ABSOLUTEADVANTAGE THEORY NUMBER OF LABOR HOURS NEEDED TO PRODUCE ONE UNIT OF SOYBEANSTEXTILES U.S.51520 ENGLAND20525.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
International Economics Dr Doaa Akl Ahmed MSc and PhD in Economics University of Leicester - England.
Advertisements

1 Ricardian Model INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, ECO 486 JDE notes to supplement the text. David Ricardo April 18, 1772 — September 11, 1823.
Chapter 3 Comparative Advantage Link to syllabus Questionable example on page 36.
International Trade Models Mercantilism; The Classical Theories: –The Principle of Absolute Advantage –The Principle of Comparative Advantage The Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson.
The Classical World of David Ricardo and Comparative Advantage
Supplementary notes Chapter 3. Unit Labor Requirements CWLabor supply Home12120 Foreign63240.
International Factor Movements
International Trade and Comparative Advantage
1 of 62 Copyright © 2011 Worth Publishers· International Economics· Feenstra/Taylor, 2/e. Chapter 2: Trade and Technology: The Ricardian Model Trade and.
The Origins of Trade Theory Professor Bryson Marriott School.
The Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson Theorem
The Origins of Trade Theory Professor Bryson Marriott School.
The Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson Theorem
International Trade Models Mercantilism; The Classical Theories: –The Principle of Absolute Advantage –The Principle of Comparative Advantage The Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson.
The Classical Model of International Trade
Foundations of Modern Trade Theory: Comparative Advantage
Factor Endowments and the Heckscher-Ohlin Theory
Economics Theories of International Trade
Classical Theories of International Trade
Chapter Two: The Law of Comparative Advantage
Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage:
Basic Economic Concepts for Understanding the Value of Trade
Chapter 2 Comparative Advantage Theory 1. David Ricardo David Ricardo 2. Ricardo’s Model Ricardo’s Model 3. Summary Summary.
Chapter II: Comparative Advantage_David Ricado Lectured by: Mr. SOK Chanrithy.
Session 3 Why Everybody Trades: Comparative Advantage.
The Gains from Trade: A General Equilibrium View Between a good and a bad economist this constitutes the whole difference–the one takes account of the.
International Trade Classical Trade Theory and Comparative Advantage.
New Classical Theories of International Trade
Economic Theories David Ricardo Comparative Advantage
Chapter 2 Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage: The Ricardian Model International Economics: Theory and Policy International Economics: Theory.
Chapter Two: The Law of Comparative Advantage. 2.2 The Mercantilists’ View on Trade  In the 17 th century a group of men (merchants, bankers, government.
Trade Theories and Economic Development
The Classical Model of International Trade
Comparative Advantage and Trade Chapter 3. 2 countries; A and B Comparative advantage (technology differences) David Ricardo; International trade based.
International Trade Theory (Ch-4) Chapter Outline 1.Introduction 2.Various trade theories  Mercantilism  Theory of Absolute Advantage  Theory of Comparative.
Why Everybody Trades: Comparative Advantage
Chapter Five International Trade Theory McGraw-Hill/Irwin International Business, 6/e © 2007 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., All Rights Reserved.
Chapter 3 In this chapter we are going to study, using Classical theory of international trade, how and why nations trade.
International Trade and Finance for Global Logistics MAGL 570 Fall 2010 Steven Yamarik
The Classical Theory of International Trade ……. The Classical Theory of International Trade Adam Smith; John Stuart Mills; James Torrens; David Ricardo.
Ricardian Model A lesson in Comparative Advantage.
1 Chapter 3 -- Classical Model INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, ECO 486 Display your name card.
International Economics
International Economics
The Classical World of David Ricardo and Comparative Advantage Copyright © 2010 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 4 Resources, Comparative Advantage, and Income Distribution.
Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 3 Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage:
International Trade Theory The Law of Comparative Advantage MC 2009.
Chapter 2 Trade Theories and Economic Development.
Lecture 2 : The law of Comparative Advantage Summary: 1.This chapter examined the development of trade theory from the mercantilists to Smith, Ricardo,
International Trade MGMT 418 Komeil Shaeri. Chapter 3 The Classical World of David Ricardo and Comparative Advantage The Principles of Political Economy.
International Trade Theory Overview of Trade Theory Free Trade occurs when a government does not attempt to influence, through quotas or duties,
Mgmt. 418 Assoc. Prof. Dr. Şule Lokmanoğlu Aker
International Economics Tenth Edition
International Economics Eleventh Edition
Mercantilists and the Classical theorists
International Trade Theory
International Trade Theory
International Economics Tenth Edition
Economics and Development International trade
Factor Endowments Theory and Heckscher-Ohlin Model
L2 classical trade theory
International Economics By Robert J. Carbaugh 9th Edition
Classic Theories of International Trade
Chapter 2: The law of comparative advantage
International Economics By Robert J. Carbaugh 9th Edition
The Classical World of David Ricardo and Comparative Advantage
Comparative advantage theory of international trade
International Trade Models
Presentation transcript:

ABSOLUTEADVANTAGE THEORY NUMBER OF LABOR HOURS NEEDED TO PRODUCE ONE UNIT OF SOYBEANSTEXTILES U.S ENGLAND20525

ABSOLUTEADVANTAGE THEORY NUMBER OF LABOR HOURS NEEDED TO PRODUCE ONE UNIT OF SOYBEANSEXTILES U.S.515 ENGLAND205 relative prices (domestic Terms Of Trade, TOT, before international Trade): In U.S.[5/15] or 1 T= 3 S In England[20/5] or 4 T = 1 S

ABSOLUTEADVANTAGE THEORY Production Before International Trade (Autarky) Soybeans Textiles Total U.S.112 England112 Total224

ABSOLUTEADVANTAGE THEORY Allocation of Labor after specialization SOYBEANSTEXTILES U.S.200 ENGLAND025

ABSOLUTEADVANTAGE THEORY Production After Specialization SoybeansTextiles Total U.S.40 4 England05 5 Total 9

ABSOLUTEADVANTAGE THEORY Assume that term of trade is established to be one to one Consumption After International Trade SoybeansTextilesTotal U.S.31 4 England Chapter 3 In this chapter we are going to study, using Classical theory of international trade, how and why nations trade. Classical Theory is useful because: 1-- The theory is applicable to today's world in the sense that it explains why and how trade is beneficial to all 2-- The theory explains why and how a high cost (wage) country like U.S. could export to a low cost (wage) country like Mexico. 3-- The theory shows why specialization in necessary. Classical theory of international trade covers: --- absolute advantage theory of Adam Smith --- Comparative advantage theory of David Ricardo Some argue that Robert Thorrens had first discovered the Comparative Advantage theory in New Assumptions in addition to those made in chapter Factors of production are not mobile among countries. 9-- There are no barriers to trade. 10- Imports are paid by exports. Balance of trade and no borrowing. 11- Labor is the only factor of production in terms of productivity analysis and cost of production. 12- Production exhibits constant return to scale. This Assumption means a technological relationship which shows a change in inputs will lead to a proportional change in output. Absolute Advantage : Adam Smith Wealth of Nations, 1776 His theory of international trade was very simple and was based on the principle of: -- self interest -- specialization -- competition all of which lead to one thing, the absolute advantage. Even though he started with the example of a pin factory in which workers cooperate and specialize to make pins, he argued that this is applicable to international trade as well. He argued that if all countries specialize they can increase production of whatever they were producing and sell the extra to other countries. This is a result of the generalization of the division of labor which he explained for the domestic production; the pin factory. ABSOLUTE ADVANTAGE THEORY NUMBER OF LABOR HOURS NEEDED TO PRODUCE ONE UNIT OF SOYBEANS TEXTILES U.S.5 15 ENGLAND20 5 relative prices (domestic TOT before international Trade) U.S.[5/15] or 1 T= 3 S England[20/5] or 4 T = I S Production Before International Trade SoybeansTextiles Total U.S.1 12 England In this case it is obvious that the U.S. must specialize in the production of soybeans and England in the production of textiles. This is because each can produce it cheaper. Allocation of Labor after specialization SOYBEANS TEXTILES US20 0 ENGLAND0 25 Production After Specialization SoybeansTextiles US40 England05 Assume that term of trade is established to be one to one Consumption After International Trade SoybeansTextiles Total US31 4 England In other words, both countries could specialize and produce more and trade some and consume more. Assuming international terms of trade (TOT) is one to one, US could exchange one unit of Soybeans for one unit of Textile and keep the rest of the soybeans for domestic use. Comparative Advantage What if one country has absolute advantage in the production of both commodities ? NUMBER OF LABOR HOURS NEEDED TO PRODUCE ONE UNIT OF SOYBEANS TEXTILES USa ls = 5 a lt = 15 ENGLANDa' ls =10 a' lt = 20 relative prices Before international Trade U.S. 1 T / 3 S England 1 T / 2 S Production Before International Trade SoybeansTextiles Total U.S.1 12 England Comparative Advantage U.S. advantage over England are: Soybeans5/10 = 1/2 = 3/6 Textiles 15/20 = 3/4 U.S. has a higher advantage in both S and T. But US's advantage is higher in S. This is because there is a relatively smaller labor requirement for the production of S than for the production of T. So, even though the united States has an absolute advantage in the production of S and T, there is a higher advantage in the production of S. Therefore US must specialize in the production of S and England must specialize in the production of T in which she has a smaller disadvantage. Graphical Analysis of Comparative Advantage Assuming that the US has 1500 hours of labor endowment and England has 1000 hours of labor endowment available. Then the internal, pre-trade PPC, and consumption possibility frontier of each country could be represented as follows: Algebra of Comparative Advantage U.S. Let L = the country's labor supply a ls = labor needed for one unit of soybeans. a lt = " " " " " " textiles England L' = the country's labor supply a' ls = labor needed for one unit of soybeans. a' lt = " " " " " " textiles If a ls < a' ls (absolute advantage) means that home labor is more efficient in the production of soybeans than foreign labor. If a lt < a' lt (absolute advantage) means that home labor is more efficient in the production of textiles than foreign labor. So, the question becomes which commodity does the United States have a higher advantage or efficiency (least cost)? We have a higher efficiency in soybeans if (a ls / a lt ) < ( a' ls / a' lt ) Or: (a ls / a lt ) < (a' ls / a' lt ) This means that the United States has a comparative advantage in the soybean production and England has a smaller comparative disadvantage relative to the United States in the production of textiles. Trade Triangle Assume that the United States and England specialized in S and T respectively. Then the pattern of production and, consumption, exports, and imports would be: productionconsumption exportsimports USODOCCD BC BC UKO'D'O'C'C'D' B'C' B'C' It can be shown that the two triangles BCD and B'C'D' are similar and identical. They are similar because -- they are both right angle -- BD and B'D' are parallel; both represent the international TOT and therefore D and B' are equal angles. As a result, B and D' must be equal angles. Also we know that exports of US is imports of England and they must be equal. Since all three angles and at least one side of the two triangles are equal, the two triangles are identical. Both triangles are identical because of the assumption that countries must pay for their imports by exports. So, imports of the U.S. (England) must be Comparative Advantage NUMBER OF LABOR HOURS NEEDED TO PRODUCE ONE UNIT OF SOYBEANS TEXTILES US510 ENGLAND1515 relative prices Before international Trade U.S. 1 T = 2 Sor1S=1/2T England 1 T =1 S Comparative Advantage Production Before International Trade SoybeansTextilesTotal U.S.112 England Comparative Advantage U.S. advantage over England are: Soybeans5/15 Textiles 10/15 Comparative Advantage Allocation of Labor after specialization SOYBEANS TEXTILES US150 ENGLAND 0 30Comparative Advantage Production After Specialization SoybeansTextilesTotal U.S.30 3 England02 2 Total U.S. has a higher advantage in both S and T. But US's advantage is higher in S. This is because there is a relatively smaller labor requirement for the production of S than for the production of T. So, even though the united States has an absolute advantage in the production of S and T, there is a higher advantage in the production of S. Therefore US must specialize in the production of S and England must specialize in the production of T in which she has a smaller disadvantage.

Comparative Advantage THEORY What if one country has absolute advantage in the production of both commodities ? NUMBER OF LABOR HOURS NEEDED TO PRODUCE ONE UNIT OF SOYBEANSTEXTILES US 5 15 ENGLAND10 20

Comparative Advantage THEORY relative prices Before international Trade U.S. 1 T / 3 S England 1 T / 2 S

Comparative Advantage THEORY Production Before International Trade SoybeansTextilesTotal U.S. 112 England 112 4

Comparative Advantage THEORY U.S. advantage over England are: Soybeans5/10 = 1/2 = 3/6 Textiles15/20 = 3/4 U.S. has a higher advantage in both S and T relative to England. The question is which one should the US specialize in?

Comparative Advantage THEORY U.S. advantage over England are: Soybeans5/10 = 1/2 = 3/6 Textiles15/20 = 3/4 But US's advantage is higher in S. Why?

Comparative Advantage THEORY U.S. advantage over England are: Soybeans5/10 = 1/2 = 3/6 Textiles15/20 = 3/4 But US's advantage is higher in S. Why? This is because there is a relatively smaller labor requirement for the production of S than for the production of T.

Comparative Advantage THEORY U.S. advantage over England are: Soybeans5/10 = 1/2 = 3/6 Textiles15/20 = 3/4 But US's advantage is higher in S. Why? This is because there is a relatively smaller labor requirement for the production of S than for the production of T. So, even though the united States has an absolute advantage in the production of S and T, there is a higher advantage in the production of S. Therefore US must specialize in the production of S and England must specialize in the production of T in which she has a smaller disadvantage.

Trade Triangle Assume that the United States and England specialized in S and T respectively. Then the pattern of production and, consumption, exports, and imports would be:

Trade Triangle BCD and B’C’D’ are equal. That is exports pay for imports. CDO B B’ O’ C’ D’ S S T T

Trade Triangle production consumptionexportsimports USOD (S)OCCDBC (T)BC UKO'D' (S) O'C'C'D'B'C' (T) B'C'

Evaluation of the Classical Model 1-- International trade expands PPC enhances standard of living for countries involved

Evaluation of the Classical Model 2-- Problems: it suggests that international trade is based on the productive capacities of different countries but it does not explain why they exist.

Evaluation of the Classical Model 2-- Problems: it suggests that international trade is based on the productive capacities of different countries but it does not explain why they exist. It makes extreme predications about direction of trade and specialization which are not borne out in the real world.

Evaluation of the Classical Model 2-- Problems: it suggests that international trade is based on the productive capacities of different countries but it does not explain why they exist. It makes extreme predications about direction of trade and specialization which are not borne out in the real world. The theory predicts that the greatest gain from trade come about when the countries involved are very dissimilar in their technologies. However, we know that most of the international trade is among advanced countries with similar technologies.