Microeconomics 2 Answers to the first 17 questions on the Second Specimen Examination Paper (the remaining 10 answers are elsewhere)

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. Markets and Prices A market is any arrangement that enables buyers and sellers to get information and do business with.
Advertisements

Perfect Competition 12.
Microeconomics 2 John Hey. Module Representatives Athena Fu Emma Wilson-Young Krishna Patel Liz Blum Michaela Lucas Kenny Yang.
Chapter 3 McGraw-Hill/IrwinCopyright © 2010 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
Rational Consumer Choice. Chapter Outline The Opportunity Set or Budget Constraint Budget Shifts Due to Price or Income Changes Consumer Preferences The.
Microeconomics 2 John Hey. “The opposite of love is not hate, it's indifference. The opposite of art is not ugliness, it's indifference. The opposite.
14 Perfect Competition CHAPTER Notes and teaching tips: 4, 7, 8, 9, 25, 26, 27, and 28. To view a full-screen figure during a class, click the red “expand”
When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Explain a perfectly competitive firm’s profit-
11 PERFECT COMPETITION CHAPTER.
11 CHAPTER Perfect Competition
© 2008 Pearson Addison Wesley. All rights reserved Review Perfect Competition Market.
Chapter 12 © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western General Equilibrium and Welfare.
Chapter 12 © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western General Equilibrium and Welfare.
3 Demand and Supply Notes and teaching tips: 4, 6, 41, and 46.
Chapter 7 Perfect Competition ©2010  Worth Publishers 1.
Economic surplus Gains and losses with international trade: Economic Welfare.
Types of Market Structure
Summer Semester  Objective of a firm in a competitive market is to maximize profit.  Profit is equal to total revenue minus total cost of production.
4 Market Structures Candy Markets Simulation.
ECON 6012 Cost Benefit Analysis Memorial University of Newfoundland
Today Begin Monopoly. Monopoly Chapter 22 Perfect Competition = Many firms Oligopoly = A few firms Four Basic Models Monopoly = One firm Monopolistic.
ECON 101: Introduction to Economics - I Lecture 3 – Demand and Supply.
Chapter 10-Perfect Competition McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2015 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
13 PART 5 Perfect Competition
Chapter 10: Perfect Competition.
3 DEMAND AND SUPPLY.
Perfect Competition Chapter 7
© 2005 Worth Publishers Slide 9-1 CHAPTER 9 Perfect Competition and the Supply Curve PowerPoint® Slides by Can Erbil and Gustavo Indart © 2005 Worth Publishers,
Microeconomics 2 Answers to the first 17 questions on the First Specimen Examination Paper (the remaining 10 answers are elsewhere)
CHAPTER 21 PURE COMPETITION COMPETITION.
Lecture 10 Market Structure. To determine structure of any particular market, we begin by asking 1. How many buyers and sellers are there in the market?
Economics 2010 Lecture 12 Perfect Competition. Competition  Perfect Competition  Firms Choices in Perfect Competition  The Firm’s Short-Run Decision.
Microeconomia Corso E John Hey. Chapter 7 – what do we know? Individual with given preferences and income m faces prices p 1 and p 2 for two goods:1 and.
TOOL #3 THE SUPPLY AND DEMAND MODEL. Our purpose is to illustrate how the supply and demand model can describe a macroeconomic system. One of the impressive.
Microeconomics Course E John Hey. Examinations Go to Read.
Microeconomics Corso E John Hey. Chapter 5 We know that the indifference curves of an individual are given by the preferences of that individual. We know.
Microeconomics Course E John Hey. An overview...of the first two parts of the course......of the most important points.
12 PERFECT COMPETITION © 2012 Pearson Addison-Wesley.
PERFECT COMPETITION 11 CHAPTER. Objectives After studying this chapter, you will able to  Define perfect competition  Explain how price and output are.
Chapter 4 Consumer and Firm Behaviour: The Work-Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education Canada.
© 2010 Pearson Education Canada. Markets and Prices A market is any arrangement that enables buyers and sellers to get information and do business with.
Microeconomics 2 Answers to the questions on the First Specimen Examination Paper for the new style examination.
Chapter 8 Perfect Competition ECONOMICS: Principles and Applications, 4e HALL & LIEBERMAN, © 2008 Thomson South-Western.
Lecture 8 Profit Maximization. Comparison of consumer theory with producer theory In consumer theory we learned that the main objective of consumer is.
Objectives:  Use the utility-maximizing model to explain how consumers choose goods and services.  Use the concept of utility to explain how the law.
Microeconomics Corso E John Hey. What do we know? The reservation price of a buyer is......the maximum price he or she would pay. The reservation price.
Perfect Competition CHAPTER 10 When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Explain a perfectly.
Microeconomics 2 John Hey.
PPT accompaniment for the Consortium's Supply, Demand, and Market Equilibrium.
1 Endowments. 2 Buying and Selling Trade involves exchange -- when something is bought something else must be sold. What will be bought? What will be.
1 Chapter 3 Lecture DEMAND AND SUPPLY. 2 Market and Prices A market is any arrangement that enables buyers and sellers to get information and do business.
11 CHAPTER Perfect Competition.
Every product is sold in a market that can be considered one of the above market structures. For example: 1.Fast Food Market 2.The Market for Cars 3.Market.
Perfect Competition CHAPTER 11. What Is Perfect Competition? Perfect competition is an industry in which  Many firms sell identical products to many.
MICROECONOMICS Chapter 3 Demand and Supply
Perfect Competition CHAPTER 11 C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to 1 Explain a perfectly.
Slide 1Copyright © 2004 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited Chapter 16 General Equilibrium and Market Efficiency.
Perfect Competition.
Microeconomics Corso E John Hey. Summary of Chapter 8 The contract curve shows the allocations that are efficient in the sense of Pareto. There always.
Microeconomics Course E John Hey. Examinations Go to Read.
© 2010 Pearson Education Canada Perfect Competition ECON103 Microeconomics Cheryl Fu.
The analytics of constrained optimal decisions microeco nomics spring 2016 the perfectly competitive market ………….1demand and supply curves revisited ………….2.
Microeconomics 2 John Hey. Lecture 26: The Labour Market The supply of labour (consumer: leisure time/money trade-off). The demand for labour (theory.
12 PERFECT COMPETITION. © 2012 Pearson Education.
ECONOMICS FOR BUSINESS (MICROECONOMICS) Lesson 2
Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of markets
C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to Explain a perfectly competitive firm’s profit-
Pure Competition in the Short-Run
Economics September Lecture 14 Chapter 12
Cost-Revenue Analysis Break-Even Points
Presentation transcript:

Microeconomics 2 Answers to the first 17 questions on the Second Specimen Examination Paper (the remaining 10 answers are elsewhere)

Rules of examination Please use the answer sheets attached to the examination paper. Students should not bring their own electronic calculators; standard university electronic calculators will be provided at each desk. To begin with pencil in the answers; at the end, ink them in. There are 27 questions in sets of various sizes. Each set of questions is preceded by a preamble, which remains in force until the next preamble. Four marks are awarded for each correct answer and one mark will be deducted for each wrong answer. The resulting mark, denoted by x will be between -27 and 108. It will then be converted into a final mark for this module y using the formula y = (x+27)/1.35, which ensures that the final mark will lie between 0 and 100. Detail of the examination structure is in the detailed description document on the Module site.detailed description I will put this PowerPoint on the Module site next Monday.

Preamble to and Questions 1 to 4 Consider a market for a hypothetical good in which there are a number of buyers and sellers, each of which wants to buy or sell one unit of the good. There are 6 buyers and their reservation prices are 5, 11, 10, 6, 12 and 7. There are 5 sellers and their reservation prices are 9, 10, 5, 6 and 4. Question 1: What is the maximum surplus realisable in the market? Question 2: What is the maximum number of trades possible (not necessarily with the same price)? Question 3: If the buyers grouped together and chose a single price which maximised their total buyer surplus, what price would they choose (assuming that any seller indifferent between selling and not selling actually sells)? Question 4: If the sellers grouped together and chose a single price which maximised their total seller surplus, what price would they choose (assuming that any buyer indifferent between buying and not buying actually buys)?

Answers to Questions 1 to 4 found by drawing demand and supply ‘curves’ Question 1: 18 Question 2: 5 Question 3: 6 Question 4: 10

Preamble to and Questions 5 and 6 Consider an individual with quasi-linear preferences whose indifference curve between money (on the vertical axis) and the quantity of a DISCRETE good (on the horizontal axis) is as given in Figure 1 attached to this script. Suppose the individual starts with an endowment at the point marked X in the figure. Suppose there is a market in which the DISCRETE good can be sold or bought at a fixed price. Suppose the price at the moment is 32. (You might like to know that the equation of the curve is m = 60/q where m and q are the variables on the vertical and horizontal axes respectively.) Question 5: State whether the individual will be a buyer or a seller and how many units he or she will buy or sell at this price. Question 6: What will the individual's surplus be at this price?

Answers to Questions 5 and 6 Starts at (3,20) (good, money). Price is 32. Cannot buy 2 – not enough money. Cannot buy 1 – not enough money. If does nothing surplus nothing. If sells 1 – moves to (2,52) surplus 22. If sells 2 – moves to (1,84) surplus 24. If sells 3 - ???? Hence sells 2 and has surplus 24.

Preamble to and Questions 7 and 8 Consider an individual with quasi-linear preferences whose indifference curves between money (on the vertical axis) and the quantity of a CONTINUOUS good (on the horizontal axis) are as given in Figure 2 attached to this script. Suppose the individual starts with an endowment at the point marked X in the figure. Suppose there is a market in which the CONTINUOUS good can be sold or bought at a fixed price. Also inserted in the figure are the budget lines for 4 different prices. Suppose the price is such that the individual's optimal decision is to buy 2 units. (You might like to know that the equation of the curve is m = 60/q where m and q are the variables on the vertical and horizontal axes respectively. Question 7: What approximately is the price in the market? Question 8: What approximately is the individual's surplus at this price?

Answers to Questions 7 and 8 If buys two units moves to flattest budget line. This intersects the vertical axis at just over 27. Hence has a slope of –( )/3 = Spends 4.8. So moves from (3,20) to (5,15.2). The original indifference curve m = 60/q passes through (5,12) an hence ends up 3.2 above it. Hence the price is 2.4 and the surplus is 3.2.

Preamble to and Questions 9 and 10 Consider an individual whose preferences are either Perfect Substitutes, Perfect Complements or Cobb-Douglas with parameter a, allocating a given endowment between two goods whose prices are p and 1 respectively. The individual's endowments of the two goods are 15 and 7 respectively. In the first situation the price p of Good 1 was 0.5 and the individual chose to consume 14½ of Good 1 and 7¼ of Good 2. In the second situation the price p of Good 1 was 1 and the individual chose to consume 14⅔ of Good 1 and 7⅓ of Good 2. Question 9: What are the individual's preferences? Question 10: What is the value of the parameter a?

Key results about demands (useful for questions 9 to 12) With Perfect Substitute preferences (with parameter a)......the Individual always spends all his or her income on one of the two goods, unless the price equals the parameter a. (If p>a then q 1 =0; if p<a then q 2 =0) With Perfect Complement preferences (with parameter a)......the ratio of the quantities (q 2 /q 1 ) purchased is always equal to the parameter a. With Cobb-Douglas preferences (with parameter a)......the individual always spends a fraction a of his or her income on Good 1.

Answers to Questions 9 and 10 Are prices different in the two situations? Yes (so?) Is the quantity purchased of either good zero? No – so cannot be Perfect Substitutes. Is the proportion of income spent on Good 1 in the two situations the same?: proportion 14½*½/(14½*½+7¼) =½ in 1; and proportion 14 ⅔ *1/(14 ⅔ *1+7⅓) = ⅔ in 2. No – so cannot be Cobb-Douglas. Is the ratio of quantities (q 2 /q 1 ) the same in the two situations: 7¼/14½ = 1/2 and 7⅓ /14 ⅔ =1/2. Yes - hence Perfect Complements with a=1/2.

Preamble to and Questions 11 and 12 Consider an individual whose preferences are either Perfect Substitutes, Perfect Complements or Cobb-Douglas with parameter a, allocating a given monetary income between two goods whose prices are p and 1 respectively. The individual's endowment of money is 117. In the first situation the price p of Good 1 was 2 and the individual chose to consume 10 of Good 1 and 97 of Good 2. In the second situation the price p of Good 1 was 3 and the individual chose to consume 0 of Good 1 and 117 of Good 2. Question 11: What are the individual's preferences? Question 12: What is the value of the parameter a?

Answers to Questions 11 and 12 Are prices different in the two situations? Yes (so?) Is the quantity purchased of either good zero? Yes – in situation 2 – so it must be Perfect Substitutes. Now notice that in situation 1, the quantity of neither good is zero. Hence in situation 1 the individual must be indifferent between all the points along the budget line (for otherwise would consume zero of some good). To be indifferent, the slope of the budget line in situation 2 must be equal to the slope of the indifference ‘curve’/line. Hence Perfect Substitutes with parameter 2.

Preamble to and Questions 13 to 16 Consider competitive exchange of two goods, Good 1 and Good 2, between two Individuals A and B. A starts with an endowment of 12 units of Good 1 and none of Good 2. B starts with an endowment of 12 units of Good 2 and none of Good 1. Individual A has Perfect Complement Preferences with a parameter 1. Individual B has Cobb-Douglas Preferences with a parameter 0.5. (In answering this question you should note a convention that we use here: in order for a situation to be termed a competitive equilibrium we require that both individuals are STRICTLY better off than with they were with their initial endowments.) Question 13: Determine whether a competitive equilibrium exists, and if so, determine the competitive equilibrium exchange rate. Question 14: If a competitive equilibrium exists, how many units of good 1 are exchanged? Question 15: If a competitive equilibrium exists, how many units of good 2 are exchanged? Question 16: Would dividing EQUALLY the initial endowments of the two goods be an efficient way of finally allocating the two goods to the two individuals?

The simplest way is with an Edgeworth Box Draw in the price-offer curves. For PC it is easy. For PS it would help to draw in the indifference curves. For CD make use of the fact that A has all of Good 1 and B all of Good 2. Here B wants to keep 1/2 of his/her Good 2. If the price-offer curves intersect inside the box at a point where both are better off then that is the competitive equilibrium. If not, not.

Answers to Questions 13 to 16 The competive exchange is at (6,6). The price line from the endowment point (12,12) to (6,6) has slope 1. The competitive exchange rate is therefore 1 for 1. A gives up 6 of Good 1 for 6 of Good 2 B gives up 6 of Good 2 for 6 of Good 1 Diving equally at point (6,6) is efficient. So answers are: 1 for 1; 6; 6; Yes

Preamble to and Question 17 Consider a perfectly competitive firm with a quadratic cost function C(q) = a + bq + cq 2 where the parameters a, b and c are given below (note that the firm has to incur its fixed cost a whether it produces any output or not). Suppose that the given price for its output is 11. The value of a is 18, the value of b is 3, and the value of c is 1. Question 17: What is its profit maximising (loss minimising) output?

Answer to Question 17 The cost function is C(q) = q + q 2 Hence Marginal Cost MC = 3 + 2q The profit-maximising condition for a competitive (price-taking) firm is price = MC The price = 11. The condition implies 11 = 3 + 2q So q = 4 and, incidentally, Profit =11*4 – (18 +3*4+4 2 )= -2

That is the end of the answers to the first 17 questions on the second specimen examination paper Go slow – there is plenty of time. The questions are easy if you understand microeconomics. They are difficult if you do not. You cannot memorise answers. You may want to memorise methods - but that is exactly what I have been trying to teach you. Obviously this is a specimen – do look at the document detailed description on the site.detailed description