if the monthly risk-free rate is 0.5%. 4-factors.xls 51

Calculating the Cost of Capital Using the Fama-French-Carhart Factor Specification (cont'd) Although it is widely used in research to measure risk, there is much debate about whether the FFC factor specification is really a significant improvement over the CAPM. One area where researchers have found that the FFC factor specification does appear to do better than the CAPM is measuring the risk of actively managed mutual funds. Researchers have found that funds with high returns in the past have positive alphas under the CAPM. When the same tests were repeated using the FFC factor specification to compute alphas, no evidence was found that mutual funds with high past returns had future positive alphas.

So, why is it hard to calculate cost of capital based on multi-factor models? Calculating the cost of capital using the the multifactor model relies on accurate estimates of risk premiums and betas. Accurately estimating these quantities is difficult. Both risk premiums and betas may not remain stable over time because.. Statistical errors – especially in multifactor models. Economic reason – firms change over time

Variation of CAPM Beta in Time