Econometrics I Professor William Greene Stern School of Business

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Introduction Describe what panel data is and the reasons for using it in this format Assess the importance of fixed and random effects Examine the Hausman.
Advertisements

Tests of Static Asset Pricing Models
Panel Data Models Prepared by Vera Tabakova, East Carolina University.
The Multiple Regression Model.
Part 12: Asymptotics for the Regression Model 12-1/39 Econometrics I Professor William Greene Stern School of Business Department of Economics.
3. Binary Choice – Inference. Hypothesis Testing in Binary Choice Models.
Vector Autoregressive Models
L18: CAPM1 Lecture 18: Testing CAPM The following topics will be covered: Time Series Tests –Sharpe (1964)/Litner (1965) version –Black (1972) version.
Part 10: Time Series Applications [ 1/64] Econometric Analysis of Panel Data William Greene Department of Economics Stern School of Business.
Economics Prof. Buckles1 Time Series Data y t =  0 +  1 x t  k x tk + u t 1. Basic Analysis.
Economics 20 - Prof. Anderson1 Multiple Regression Analysis y =  0 +  1 x 1 +  2 x  k x k + u 6. Heteroskedasticity.
1Prof. Dr. Rainer Stachuletz Multiple Regression Analysis y =  0 +  1 x 1 +  2 x  k x k + u 6. Heteroskedasticity.
Generalized Regression Model Based on Greene’s Note 15 (Chapter 8)
12.3 Correcting for Serial Correlation w/ Strictly Exogenous Regressors The following autocorrelation correction requires all our regressors to be strictly.
Economics 20 - Prof. Anderson
Part 7: Regression Extensions [ 1/59] Econometric Analysis of Panel Data William Greene Department of Economics Stern School of Business.
Linear Regression Models Powerful modeling technique Tease out relationships between “independent” variables and 1 “dependent” variable Models not perfect…need.
Economics Prof. Buckles
Part 21: Generalized Method of Moments 21-1/67 Econometrics I Professor William Greene Stern School of Business Department of Economics.
Part 7: Multiple Regression Analysis 7-1/54 Regression Models Professor William Greene Stern School of Business IOMS Department Department of Economics.
Part 14: Generalized Regression 14-1/46 Econometrics I Professor William Greene Stern School of Business Department of Economics.
Part 3: Regression and Correlation 3-1/41 Regression Models Professor William Greene Stern School of Business IOMS Department Department of Economics.
Inference issues in OLS
Part 5: Random Effects [ 1/54] Econometric Analysis of Panel Data William Greene Department of Economics Stern School of Business.
What does it mean? The variance of the error term is not constant
Microeconometric Modeling William Greene Stern School of Business New York University.
Pure Serial Correlation
Random Regressors and Moment Based Estimation Prepared by Vera Tabakova, East Carolina University.
Chap 14-1 Statistics for Business and Economics, 6e © 2007 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 14 Additional Topics in Regression Analysis Statistics for Business.
Various topics Petter Mostad Overview Epidemiology Study types / data types Econometrics Time series data More about sampling –Estimation.
Properties of OLS How Reliable is OLS?. Learning Objectives 1.Review of the idea that the OLS estimator is a random variable 2.How do we judge the quality.
Part 2: Model and Inference 2-1/49 Regression Models Professor William Greene Stern School of Business IOMS Department Department of Economics.
Maximum Likelihood Estimation Methods of Economic Investigation Lecture 17.
LECTURE 7 CONSTRUCTION OF ECONOMETRIC MODELS WITH AUTOCORRELATED RESIDUES.
Copyright © 2006 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin The Two-Variable Model: Hypothesis Testing chapter seven.
1 Javier Aparicio División de Estudios Políticos, CIDE Primavera Regresión.
Problems with the Durbin-Watson test
EC 532 Advanced Econometrics Lecture 1 : Heteroscedasticity Prof. Burak Saltoglu.
[Topic 1-Regression] 1/37 1. Descriptive Tools, Regression, Panel Data.
Dynamic Models, Autocorrelation and Forecasting ECON 6002 Econometrics Memorial University of Newfoundland Adapted from Vera Tabakova’s notes.
Module 4 Forecasting Multiple Variables from their own Histories EC 827.
Part 4A: GMM-MDE[ 1/33] Econometric Analysis of Panel Data William Greene Department of Economics Stern School of Business.
Review of Statistical Inference Prepared by Vera Tabakova, East Carolina University.
Univariate Time series - 2 Methods of Economic Investigation Lecture 19.
5. Extensions of Binary Choice Models
Ch5 Relaxing the Assumptions of the Classical Model
Vera Tabakova, East Carolina University
Kakhramon Yusupov June 15th, :30pm – 3:00pm Session 3
REGRESSION DIAGNOSTIC II: HETEROSCEDASTICITY
Evgeniya Anatolievna Kolomak, Professor
Chapter 15 Panel Data Analysis.
Pure Serial Correlation
Chapter 12 – Autocorrelation
Serial Correlation and Heteroskedasticity in Time Series Regressions
Chengyuan Yin School of Mathematics
Serial Correlation and Heteroscedasticity in
Chengyuan Yin School of Mathematics
Simple Linear Regression
Tutorial 1: Misspecification
Econometrics Analysis
Econometrics I Professor William Greene Stern School of Business
Econometrics I Professor William Greene Stern School of Business
Econometrics Chengyuan Yin School of Mathematics.
Econometric Analysis of Panel Data
Financial Econometrics Fin. 505
Serial Correlation and Heteroscedasticity in
Econometrics I Professor William Greene Stern School of Business
Microeconometric Modeling
Econometrics I Professor William Greene Stern School of Business
Presentation transcript:

Econometrics I Professor William Greene Stern School of Business Department of Economics

Econometrics I Part 15 – Generalized Regression Applications

Leading Applications of the GR Model Heteroscedasticity and Weighted Least Squares Autocorrelation in Time Series Models SUR Models for Production and Cost VAR models in Macroeconomics and Finance

Two Step Estimation of the Generalized Regression Model Use the Aitken (Generalized Least Squares - GLS) estimator with an estimate of  1.  is parameterized by a few estimable parameters. Examples, the heteroscedastic model 2. Use least squares residuals to estimate the variance functions 3. Use the estimated  in GLS - Feasible GLS, or FGLS

General Result for Estimation When  Is Estimated True GLS uses [X-1 X] -1X-1y which converges in probability to . We seek a vector which converges to the same thing that this does. Call it “feasible” GLS, FGLS, based on

FGLS Feasible GLS is based on finding an estimator which has the same properties as the true GLS. Example Var[i] = 2 [Exp(zi)]2. True GLS would regress y/[ Exp(zi)] on the same transformation of xi. With a consistent estimator of [,], say [s,c], we do the same computation with our estimates. So long as plim [s,c] = [,], FGLS is as “good” as true GLS.  Consistent  Same Asymptotic Variance  Same Asymptotic Normal Distribution

FGLS vs. Full GLS VVIR (Theorem 9.6) To achieve full efficiency, we do not need an efficient estimate of the parameters in , only a consistent one.

Heteroscedasticity Setting: The regression disturbances have unequal variances, but are still not correlated with each other: Classical regression with hetero-(different) scedastic (variance) disturbances. yi = xi + i, E[i] = 0, Var[i] = 2 i, i > 0. The classical model arises if i = 1. A normalization: i i = n. Not a restriction, just a scaling that is absorbed into 2. A characterization of the heteroscedasticity: Well defined estimators and methods for testing hypotheses will be obtainable if the heteroscedasticity is “well behaved” in the sense that no single observation becomes dominant.

Behavior of OLS Implications for conventional estimation technique and hypothesis testing: 1. b is still unbiased. Proof of unbiasedness did not rely on homoscedasticity 2. Consistent? We need the more general proof. Not difficult. 3. If plim b = , then plim s2 = 2 (with the normalization).

Inference Based on OLS What of s2(XX)-1 ? Depends on XX - XX. If they are nearly the same, the OLS covariance matrix is OK. When will they be nearly the same? Relates to an interesting property of weighted averages. Suppose i is randomly drawn from a distribution with E[i] = 1. Then, (1/n)ixi2  E[x2] and (1/n)iixi2  E[x2]. This is the crux of the discussion in your text.

Inference Based on OLS VIR: For the heteroscedasticity to be substantive wrt estimation and inference by LS, the weights must be correlated with x and/or x2. (Text, page 272.) If the heteroscedasticity is important. Then, b is inefficient. The White estimator. ROBUST estimation of the variance of b. Implication for testing hypotheses. We will use Wald tests. Why? (ROBUST TEST STATISTICS)

Finding Heteroscedasticity The central issue is whether E[2] = 2i is related to the xs or their squares in the model. Suggests an obvious strategy. Use residuals to estimate disturbances and look for relationships between ei2 and xi and/or xi2. For example, regressions of squared residuals on xs and their squares.

Procedures White’s general test: nR2 in the regression of ei2 on all unique xs, squares, and cross products. Chi-squared[P] Breusch and Pagan’s Lagrange multiplier test. Regress {[ei2 /(ee/n)] – 1} on Z (may be X). Chi-squared. Is nR2 with degrees of freedom rank of Z. (Very elegant.) Others described in text for other purposes. E.g., groupwise heteroscedasticity. Wald, LM, and LR tests all examine the dispersion of group specific least squares residual variances.

Estimation: WLS form of GLS General result - mechanics of weighted least squares. Generalized least squares - efficient estimation. Assuming weights are known. Two step generalized least squares: Step 1: Use least squares, then the residuals to estimate the weights. Step 2: Weighted least squares using the estimated weights. (Iteration: After step 2, recompute residuals and return to step 1. Exit when coefficient vector stops changing.)

Autocorrelation The analysis of “autocorrelation” in the narrow sense of correlation of the disturbances across time largely parallels the discussions we’ve already done for the GR model in general and for heteroscedasticity in particular. One difference is that the relatively crisp results for the model of heteroscedasticity are replaced with relatively fuzzy, somewhat imprecise results here. The reason is that it is much more difficult to characterize meaningfully “well behaved” data in a time series context. Thus, for example, in contrast to the sharp result that produces the White robust estimator, the theory underlying the Newey-West robust estimator is somewhat ambiguous in its requirement of a bland statement about “how far one must go back in time until correlation becomes unimportant.”

The Familiar AR(1) Model t = t-1 + ut, || < 1. This characterizes the disturbances, not the regressors.  A general characterization of the mechanism producing  history + current innovations  Analysis of this model in particular. The mean and variance and autocovariance  Stationarity. Time series analysis.  Implication: The form of 2; Var[] vs. Var[u].  Other models for autocorrelation - less frequently used – AR(1) is the workhorse.

Building the Model Prior view: A feature of the data “Account for autocorrelation in the data.” Different models, different estimators Contemporary view: Why is there autocorrelation? What is missing from the model? Build in appropriate dynamic structures Autocorrelation should be “built out” of the model Use robust procedures (Newey-West) instead of elaborate models specifically for the autocorrelation.

Model Misspecification

Implications for Least Squares Familiar results: Consistent, unbiased, inefficient, asymptotic normality The inefficiency of least squares:  Difficult to characterize generally. It is worst in “low frequency” i.e., long period (year) slowly evolving data.  Can be extremely bad. GLS vs. OLS, the efficiency ratios can be 3 or more. A very important exception - the lagged dependent variable yt = xt + yt-1 + t. t = t-1 + ut,. Obviously, Cov[yt-1 ,t ]  0, because of the form of t.  How to estimate? IV  Should the model be fit in this form? Is something missing? Robust estimation of the covariance matrix - the Newey-West estimator.

GLS and FGLS Theoretical result for known  - i.e., known . Prais-Winsten vs. Cochrane-Orcutt. FGLS estimation: How to estimate ? OLS residuals as usual - first autocorrelation. Many variations, all based on correlation of et and et-1

Testing for Autocorrelation A general proposition: There are several tests. All are functions of the simple autocorrelation of the least squares residuals. Two used generally, Durbin-Watson and Lagrange Multiplier The Durbin - Watson test. d  2(1 - r). Small values of d lead to rejection of NO AUTOCORRELATION: Why are the bounds necessary? Godfrey’s LM test. Regression of et on et-1 and xt. Uses a “partial correlation.”

Consumption “Function” Log real consumption vs Consumption “Function” Log real consumption vs. Log real disposable income (Aggregate U.S. Data, 1950I – 2000IV. Table F5.2 from text) ---------------------------------------------------------------------- Ordinary least squares regression ............ LHS=LOGC Mean = 7.88005 Standard deviation = .51572 Number of observs. = 204 Model size Parameters = 2 Degrees of freedom = 202 Residuals Sum of squares = .09521 Standard error of e = .02171 Fit R-squared = .99824 <<<*** Adjusted R-squared = .99823 Model test F[ 1, 202] (prob) =114351.2(.0000) --------+------------------------------------------------------------- Variable| Coefficient Standard Error t-ratio P[|T|>t] Mean of X Constant| -.13526*** .02375 -5.695 .0000 LOGY| 1.00306*** .00297 338.159 .0000 7.99083

Least Squares Residuals: r = .91

Conventional vs. Newey-West +---------+--------------+----------------+--------+---------+----------+ |Variable | Coefficient | Standard Error |t-ratio |P[|T|>t] | Mean of X| Constant -.13525584 .02375149 -5.695 .0000 LOGY 1.00306313 .00296625 338.159 .0000 7.99083133 |Newey-West Robust Covariance Matrix Constant -.13525584 .07257279 -1.864 .0638 LOGY 1.00306313 .00938791 106.846 .0000 7.99083133

FGLS +---------------------------------------------+ | AR(1) Model: e(t) = rho * e(t-1) + u(t) | | Initial value of rho = .90693 | <<<*** | Maximum iterations = 100 | | Method = Prais - Winsten | | Iter= 1, SS= .017, Log-L= 666.519353 | | Iter= 2, SS= .017, Log-L= 666.573544 | | Final value of Rho = .910496 | <<<*** | Durbin-Watson: e(t) = .179008 | | Std. Deviation: e(t) = .022308 | | Std. Deviation: u(t) = .009225 | | Durbin-Watson: u(t) = 2.512611 | | Autocorrelation: u(t) = -.256306 | | N[0,1] used for significance levels | +---------+--------------+----------------+--------+---------+----------+ |Variable | Coefficient | Standard Error |b/St.Er.|P[|Z|>z] | Mean of X| Constant -.08791441 .09678008 -.908 .3637 LOGY .99749200 .01208806 82.519 .0000 7.99083133 RHO .91049600 .02902326 31.371 .0000

Seemingly Unrelated Regressions The classical regression model, yi = Xii + i. Applies to each of M equations and T observations. Familiar example: The capital asset pricing model: (rm - rf) = mi + m( rmarket – rf ) + m Not quite the same as a panel data model. M is usually small - say 3 or 4. (The CAPM might have M in the thousands, but it is a special case for other reasons.)

Formulation Consider an extension of the groupwise heteroscedastic model: We had yi = Xi + i with E[i|X] = 0, Var[i|X] = i2I. Now, allow two extensions: Different coefficient vectors for each group, Correlation across the observations at each specific point in time (think about the CAPM above. Variation in excess returns is affected both by firm specific factors and by the economy as a whole). Stack the equations to obtain a GR model.

SUR Model

OLS and GLS Each equation can be fit by OLS ignoring all others. Why do GLS? Efficiency improvement. Gains to GLS: None if identical regressors - NOTE THE CAPM ABOVE! Implies that GLS is the same as OLS. This is an application of a strange special case of the GR model. “If the K columns of X are linear combinations of K characteristic vectors of , in the GR model, then OLS is algebraically identical to GLS.” We will forego our opportunity to prove this theorem. This is our only application. (Kruskal’s Theorem) Efficiency gains increase as the cross equation correlation increases (of course!).

The Identical X Case Suppose the equations involve the same X matrices. (Not just the same variables, the same data. Then GLS is the same as equation by equation OLS. Grunfeld’s investment data are not an example - each firm has its own data matrix. The 3 equation model on page 313 with Berndt and Wood’s data give an example. The three share equations all have the constant and logs of the price ratios on the RHS. Same variables, same years. The CAPM is also an example. (Note, because of the constraint in the B&W system (same δ parameters in more than one equation), the OLS result for identical Xs does not apply.)

Estimation by FGLS Two step FGLS is essentially the same as the groupwise heteroscedastic model. (1) OLS for each equation produces residuals ei. (2) Sij = (1/n)eiej then do FGLS Maximum likelihood estimation for normally distributed disturbances: Just iterate FLS. (This is an application of the Oberhofer-Kmenta result.)

Inference About the Coefficient Vectors Usually based on Wald statistics. If the estimator is maximum likelihood, LR statistic T(log|Srestricted| - log|Sunrestricted|) is a chi-squared statistic with degrees of freedom equal to the number of restrictions. Equality of the coefficient vectors: (Historical note: Arnold Zellner, The original developer of this model and estimation technique: “An Efficient Method of Estimating Seemingly Unrelated Regressions and Tests of Aggregation Bias” (my emphasis). JASA, 1962, pp. 500-509.  What did he have in mind by “aggregation bias?”  How to test the hypothesis?

Application A Translog demand system for a 3 factor process: (To bypass a transition in the notation, we proceed directly to the application) Electricity, Y, is produced using Fuel, F, capital, K, and Labor, L. Theory: The production function is Y = f(K,L,F). If it is smooth, has continuous first and second derivatives, and if(1) factor prices are determined in a market and (2) producers seek to minimize costs (maximize profits), then there is a “cost function” C = C(Y,PK,PL,PF). Shephard’s Lemma states that the cost minimizing factor demands are given by Xm = C(…)/Pm. Take logs gives the factor share equations, logC(…)/logPm = Pm/C  C(…)/Pm = PmXm/C which is the proportion of total cost spent on factor m.

Translog

Restrictions

Data – C&G, N=123

Least Squares Estimate of Cost Function ---------------------------------------------------------------------- Ordinary least squares regression ............ LHS=C Mean = -.38339 Standard deviation = 1.53847 Number of observs. = 123 Model size Parameters = 10 Degrees of freedom = 113 Residuals Sum of squares = 2.32363 Standard error of e = .14340 Fit R-squared = .99195 Adjusted R-squared = .99131 Model test F[ 9, 113] (prob) = 1547.7(.0000) --------+------------------------------------------------------------- Variable| Coefficient Standard Error t-ratio P[|T|>t] Mean of X Constant| -7.79653 6.28338 -1.241 .2172 Y| .42610*** .14318 2.976 .0036 8.17947 YY| .05606*** .00623 8.993 .0000 35.1125 PK| 2.80754 2.11625 1.327 .1873 .88666 PL| -.02630 (!) 2.54421 -.010 .9918 5.58088 PKK| .69161 .43475 1.591 .1144 .43747 PLL| .10325 .51197 .202 .8405 15.6101 PKL| -.48223 .41018 -1.176 .2422 5.00507 YK| -.07676** .03659 -2.098 .0381 7.25281 YL| .01473 .02888 .510 .6110 45.6830

FGLS Criterion function for GLS is log-likelihood. Iteration 0, GLS = 514.2530 Iteration 1, GLS = 519.8472 Iteration 2, GLS = 519.9199 ---------------------------------------------------------------------- Estimates for equation: C......................... Generalized least squares regression ............ LHS=C Mean = -.38339 Residuals Sum of squares = 2.24766 Standard error of e = .14103 Fit R-squared = .99153 Adjusted R-squared = .99085 Model test F[ 9, 113] (prob) = 1469.3(.0000) --------+------------------------------------------------------------- Variable| Coefficient Standard Error b/St.Er. P[|Z|>z] Mean of X Constant| -9.51337** 4.26900 -2.228 .0258 Y| .48204*** .09725 4.956 .0000 8.17947 YY| .04449*** .00423 10.521 .0000 35.1125 PK| 2.48099* 1.43621 1.727 .0841 .88666 PL| .61358 1.72652 .355 .7223 5.58088 PKK| .65620** .29491 2.225 .0261 .43747 PLL| -.03048 .34730 -.088 .9301 15.6101 PKL| -.42610 .27824 -1.531 .1257 5.00507 YK| -.06761*** .02482 -2.724 .0064 7.25281 YL| .01779 .01959 .908 .3640 45.6830

Maximum Likelihood Estimates ----------------------------------------------------------- Constrained MLE for Multivariate Regression Model First iteration: 0 F= -48.2305 log|W|= -7.72939 gtinv(H)g= 2.0977 Last iteration: 5 F= 508.8056 log|W|= -16.78689 gtinv(H)g= .0000 Number of observations used in estimation = 123 Model: ONE PK PL PKK PLL PKL Y YY YK YL C B0 BK BL CKK CLL CKL CY CYY CYK CYL SK BK CKK CKL CYK SL BL CKL CLL CYL --------+-------------------------------------------------- Variable| Coefficient Standard Error b/St.Er. P[|Z|>z] (FGLS) (OLS) B0| -6.71218*** .21594 -31.084 .0000 -9.51337 -7.79653 CY| .58239*** .02737 21.282 .0000 .48204 .42610 CYY| .05016*** .00371 13.528 .0000 .04449 .05606 BK| .22965*** .06757 3.399 .0007 2.48099 2.80754 BL| -.13562* .07948 -1.706 .0879 .61358 -.02630 CKK| .11603*** .01817 6.385 .0000 .65620 .69161 CLL| .07801*** .01563 4.991 .0000 -.03048 .10325 CKL| -.01200 .01343 -.894 .3713 -.42610 -.48223 CYK| -.00473* .00250 -1.891 .0586 -.06761 -.07676 CYL| -.01792*** .00211 -8.477 .0000 .01779 .01473

Vector Autoregression The vector autoregression (VAR) model is one of the most successful, flexible, and easy to use models for the analysis of multivariate time series. It is a natural extension of the univariate autoregressive model to dynamic multivariate time series. The VAR model has proven to be especially useful for describing the dynamic behavior of economic and financial time series and for forecasting. It often provides superior forecasts to those from univariate time series models and elaborate theory-based simultaneous equations models. Forecasts from VAR models are quite flexible because they can be made conditional on the potential future paths of specified variables in the model. In addition to data description and forecasting, the VAR model is also used for structural inference and policy analysis. In structural analysis, certain assumptions about the causal structure of the data under investigation are imposed, and the resulting causal impacts of unexpected shocks or innovations to specified variables on the variables in the model are summarized. These causal impacts are usually summarized with impulse response functions and forecast error variance decompositions. Eric Zivot: http://faculty.washington.edu/ezivot/econ584/notes/varModels.pdf

VAR

Zivot’s Data

Impulse Responses