Nonlinear Pricing Models

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Dynamic Workforce Planning Models
Advertisements

Introduction to LP Modeling
A Multiperiod Production Problem
Network Models Robert Zimmer Room 6, 25 St James.
Network Models Robert Zimmer Room 6, 25 St James.
Network Models Robert Zimmer Room 6, 25 St James.
Price Discrimination A monopoly engages in price discrimination if it is able to sell otherwise identical units of output at different prices Whether a.
Example 2.2 Estimating the Relationship between Price and Demand.
1 Predatory Conduct. 2 Predatory conduct is the implementation of a strategy designed specifically to deter rival firms from competing in a market. To.
Managerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 5e Chapter 7: Pricing with Market Power Copyright © 2009 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All.
Example 2.1 Finding a Breakeven Point. Background Information n The Great Threads Company sells hand-knit sweaters. Great Threads is planning to print.
Example 6.1 Capital Budgeting Models | 6.3 | 6.4 | 6.5 | 6.6 | Background Information n The Tatham Company is considering seven.
Advanced Pricing Ideas 1. 2 We have looked at a single price monopoly. But perhaps other ways of pricing can lead to greater profits for the sports team.
Pricing Strategies for Firms with Market Power
14 Perfect Competition CHAPTER Notes and teaching tips: 4, 7, 8, 9, 25, 26, 27, and 28. To view a full-screen figure during a class, click the red “expand”
Example 14.3 Football Production at the Pigskin Company
Spreadsheet Simulation
Chapter 14 Advanced Pricing Techniques
Chapter Twelve Pricing.
Example 6.4 Plant and Warehouse Location Models | 6.2 | 6.3 | 6.5 | 6.6 | Background Information n Huntco produces tomato sauce.
Linear Programming Excel Solver. MAX8X 1 + 5X 2 s.t.2X 1 + 1X 2 ≤ 1000 (Plastic) 3X 1 + 4X 2 ≤ 2400 (Prod. Time) X 1 + X 2 ≤ 700 (Total Prod.) X 1 - X.
Example 6.2 Fixed-Cost Models | 6.3 | 6.4 | 6.5 | 6.6 | Background Information n The Great Threads Company is capable of manufacturing.
Class Concepts – Advanced Pricing  Advanced Pricing -Use price customization to sell the same good at different prices per unit -Ideally, we would like.
Example 12.1 Operations Models: Bidding on Contract.
© 2008 Pearson Addison Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter Twelve Pricing and Advertising.
1 1 st degree price discrimination A form of Monopoly Power.
Example 5.3 More General Logistics Models | 5.2 | 5.4 | 5.5 | 5.6 | 5.7 | 5.8 | 5.9 | 5.10 | 5.10a a Background Information.
Example 5.5 Non-logistics Network Models | 5.2 | 5.3 | 5.4 | 5.6 | 5.7 | 5.8 | 5.9 | 5.10 | 5.10a a Background Information.
Example 7.1 Pricing Models | 7.3 | 7.4 | 7.5 | 7.6 | 7.7 | 7.8 | 7.9 | 7.10 | Background Information n The Madison.
Example 8.7 Cluster Analysis | 8.2 | 8.3 | 8.4 | 8.5 | 8.6 | CLUSTERS.XLS n This file contains demographic data on 49 of.
Example 9.1 Goal Programming | 9.3 | Background Information n The Leon Burnit Ad Agency is trying to determine a TV advertising schedule.
Example 7.6 Facility Location Models | 7.2 | 7.3 | 7.4 | 7.5 | 7.7 | 7.8 | 7.9 | 7.10 | Background Information.
Spreadsheet Modeling & Decision Analysis:
Example 4.4 Blending Models.
Example 15.2 Blending Oil Products at Chandler Oil
Example 14.1 Introduction to LP Modeling. 14.1a14.1a | 14.2 | Linear Programming n Linear programming (LP) is a method of spreadsheet optimization.
Pricing Policies chapter 18
Linear Programming The Industrial Revolution resulted in (eventually) -- large companies, large problems How to optimize the utilization of scarce resources?
Transportation Models
Example 15.4 Distributing Tomato Products at the RedBrand Company
Copyright © 2009 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Chapter 4 How Businesses Work.
EXAMPLE: 3.1 ASSEMBLING AND TESTING COMPUTERS
Chapter 4 How Businesses Work McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2012 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
Chapter 7 Profit Maximization and Competitive Market.
Pricing Examples. Bundling In marketing, product bundling offers several products for sale as one combined product. This is common in the software business.
Example 12.6 A Financial Planning Model | 12.2 | 12.3 | 12.4 | 12.5 | 12.7 |12.8 | 12.9 | | | | | | |
Example 16.1 Ordering calendars at Walton Bookstore
Example 7.2 Pricing Models | 7.3 | 7.4 | 7.5 | 7.6 | 7.7 | 7.8 | 7.9 | 7.10 | Background Information n We continue.
Spreadsheets in Finance and Forecasting Presentation 8: Problem Solving.
Spreadsheet Modeling of Linear Programming (LP). Spreadsheet Modeling There is no exact one way to develop an LP spreadsheet model. We will work through.
Example 15.6 Managing Cash Flows at Fun Toys
Integer Programming Models
Example 4.5 Production Process Models | 4.2 | 4.3 | 4.4 | 4.6 | Background Information n Repco produces three drugs, A, B and.
Example 15.1 Daily Scheduling of Postal Employees Workforce Scheduling Models.
Example 5.8 Non-logistics Network Models | 5.2 | 5.3 | 5.4 | 5.5 | 5.6 | 5.7 | 5.9 | 5.10 | 5.10a a Background Information.
The Supply Curve and the Behavior of Firms
Example 2.5 Decisions Involving the Time Value of Money.
Example 2.3 An Ordering Decision with Quantity Discounts.
MBA7020_12.ppt/July 25, 2005/Page 1 Georgia State University - Confidential MBA 7020 Business Analysis Foundations Optimization Modeling July 25, 2005.
Example 15.7 Capital Budgeting at the Tatham Company Integer Programming Models.
Example 2.4 An Option Model for Hedging Investment Risk.
Example 5.10 Project Scheduling Models | 5.2 | 5.3 | 5.4 | 5.5 | 5.6 | 5.7 | 5.8 | 5.9 | 5.10a a Background Information.
Spreadsheet Modeling & Decision Analysis A Practical Introduction to Management Science 5 th edition Cliff T. Ragsdale.
3 Components for a Spreadsheet Optimization Problem  There is one cell which can be identified as the Target or Set Cell, the single objective of the.
Perfect Competition CHAPTER 11 C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to 1 Explain a perfectly.
Chapter: 14 >> Krugman/Wells Economics ©2009  Worth Publishers Monopoly.
The analytics of constrained optimal decisions microeco nomics spring 2016 the monopoly model (II): further pricing analysis ………….1platform and consumables.
14-1 Learning Objectives  Explain why uniform pricing does not generate maximum possible total revenue and how price discrimination can generate more.
A Multiperiod Production Problem
Presentation transcript:

Nonlinear Pricing Models Example 8.2 Nonlinear Pricing Models

Background Information Suppose we sell Menthos candy. Most people value the first pack of Menthos they purchase more than the second pack. They also value the second pack more than the third pack, and so on. How can we take advantage of this when pricing Menthos? If we charge a single price for each pack of Menthos, then few people are going to buy more than one or two packs. Alternatively, however, we can try the two-part tariff approach.

Background Information -- continued Here we charge an “entry fee” to anyone who buys Menthos, plus a reduced price per pack purchased. For example, a reasonable single price per pack is $1.10, then a reasonable two-part tariff might be an entry fee of $1.50 and a price of $.50 per pack. This will give some customers an incentive to purchase many packs of Menthos. Because the total cost of purchasing n packs is no longer a linear function of n – it is now “piecewise linear” – we refer to the two-part tariff as a nonlinear pricing strategy.

Background Information -- continued As usual with pricing models, the key input is customer sensitivity to price. Rather than having a single demand function, however, we now assume that each customer has his or her unique sensitivity to price. To keep the example fairly small, we will assume that four typical customers from the four market segments for the product have been asked what they would pay for each successive pack of Menthos, the results are shown on the next slide.

Background Information -- continued For example, customer 1 is willing to pay $1.24 for the first pack of Menthos, $1.03 for the second pack, and only $0.35 for the tenth pack. These four customers are considered representative of the market. If it costs $0.40 to produce a pack of Menthos, determine a profit-maximizing single price and a profit-maximizing two-part tariff. Assume that the four market segments have 10,000, 5000, 7500, and 15,000 customers, respectively, and that the customers within a market segment all respond identically to price.

MENTHOS1.XLS The completed single-price model appears on the next slide. This file contains the spreadsheet model.

Developing the Single-Price Model To develop this model, proceed as follows. Inputs. Enter the inputs in the shaded ranges. Note that the large shaded range is just the price sensitivity table shown before. Price. The only decision variable in this model is the single price charged for every pack of Menthos sold. Enter any value in this Price cell. Total value table. The values in the shaded price sensitivity range are marginal values, the most each customer would pay for the next pack of Menthos. In the range H6:K15 calculate the total value of n packs to each customer (for n from 1 to 10).

Developing the Single-Price Model -- continued First, enter the formula =B6 in cell H6 and copy it across row 6. Then enter the formula =H6+B7 in cell H77 and copy it to the range H7:K15. Total cost column. Using the single-price scheme, each customer must pay np for n packs if the price is p. Calculate these amounts in the range E19:E28 by entering the formula =UnitPrice*D19 in cell E19 and copying it down. Surplus table. This is the key to the model. We define the “surplus” for any customer from buying n packs as the total value of n packs minus the total cost of n packs, and we assume that the customer will buy the number of packs with the largest surplus.

Developing the Single-Price Model -- continued This makes sense economically. If a customer places more value on n packs than it costs to buy n packs, then presumably the customer will consider purchasing n packs. But a customer will not purchase n packs if they cost more than the customer values them. To calculate these surpluses, enter the formula =H6-$E19 in cell H19 and copy it to the range H19:K28. Maximum surplus. Calculate the maximum surplus for each customer by entering the formula =MAX(H19:H28) in cell B32 and copying it across row 32.

Developing the Single-Price Model -- continued Packs purchased. For each customer we need to find the number of packs that corresponds to the maximum surplus. This can be done easily with Excel’s MATCH function. Specifically, enter the formula =IF(B32<0,0,MATCH(B32,H19:H28,0)) in cell B33 and copy it across row 33. This formula says that if the maximum surplus is negative, the customer will not purchase any packs at all. Otherwise, it matches the maximum surplus to the entries in the range H19:H28 and returns the index of the cell where the match occurs. In this example, the match for customer 1 occurs in the 4th cell of the range H19:H28, so that the MATCH function returns 4. Note that the last argument of the MATCH function is 0 if we want an exact match, as we do here.

Developing the Single-Price Model -- continued Then calculate the total number of packs purchased by all customers with the formula =SUMPRODUCT(MktSize,Npurch) in the TotPurch cell. Profit. Calculate the profit in the Profit cell with the formula =(UnitPrice-UnitCost)*TotPurch

Using the Evolutionary Solver First, note that the standard Solver will have trouble with this model because of the IF and MATCH functions. However, these present no difficulties to the Evolutionary Solver. We set it up as shown on the next slide, using the same values for the various options as in the previous example. Note that we use an upper limit of $1.50 for the unit price. This suffices because the most any customer will pay for any pack of Menthos is $1.49.

Using the Evolutionary Solver -- continued Again, the Solver converges to the solution shown earlier quickly and then tries for a long time – unsuccessfully – to find a better solution. We can be fairly certain that this solution is optimal, but this is not guaranteed. The single price of $0.80 produces a profit of $62,000. It strikes the best balance for these four market segments. A lower price needlessly sacrifices revenue, whereas a higher price would cause at least one market segment to buy fewer packs.

MENTHOS2.XLS The two-part tariff model is so similar that we made a copy of the Menthos1.xls spreadsheet file and then made the following modifications. The completed single-price model appears on the next slide. This file contains the spreadsheet model.

Developing the Two-Part Tariff Model The steps that are the same as before are omitted. Decision variables. Now there are two decision variables – the fixed entry fee and the variable cost per pack. Enter any values for these in the Fixed and Variable cells. Total cost column. The total cost of purchasing n packs is now the fixed entry fee plus the variable cost times n. Calculate this in the range E19:E28 by entering the formula =Fixed+Variable*D19 in cell E19 and copying it to the rest of the range.

Developing the Two-Part Tariff Model -- continued Revenues. Calculate the amount paid by the customers in row 34 by entering the formula =IF(B33>0,Fixed+Variable*B33,0) in cell B34 and copying it across. Note that the entry fee is evidently too high for customer 2, so she does not purchase any packs, and there is no corresponding revenue. Profit. Calculate the profit in the Profit cell with the formula =SUMPRODUCT(Revenues, MktSize)-UnitCost*TotPurch

Using the Evolutionary Solver The Evolutionary Solver setup is almost the same as before. However, we now select both the Fixed and Variable cells as changing cells, and we put upper limits on each of them (We used $10 as an upper limit on Fixed and $1.50 for Variable, reasoning that these would almost certainly be large enough. The solution shown earlier was found after a few seconds.

Using the Evolutionary Solver -- continued It indicates that the company should charge all customers $3.39 plus $0.39 for each pack purchased. This pricing scheme is too high for the second market segment, which doesn't buy any packs, but it entices segments 1, 3, and 4 to purchase many more packs than they purchased with the single price of $0.80.

Using the Evolutionary Solver -- continued More important it yields a profit of $107,376, about 73% more than the profit from the single-price policy. The moral is clear – clever pricing schemes can make companies significantly larger profits than the simple pricing schemes we are accustomed to.