SLOPE DUMMY VARIABLES 1 The scatter diagram shows the data for the 74 schools in Shanghai and the cost functions derived from a regression of COST on N and a dummy variable for the type of curriculum (occupational / regular). N occupational school regular school COST
2 The specification of the model incorporates the assumption that the marginal cost per student is the same for occupational and regular schools. Hence the cost functions are parallel. SLOPE DUMMY VARIABLES N occupational school regular school COST
3 However, this is not a realistic assumption. Occupational schools incur expenditure on training materials that is related to the number of students. SLOPE DUMMY VARIABLES N occupational school regular school COST
4 Also, the staff-student ratio has to be higher in occupational schools because workshop groups cannot be, or at least should not be, as large as academic classes. SLOPE DUMMY VARIABLES N occupational school regular school COST
5 Looking at the scatter diagram, you can see that the cost function for the occupational schools should be steeper, and that for the regular schools should be flatter. SLOPE DUMMY VARIABLES N occupational school regular school COST
6 We will relax the assumption of the same marginal cost by introducing what is known as a slope dummy variable. This is NOCC, defined as the product of N and OCC. SLOPE DUMMY VARIABLES COST = 1 + OCC + 2 N + NOCC + u
7 In the case of a regular school, OCC is 0 and hence so also is NOCC. The model reduces to its basic components. SLOPE DUMMY VARIABLES Regular school (OCC = NOCC = 0) COST = 1 + OCC + 2 N + NOCC + u COST = 1 + 2 N + u
In the case of an occupational school, OCC is equal to 1 and NOCC is equal to N. The equation simplifies as shown. 8 SLOPE DUMMY VARIABLES Regular school (OCC = NOCC = 0) COST = 1 + OCC + 2 N + NOCC + u COST = 1 + 2 N + u COST = ( 1 + ) + ( 2 + )N + u Occupational school (OCC = 1; NOCC = N)
The model now allows the marginal cost per student to be an amount greater than that in regular schools, as well as allowing the overhead costs to be different. 9 SLOPE DUMMY VARIABLES Regular school (OCC = NOCC = 0) COST = 1 + OCC + 2 N + NOCC + u Occupational school (OCC = 1; NOCC = N) COST = 1 + 2 N + u COST = ( 1 + ) + ( 2 + )N + u
N 1 + 11 Occupational Regular The diagram illustrates the model graphically. 10 SLOPE DUMMY VARIABLES COST
Here are the data for the first ten schools. Note the weird way in which NOCC is defined. 11 School TypeCOST N OCC NOCC 1Occupational345, Occupational 537, Regular 170, Occupational Regular100, Regular 28, Regular 160, Occupational 45, Occupational 120, Occupational61, SLOPE DUMMY VARIABLES
. reg COST N OCC NOCC Source | SS df MS Number of obs = F( 3, 70) = Model | e e+11 Prob > F = Residual | e e+09 R-squared = Adj R-squared = Total | e e+10 Root MSE = COST | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval] N | OCC | NOCC | _cons | Weird or not, the procedure works very well. Here is the regression output using the full sample of 74 schools. We will begin by interpreting the regression coefficients. 12 SLOPE DUMMY VARIABLES
Here is the regression in equation form. 13 SLOPE DUMMY VARIABLES COST = 51,000 – 4,000OCC + 152N + 284NOCC ^
Putting OCC, and hence NOCC, equal to 0, we get the cost function for regular schools. We estimate that their annual overhead costs are 51,000 yuan and their annual marginal cost per student is 152 yuan. 14 SLOPE DUMMY VARIABLES Regular school (OCC = NOCC = 0) COST = 51,000 – 4,000OCC + 152N + 284NOCC COST = 51, N ^ ^
Putting OCC equal to 1, and hence NOCC equal to N, we estimate that the annual overhead costs of the occupational schools are 47,000 yuan and the annual marginal cost per student is 436 yuan. 15 SLOPE DUMMY VARIABLES Regular school (OCC = NOCC = 0) COST = 51,000 – 4,000OCC + 152N + 284NOCC COST = 51, N COST = 51,000 – 4, N + 284N = 47, N ^ ^ ^ Occupational school (OCC = 1; NOCC = N)
You can see that the cost functions fit the data much better than before and that the real difference is in the marginal cost, not the overhead cost. 16 SLOPE DUMMY VARIABLES COST occupational school regular school N
Now we can see why we had a nonsensical negative estimate of the overhead cost of a regular school in previous specifications. 17 SLOPE DUMMY VARIABLES COST occupational school regular school N
The assumption of the same marginal cost led to an estimate of the marginal cost that was a compromise between the marginal costs of occupational and regular schools. 18 SLOPE DUMMY VARIABLES COST occupational school regular school N
The cost function for regular schools was too steep and as a consequence the intercept was underestimated, actually becoming negative and indicating that something must be wrong with the specification of the model. 19 SLOPE DUMMY VARIABLES COST occupational school regular school N
We can perform t tests as usual. The t statistic for the coefficient of NOCC is 3.76, so the marginal cost per student in an occupational school is significantly higher than that in a regular school. 20. reg COST N OCC NOCC Source | SS df MS Number of obs = F( 3, 70) = Model | e e+11 Prob > F = Residual | e e+09 R-squared = Adj R-squared = Total | e e+10 Root MSE = COST | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval] N | OCC | NOCC | _cons | SLOPE DUMMY VARIABLES
The coefficient of OCC is now negative, suggesting that the overhead costs of occupational schools are actually lower than those of regular schools. 21 SLOPE DUMMY VARIABLES. reg COST N OCC NOCC Source | SS df MS Number of obs = F( 3, 70) = Model | e e+11 Prob > F = Residual | e e+09 R-squared = Adj R-squared = Total | e e+10 Root MSE = COST | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval] N | OCC | NOCC | _cons |
This is unlikely. However, the t statistic is only -0.09, so we do not reject the null hypothesis that the overhead costs of the two types of school are the same. 22 SLOPE DUMMY VARIABLES. reg COST N OCC NOCC Source | SS df MS Number of obs = F( 3, 70) = Model | e e+11 Prob > F = Residual | e e+09 R-squared = Adj R-squared = Total | e e+10 Root MSE = COST | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval] N | OCC | NOCC | _cons |
We can also perform an F test of the joint explanatory power of the dummy variables, comparing RSS when the dummy variables are included with RSS when they are not. 23 SLOPE DUMMY VARIABLES. reg COST N OCC NOCC Source | SS df MS Number of obs = F( 3, 70) = Model | e e+11 Prob > F = Residual | e e+09 R-squared = Adj R-squared = Total | e e+10 Root MSE = reg COST N Source | SS df MS Number of obs = F( 1, 72) = Model | e e+11 Prob > F = Residual | e e+10 R-squared = Adj R-squared = Total | e e+10 Root MSE = 1.1e
The null hypothesis is that the coefficients of OCC and NOCC are both equal to 0. The alternative hypothesis is that one or both are nonzero. 24 SLOPE DUMMY VARIABLES. reg COST N OCC NOCC Source | SS df MS Number of obs = F( 3, 70) = Model | e e+11 Prob > F = Residual | e e+09 R-squared = Adj R-squared = Total | e e+10 Root MSE = reg COST N Source | SS df MS Number of obs = F( 1, 72) = Model | e e+11 Prob > F = Residual | e e+10 R-squared = Adj R-squared = Total | e e+10 Root MSE = 1.1e
The improvement in the fit on adding the dummy variables is the reduction in RSS. 25 SLOPE DUMMY VARIABLES. reg COST N OCC NOCC Source | SS df MS Number of obs = F( 3, 70) = Model | e e+11 Prob > F = Residual | e e+09 R-squared = Adj R-squared = Total | e e+10 Root MSE = reg COST N Source | SS df MS Number of obs = F( 1, 72) = Model | e e+11 Prob > F = Residual | e e+10 R-squared = Adj R-squared = Total | e e+10 Root MSE = 1.1e
The cost is 2 because 2 extra parameters, the coefficients of the dummy variables, have been estimated, and as a consequence the number of degrees of freedom remaining has been reduced from 72 to SLOPE DUMMY VARIABLES. reg COST N OCC NOCC Source | SS df MS Number of obs = F( 3, 70) = Model | e e+11 Prob > F = Residual | e e+09 R-squared = Adj R-squared = Total | e e+10 Root MSE = reg COST N Source | SS df MS Number of obs = F( 1, 72) = Model | e e+11 Prob > F = Residual | e e+10 R-squared = Adj R-squared = Total | e e+10 Root MSE = 1.1e
The first component of the denominator is RSS after the dummies have been added. 27 SLOPE DUMMY VARIABLES. reg COST N OCC NOCC Source | SS df MS Number of obs = F( 3, 70) = Model | e e+11 Prob > F = Residual | e e+09 R-squared = Adj R-squared = Total | e e+10 Root MSE = reg COST N Source | SS df MS Number of obs = F( 1, 72) = Model | e e+11 Prob > F = Residual | e e+10 R-squared = Adj R-squared = Total | e e+10 Root MSE = 1.1e
The denominator is RSS after the dummies have been added, divided by the number of degrees of freedom remaining. This is 70 because there are 74 observations and 4 parameters have been estimated. 28 SLOPE DUMMY VARIABLES. reg COST N OCC NOCC Source | SS df MS Number of obs = F( 3, 70) = Model | e e+11 Prob > F = Residual | e e+09 R-squared = Adj R-squared = Total | e e+10 Root MSE = reg COST N Source | SS df MS Number of obs = F( 1, 72) = Model | e e+11 Prob > F = Residual | e e+10 R-squared = Adj R-squared = Total | e e+10 Root MSE = 1.1e
The F statistic is therefore The critical vale of F(2,70) at the 0.1 percent level is SLOPE DUMMY VARIABLES. reg COST N OCC NOCC Source | SS df MS Number of obs = F( 3, 70) = Model | e e+11 Prob > F = Residual | e e+09 R-squared = Adj R-squared = Total | e e+10 Root MSE = reg COST N Source | SS df MS Number of obs = F( 1, 72) = Model | e e+11 Prob > F = Residual | e e+10 R-squared = Adj R-squared = Total | e e+10 Root MSE = 1.1e
Thus we conclude that at least one of the dummy variable coefficients is different from 0. We knew this already from the t tests, so in this case the F test does not actually add anything. 30 SLOPE DUMMY VARIABLES. reg COST N OCC NOCC Source | SS df MS Number of obs = F( 3, 70) = Model | e e+11 Prob > F = Residual | e e+09 R-squared = Adj R-squared = Total | e e+10 Root MSE = reg COST N Source | SS df MS Number of obs = F( 1, 72) = Model | e e+11 Prob > F = Residual | e e+10 R-squared = Adj R-squared = Total | e e+10 Root MSE = 1.1e
Copyright Christopher Dougherty These slideshows may be downloaded by anyone, anywhere for personal use. Subject to respect for copyright and, where appropriate, attribution, they may be used as a resource for teaching an econometrics course. There is no need to refer to the author. The content of this slideshow comes from Section 5.3 of C. Dougherty, Introduction to Econometrics, fourth edition 2011, Oxford University Press. Additional (free) resources for both students and instructors may be downloaded from the OUP Online Resource Centre Individuals studying econometrics on their own who feel that they might benefit from participation in a formal course should consider the London School of Economics summer school course EC212 Introduction to Econometrics or the University of London International Programmes distance learning course EC2020 Elements of Econometrics