Bad Email Addresses toluwo1@student.gsu.edu bluepenny65@hotmail.com atlantacdshop@excite.com tedie0@aol.com See me if one of these belongs to you!
Describing Supply and Demand: Elasticities Chapter 6
Classifying Demand and Supply as to their relative responsiveness to price changes: Elasticity It is helpful to describe the relative responsiveness of consumers and suppliers to price changes. For example, after a large price increase there may be a large or small drop in the quantity demanded. We call this relative responsiveness to price changes the elasticity of demand or supply.
Responsiveness of Demand Here we have two different demand curves Responsiveness of Demand Here we have two different demand curves. Let’s pretend that they possibly represent the demand behavior of consumers in the antacid market. The problem is that we don’t which curve is the real demand curve. If the real curve is DA then raising the price from P1 to P2 will cause quantity demanded to drop from QA,1 to QA,2. However, if the real curve is DB then demand falls from QB,1 to QB,2 Q P Price P2 DA DB P1 QB,2 QA,2 QB,1 QA,1 Quantity Demanded
Responsiveness of Supply Here we have two different supply curves Responsiveness of Supply Here we have two different supply curves. Let’s pretend that they possibly represent the supply curves of your firm in the antacid market. The problem is that you don’t which curve is the real supply curve. If the real curve is SA then raising the price from P1 to P2 will cause quantity supplied to rise from QA,1 to QA,2. However, if the real curve is SB then demand falls from QB,1 to QB,2. Think what happens to profits if you get it wrong. Either your costs rise faster than your revenues or your revenues do not expand due to increased opportunity. Q P Price P2 SA SB P1 QB,1 QA,2 QA,1 QA,2 Quantity Demanded
Elasticity: Definition Elasticity is defined as the percentage change in Quantity Demanded or Supplied relative to a percentage change in Price. We usually “normalize” the change in price to a 1% increase. The change in Quantity Demanded or Supplied as being less than 1%, 1% also, or more than 1%.
Price Elasticity: Formula The formula for computing an elasticity is to divide the percentage change in price by the percentage change in quantity demanded or supplied:
Elastic Demand and Supply For elastic points on curves, the percentage change in quantity is greater than the percentage change in price. E > 1
Elastic Demand and Supply Common sense tells us that an elastic supply means that quantity changes by a greater percentage than the percentage change in price. The same holds true for demand.
Inelastic Demand and Supply For inelastic points on curves, the percentage change in quantity is less than the percentage change in price. E < 1
Inelastic Demand and Supply Common sense tells us that an inelastic supply means that quantity doesn't change much with a change in price. The same holds true for demand.
What Information Price Elasticity Provides Price elasticity gives of demand and supply gives information about the exact quantity response to a price change. As elasticity increases, responsiveness of quantity to price also increases.
Elasticity Is Independent of Units Percentages allow us to have a measure of responsiveness that is independent of units.
Elasticity Is Independent of Units Having a measure of responsiveness that is independent of units makes comparisons of responsiveness of different goods easier.
Calculating Elasticities To determine elasticity divide the percentage change in quantity by the percentage change in price.
The End-Point Problem The end-point problem is that the percentage change differs depending on whether you view the change as a rise or a decline in price.
The Arc Convention Economists use the arc convention to get around the end-point problem. The arc elasticity method entails the calculating the percentage change at the midpoint of the range.
The Arc Convention Using the arc convention, the average of the two end points are used as the starting point when calculating percentage change.
Graphs of Elasticities Price Quantity of software (in hundred thousands) $26 24 22 20 18 16 14 D B A 10 12 C (midpoint) Elasticity of demand = 1.3
Graphs of Elasticities Wage per hour Quantity of workers $6.00 5.50 5.00 4.50 4.00 3.50 3.00 C B A 470 (midpoint) 480 490 Elasticity of supply = 0.18
Graphs of Elasticities $10 B 9 E = 4 8 A 7 6 Price C 5 E = 0.54 4 F 3 E = 0.67 2 D E 1 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 Quantity (c) Some e xamples
Calculating Elasticity at a Point Let us now turn to a method of calculating the elasticity at a specific point, rather than over a range or an arc.
Calculating Elasticity at a Point To calculate elasticity at a point, determine a range around that point and calculate the arc elasticity.
Calculating Elasticity at a Point Price Quantity $10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 C B A 24 40 28 20
Calculating Elasticity at a Point $10 Demand 9 Supply EA = 2.33 8 A 7 6 D Price 5 ED = 0.86 4 3 C EB = 0.11 EC = 0.75 2 B 1 6 12 18 24 30 36 42 48 54 60 Quantity
Elasticity and Supply and Demand Curves Two important points to consider: Elasticity is related (but is not the same as) slope. Elasticity changes along straight-line demand and supply curves.
Elasticity Is Not the Same as Slope The relationship between elasticity and slope means that the steeper the curve begins at a given point, the less elastic is supply or demand.
Elasticity Is Not the Same as Slope There are two limiting examples of this.
Elasticity Is Not the Same as Slope When the curves are flat, we call the curves perfectly elastic. Perfectly elastic curves are flat curves in which quantity changes enormously in response to a proportional change in price (E = ¥).
Elasticity Is Not the Same as Slope When the curves are vertical, we call the curves perfectly inelastic. Perfectly inelastic curves are vertical curves in which quantity does not change at all in response to an enormous proportional change in price (E = 0).
Perfectly Inelastic Demand Curve Price Quantity Perfectly inelastic demand curve
Perfectly Elastic Demand Curve Price Quantity Perfectly inelastic demand curve
Elasticity Changes Along Straight-Line Curves Elasticity is not the same as slope. Elasticity changes along the straight line supply and demand curves—slope does not.
Elasticity Changes Along Straight-Line Curves On a demand curve, elasticity is perfectly elastic (E = ¥) at the price intercept. It becomes smaller as you move down the demand curve until it becomes zero at the quantity intercept.
Elasticity Changes Along Straight-Line Curves Elasticity is perfectly elastic (E = ¥) where a straight line supply curve intercepts the price axis. Points become less elastic as you move out along the supply curve.
Elasticity Along a Demand Curve Ed = $10 Elasticity declines along demand curve as one moves toward the quantity axis 9 8 Ed > 1 7 6 Ed = 1 Price 5 4 3 Ed < 1 2 1 Ed = 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Quantity
Elasticity Along a Supply Curve $10 9 Es declines 8 7 Es rises 6 Es = Price 5 4 3 2 Es = 0 1 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Quantity
Elasticity Review Perfectly elastic – quantity responds enormously to price changes (E = ). Elastic – the percentage change in quantity exceeds the percentage change in price (E >1).
Elasticity Review Unit elastic – the percentage change in quantity is the same as the percentage change in price (E = 1).
Elasticity Review Inelastic – the percentage change in quantity is less than the percentage change in price (E <1). Perfectly inelastic – quantity does not respond at all to price changes (E = 0).
Substitution and Elasticity As a general rule, the more substitutes a good has, the more elastic is its supply and demand.
Substitution and Elasticity Factors that affect a good’s substitutability of demand differ from factors that affect a good’s substitutability of supply.
Substitution and Demand The larger the time interval considered, or the longer the run, the more elastic is the good’s demand curve. There are more substitutes in the long run than in the short run. The long run provides more options for change.
Substitution and Demand The less a good is a necessity, the more elastic its demand curve. Necessities tend to have fewer substitutes than do luxuries.
Substitution and Demand As the definition of a good becomes more specific, demand becomes more elastic. If the good is broadly defined—say, transportation—there are not many substitutes and demand will be inelastic.
Substitution and Demand As the definition of a good becomes more specific, demand becomes more elastic. If the definition of a good is narrowed—say to transportation by bus—there are more substitutes.
Substitution and Demand Demand for goods that represent a large proportion of one's budget are more elastic than demand for goods that represent a small proportion of one's budget.
Substitution and Demand Goods that cost very little relative to your total expenditures are not worth spending a lot of time figuring out if there is a good substitute. It is worth spending a lot of time looking for substitutes for goods that take a large portion of one’s income.
Substitution and Supply The longer the time period considered, the more elastic the supply.
Substitution and Supply The reasoning is the same as for demand. In the long run there are more options for change so it is easier (less costly) for suppliers to change into the production of another good.
Substitution and Supply Economists distinguish three time periods relevant to supply: The instantaneous period. The short run. The long run.
Substitution and Supply In the instantaneous period, quantity supplied is fixed so the elasticity of supply is perfectly inelastic. This supply is sometimes called the momentary supply.
Substitution and Supply In the short run, some substitution is possible, so the short-run supply curve is somewhat elastic.
Substitution and Supply In the long run, significant substitution is possible; the supply curve becomes very elastic.
Substitution and Supply An additional factor to consider: Many goods are produced, so we must take into account how easy it is to substitute for existing goods by producing more of those same goods.
How Substitution Factors Affect Specific Decisions Suppose you’ve been asked to evaluate the potential impact of a 10¢ gas tax increase in Washington, D.C. and in the nation.
Impact of a 10¢ Gas Tax Increase In the short run the demand curve for gasoline would be less elastic than in the long run. In the long run, motorists would switch to fuel efficient cars.
Impact of a 10¢ Gas Tax Increase Although gasoline is considered a necessity, it is only a small part of what it costs to drive, demand would probably be inelastic.
Impact of a 10¢ Gas Tax Increase For the entire U.S., demand would be inelastic, but for Washington, it would be very elastic since there are many alternative choices of transportation.
Impact of a 10¢ Gas Tax Increase Some may switch to an alternative form of transportation. Others would go to neighboring states to buy gasoline.
Impact of a 10¢ Gas Tax Increase Smaller geographic areas have more elastic demands. This limits how highly state and local governments can tax goods relative to their neighboring localities or states.
Empirical Estimates of Elasticities The following table provides short- and long-term estimates of elasticities for a number of goods.
Empirical Estimates of Elasticities These demand estimates are for the entire U.S. If they were for specific regions or cities, the examples would show greater elasticity.
Empirical Estimates of Elasticities
Empirical Estimates of Elasticities There are many fewer empirical measurements of elasticity of supply than there are of demand.
Empirical Estimates of Elasticities One does find empirical measurements of elasticity of supply in factor markets, such as the market for labor services.
Empirical Estimates of Elasticities Other areas in which elasticities of supply are estimated are agricultural and raw materials markets. In these markets, economists have generally found that the short-run supplies are highly inelastic, and that the long-run supplies are highly elastic.
Elasticity, Total Revenue, and Demand Knowing the elasticity of demand tells suppliers how their total revenue will change if their price changes. Total revenue equals total quantity sold multiplied by price of good.
Elasticity, Total Revenue, and Demand If ED is elastic (ED > 1), a rise in price lowers total revenue. Price and total revenue move in opposite directions.
Elasticity, Total Revenue, and Demand If ED is unit elastic (ED = 1), a rise in price leaves total revenue unchanged.
Elasticity, Total Revenue, and Demand If ED is inelastic (ED < 1), a rise in price increases total revenue. Price and total revenue move in the same direction.
Elasticity and Total Revenue (a) Unit Elastic Demand E = 1 6 Price Quantity $10 8 4 2 1 3 5 7 9 TR constant F Gained revenue C E Lost revenue A B
Elasticity and Total Revenue (b) Inelastic Demand E < 1 $10 TR rises 8 6 Price Gained revenue Lost revenue 4 H 2 G C A B 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Quantity
Elasticity and Total Revenue (c) Elastic Demand E = 1 $10 K J C TR falls 8 Gained revenue A B 6 Price 4 Lost revenue 2 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Quantity
Total Revenue Along a Demand Curve ED is elastic at prices above the point where demand is unit elastic – a rise in price lowers total revenue. If ED is inelastic at prices below the point where demand is unit elastic – a rise in price increases total revenue.
How Total Revenue Changes Along a Demand Curve Elastic range ED > 1 ED = 1 Price Total revenue Inelastic range ED < 1 Q0 Quantity Q0 Quantity (a) (b)
Elasticity of Individual and Market Demand Market demand elasticity is influenced both by: Many people drop out totally when price increases. How much an existing consumer marginally changes his or her quantity demanded.
Elasticity of Individual and Market Demand Price discrimination occurs when a firm separates the people with less elastic demand from those with more elastic demand.
Elasticity of Individual and Market Demand Firms that price discriminate can charge more to the individuals with inelastic demand and less to individuals with elastic demands.
Elasticity of Individual and Market Demand Examples of price discrimination include: Airlines’ Saturday stay-over specials. The phenomenon of selling new cars. The almost-continual-sale phenomenon.
Other Elasticity Concepts Other elasticities can be useful in specifying the effects of a shift factor of demand: Income elasticity of demand. Cross-price elasticity of demand.
Income Elasticity of Demand Income elasticity of demand is defined as the percentage change in demand divided by the percentage change in income.
Income Elasticity of Demand Income elasticity of demand tells us the responsiveness of demand to changes in income.
Income Elasticity of Demand An increase in income generally increases one’s consumption of almost all goods, although the increase may be greater for some goods than for others.
Income Elasticity of Demand Normal goods are those whose consumption increases with an increase in income. They have income elasticities greater than zero.
Income Elasticity of Demand Normal goods are divided into luxuries and necessities.
Income Elasticity of Demand Luxuries are goods that have an income elasticity greater than one. Their percentage increase in demand is greater than the percentage increase in income.
Income Elasticity of Demand Shoes are a necessity—a good that has an income elasticity less than 1. The consumption of a necessity rises by a smaller proportion than the rise in income.
Income Elasticity of Demand Inferior goods are those whose consumption decreases when income increases. Inferior goods have income elasticities less than zero. Dried milk is an example of an inferior good.
Income Elasticities of Selected Goods
Cross-Price Elasticity of Demand Cross-price elasticity of demand is defined as the percentage change in demand divided by the percentage change in the price of another good.
Cross-Price Elasticity of Demand Cross-price elasticity of demand tells us the responsiveness of demand to changes in prices of other goods.
Complements and Substitutes Substitutes are goods that can be used in place of another. When the price of a good goes up, the demand for the substitute good also goes up.
Complements and Substitutes Complements are goods that are used in conjunction with other goods. A fall in the price of a good will increase the demand for its complement. The cross-price elasticity of complements is negative.
Cross-Price Elasticities
Shift due to 20% rise in income Some Examples P0 D0 D1 20 Quantity 26 Shift due to 20% rise in income
Some Examples S0 P0 S1 104 Quantity 108 Shift due to 33% rise in price of pork
The Power of Supply and Demand Analysis A number of questions may be answered by combining supply and demand analysis with elasticity.
When Should a Supplier Raise Price? The supplier should raise his price when it faces an inelastic demand. Total revenue increases with a price increase because quantity drops proportionally less than price goes up. Since costs also fall, profit rise.
When Should a Supplier Raise Price? When you have an elastic demand, you should hesitate to increase price.
Elasticity and Shifting Supply and Demand Elasticity can tell us more exactly the effect of shifting supply and demand.
Elasticity and Shifting Supply and Demand The more elastic the demand, the greater the effect of a supply shift on quantity, and the smaller effect on price.
Elasticity and Shifting Supply and Demand The more elastic the supply, the greater the effect of a demand shift on quantity, and the smaller the effect on price.
Effects of Shifts in Supply on Price and Quantity Inelastic Supply and Inelastic Demand P0 P1 Demand Price Quantity S0 S1 Q0 Q1
Effects of Shifts in Supply on Price and Quantity Inelastic Supply and Elastic Demand Demand S0 S1 Price P0 P1 Q0 Q1 Quantity
Describing Supply and Demand: Elasticities End of Chapter 6