ECO 7550 More Health Capital The Demand for Health Capital Cost of capital, in terms of foregone resources (for health capital, both time and money)

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Evaluate Factors That Affect Fitness to Assess Daily Dietary and Wellness Needs. Objective Identify factors that affect fitness.
Advertisements

The Demand for health and healthcare - Grossman Model
Chapter Nineteen Profit-Maximization.
Chapter 7 (7.1 – 7.4) Firm’s costs of production: Accounting costs: actual dollars spent on labor, rental price of bldg, etc. Economic costs: includes.
Understanding the Concept of Present Value
UNIT 7 SEMINAR NS 220 Module 7: Meeting Energy Needs.
Section 9.2 Safely Managing Your Weight Slide 1 of 27 Objectives Examine how heredity, activity level, and body composition influence a person’s weight.
3 Gains and Losses from Trade in the Specific-Factors Model 1
Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western.
Consumer Behavior Representative Consumer Rationale Two goods Consumption bundles.
Chapter 7 Demand for Health Capital 1.The demand for health 2.The investment/consumption aspects of health 3.The demand for health capital 4.Changes in.
Who Wants to be an Economist? Part II Disclaimer: questions in the exam will not have this kind of multiple choice format. The type of exercises in the.
Obesity © Allen C. Goodman, Obesity A leading risk factor for heart disease, hypertension (high blood pressure), certain cancers, and type-2 diabetes.
In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
Chapter 8 Costs © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western.
Mosby items and derived items © 2006 by Mosby, Inc. Slide 1 Chapter 6 Energy Balance.
Chapter 20: Consumer Choice
The Theory of Aggregate Supply Classical Model. Learning Objectives Understand the determinants of output. Understand how output is distributed. Learn.
Ch. 18: Demand and Supply in Factor Markets
 Calorie (aka. ______________) ◦ Amount of ____________ needed to __________ the temperature of 1 _________ of pure water by 1C  ______ calories =
Section 9.2 Safely Managing Your Weight Slide 1 of 27 Objectives Examine how heredity, activity level, and body composition influence a person’s weight.
Weight management.
Lesson 1 Bell Ringer Define Body image and self esteem.
Nutrition Choosing Food Wisely Food Labels & Healthy Weight Management.
Lecture 6 Demand for Health Capital Tianxu Chen
Lecture 5 FGS - Chapter 7 – Health Capital 2014 How to Manage Dental Costs, With or Without Insurance By WALECIA KONRAD Published: September 4, 2009.
Maintaining a Healthy Weight
JOURNAL  List 3 occupations that you think burn the most calories.  List 3 occupations that you think burn the least amount of calories.
Determining Healthy Weight Chapter 5. Body Weight Includes the weight of: Bones, Muscle, Fat, and other tissues. People have different body compositions.
Obesity and Weight Control Senior Health-Bauberger.
Chapter 8 © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western Costs.
Principles of Microeconomics
6.1 Chapter 7 – The Theory of Consumer Behavior  The Theory of Consumer behavior provides the theoretical basis for buyer decision- making and the foundation.
© 2011 South-Western, a part of Cengage Learning, all rights reserved C H A P T E R 2011 update The Theory of Consumer Choice M icroeconomics P R I N C.
The Theory of Consumer Choice
Perfect Competition Chapter 7
Junk Food, Physical Activity, and Obesity: The Effect of the Fat Tax and the Thin Subsidy by Odelia Rosin, Yossef Tobol, Gideon Yaniv.
Derivatives to Business and Economics. Our textbook tells us that business analysts and economists have increasingly turned to mathematical models to.
ECO 5550 More Health Capital Supply -- (Cost of Capital) Since health is a capital good, it is necessary to understand the cost of capital as well as.
BELL WORK What do you think are some factors in the rise of obesity?
Slide 0 CHAPTER 3 National Income Outline of model A closed economy, market-clearing model Supply side  factor markets (supply, demand, price)  determination.
Appendix Basic Math for Economics. 2 Functions of One Variable Variables: The basic elements of algebra, usually called X, Y, and so on, that may be given.
1 Aggregate Expenditure and Aggregate Demand CHAPTER 25 © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
Chapter 4 Consumer and Firm Behaviour: The Work-Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education Canada.
UNIT 7 SEMINAR NS 220 Module 7: Meeting Energy Needs.
Slide 1 Copyright © 2002 by O. Mikhail, Graphs are © by Pearson Education, Inc. Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work-Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization.
Chapter 6 Food and Your Health Lesson 1 Managing Your Weight p. 132.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western. The Theory of Consumer Choice The theory of consumer choice addresses the following questions: –Do all demand curves slope.
Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior. Chapter 3: Consumer BehaviorSlide 2 Topics to be Discussed Consumer Preferences Budget Constraints Consumer Choice Revealed.
1 Consumer Choice and Demand CHAPTER 6 © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
1 Consumer Choice and Demand CHAPTER 6 © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 9 A Real Intertemporal Model with Investment.
Healthy Weight Management Nutrition Unit Lesson 9.
Test Review Econ 322 Test Review Test 1 Chapters 1,2,8,3,4,7.
Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 4 Resources, Comparative Advantage, and Income Distribution.
Aggregate Demand Aggregate demand is the total demand in an economy for all the goods and services produced. The aggregate demand schedule is a schedule.
Consumer Choices and Economic Behavior
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 4 Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work-Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization.
Maintaining a healthy weight has many benefits Better sleep Increase energy level Increase in emotional wellness (decrease in stress) Reduces which diseases?
Supply and demand Part 3. Underlying assumptions in economic theory The underlying value judgement Individual (Homo oeconomicus hypothesis) sovereignty:
1 Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization CHAPTER 6 Appendix © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
© 2011 South-Western, a part of Cengage Learning, all rights reserved C H A P T E R 2011 update The Theory of Consumer Choice M icroeconomics P R I N C.
Chapter 4 Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work-Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization.
Section 9.2 Safely Managing Your Weight Objectives
ECO 7550 More Health Capital
Physical Health: Nutrition
Energy Extension.
Energy Extension.
Section 9.2 Safely Managing Your Weight Objectives
AS-AD curves: how natural is the natural rate of unemployment?
Presentation transcript:

ECO 7550 More Health Capital

The Demand for Health Capital Cost of capital, in terms of foregone resources (for health capital, both time and money) is a supply concept. Other needed tool is the concept of the marginal efficiency of investment, the MEI, a demand concept which relates the return to investment to the amount of resources invested.

Marginal Efficiency of Investment (MEI) and Rate of Return The MEI can be described in terms of the X-ray machine example. A clinic which does considerable business may wish to own more than one such X-ray machine. How many? The clinic management may logically consider them in sequence. Size of I (in $) Rate of Return (%)

The first X-ray machine purchased (if they were to buy only one) would yield a return. Suppose that return each year was $100,000. We can also calculate the rate of return, which would be $100,000/$500,000 or 20% per year. They would buy this X- ray machine if it covered its opportunity cost of capital and the depreciation. Size of I (in $) Rate of Return (%) Marginal Efficiency of Investment (MEI) and Rate of Return

Management would choose to own the first X-ray machine as long as the rate of return, 20%, was greater than the –interest rate (the opportunity cost of capital) –plus the depreciation rate. Size of I (in $) Rate of Return (%) Marginal Efficiency of Investment (MEI) and Rate of Return Cost of capital = interest rate + depreciation rate

Marginal Efficiency of Investment If they considered owning two X-ray machines, they would discover that the rate of return to the second X-ray machine was probably less than the first. Suppose that a clinic buying only one X-ray machine would assign it to the highest priority uses, those with the highest rate of return. If they add a second X-ray machine, then logically it could only be assigned to lesser priority uses (and might be idle on occasion)  lower rate of return than the first. Clinic would also purchase the second X-ray machine only if its rate of return was still higher than interest plus depreciation.

Decreasing MEI Let the marginal efficiency of investment curve, MEI, describe the pattern of rates of return, declining as the amount of investment (measured on the horizontal axis) increases. The cost of capital, that is, the interest rate plus the depreciation rate, is shown as the horizontal line labeled (r +  ). Size of I (in $) Rate of Return (%) Cost of capital = interest rate (r) + depreciation rate (  )

Optimum amount of capital The optimum amount of capital demanded is thus K o, which represents the amount of capital at which the marginal efficiency of investment just equals the cost of capital. Like the mgl efficiency of investment curve in this example, the MEI curve for investments in health would also be downward sloping. Size of I (in $) Rate of Return (%) I* MEI Curve Expenditures ↓ I may NOT mean ↓ Expenditures Cost of capital = interest rate (r) + depreciation rate (  )

Diminishing Marginal Returns This occurs because the production function for healthy days (Figure 7.4) exhibits diminishing marginal returns. Health Inputs Healthy Days 365 Total Product

Equilibria Cost of capital for health would similarly reflect the interest rate plus the rate of depreciation in health. Person’s health, like any capital good, will also depreciate over time. Thus the optimal demand for health is likewise given at the intersection of the MEI curve and the cost of capital curve, (r +  ). Size of I (in $) Rate of Return (%) Cost of capital = interest rate (r) + depreciation rate (  ) I* MEI Curve Increased depreciation rate I**

Pure Investment and Pure Consumption Models Do we invest in health because it makes us feel good, or do we invest in health because it makes us more productive? If all we care about is the money we can earn, then all we care about is bread. We have vertical indifference curves. We want only the amount that will allow us to earn as much as we can. Health Bread PP curve Pure investment eq’m

Pure Investment and Consumption Models If all we also care about health, we get more conventional indifference curves. Health Bread PPP Less bread -- more health Pure investment eq’m

Comparative Statics – Age Age  What happens to MEI? Why? Size of I (in $) Rate of Return (%) Cost of capital = interest rate (r) + depreciation rate (  ) I* MEI Curve

Comparative Statics – Education Higher Education  What happens to MEI? Why? Size of I (in $) Rate of Return (%) Cost of capital = interest rate (r) + depreciation rate (  ) I* MEI Curve

Comparative Statics – Wage Wage  What happens to MEI? Why? But what if investment has a large wage component? As drawn the impact is positive, but mathematically it is ambiguous. Size of I (in $) Rate of Return (%) Cost of capital = interest rate (r) + depreciation rate (  ) I* MEI Curve

One More Example of MEI – Uncertainty What is impact of increased uncertainty. Some models say I ↑. Others say I ↓. Let’s look ex ante. You’re uncertain about the future. You can invest in I, or in F (non-health financial asset), which by assumption is less risky. What do we do this year. Investment Cost of Capital MEI I*

Uncertainty Depends! An ↑ in I this year will increase health capital next year. If this ↑ productivity, MEI shifts right  Do it (i.e. Invest)! Investment MEI I* MEI' An ↑ in I will increase health capital next year. If this does NOT ↑ productivity, you move down MEI curve  Don’t do it (i.e. Don’t Invest.) Cost of Capital

If on net, sum of the impacts is positive, uncertainty increases health investment. If on net, sum of impacts is negative, uncertainty decreases health investment. One More Example – Uncertainty

So, what does Grossman tell us? How resources are allocated over time. How resources are allocated in any given period. Grossman focuses on the first. Ultimately the math is complex but it comes to the equation: [1][2][3][4] Marginal BenefitsMarginal Costs = Sick time

What does it mean? [3] Increased health must reduce sick time (-). If not, I = 0. [1][2][3][4] Marginal BenefitsMarginal Costs = [1] Valuation of health as a consumption good. Numerator (-) refers to increased utility that health buys. Denominator (+) tells about the increased income from financial assets (nonwage income), and what you can buy with it. [2] Increased labor income (-)  pure investment effect [4] Cost of capital * amount of capital.

Edgeworth Boxes and Constant Returns An a%  in goods and leisure  an a%  in health and home good Health Leisure Expansion path for health Expansion path for home good Think about CRTS? What does the length of the ray mean?

Edgeworth Boxes and Increases in 1 Factor An a% increase in goods  an  in goods-intensive output (here, health), but a  in home good. Why?

Rybczynski - A little calculus Let: a gI and a tI denote the goods and leisure per unit of Health Investment, I a gc and a tc denote the goods and leisure per unit of Home Good, C These coefficients will vary with the relative factor prices {Leisure - wage rate; Home good - out-of-pocket price}, but since a given commodity price ratio (e.g. Health Investment/Home Good) uniquely determines a factor price ratio, these coefficients will be constants at the given commodity price-ratio (why?). Denoting the total amounts of goods and leisure available as G and T respectively: a gI I + a gc C = G a tI I + a tc C = T

Solving these equations for I/T and C/T yields: I/T = [a tc (G/T) - a gc ] / [a gI a tc -a tI a gc ] C/T = [a gI - a tI (G/T)] / [a gI a tc -a tI a gc ] We can then solve for: I/C = [a tc (G/T) - a gc ]/[a gI - a tI (G/T)] This is the ratio of commodity outputs as a function of the goods/time ratio. Differentiating (I/C) with respect to (G/T) yields: d (I/C) / d (G/T) = (a gI a tc - a tI a gc ) / (a gI - a tI (G/T)) 2 Then: d (I/C) / d (G/T)  0, as (a gI /a tI )  (a gc /a tc ). d (I/C) / d (G/T)  0, as (a gI /a tI )  (a gc /a tc ). a gI /a tI = (goods/leisure ratio) I a gc /a tc = (goods/leisure ratio) C. x x Factor the Denominators

Income Effects As drawn, I is more mkt.-intensive. An  in G leads to relatively large  in I. Bread Invest. Time $

Obesity – An Application of Human Capital A leading risk factor for heart disease, hypertension (high blood pressure), certain cancers, and type-2 diabetes. According to reports from the CDC in 2012, over one third of U.S. adults (more than 72 million) people and 17% of U.S. children are obese. From 1980 through 2008, obesity rates for adults doubled and rates for children tripled. Obesity describes health capital: –may make the body less productive, –more susceptible to disease, and –possibly cause it to depreciate more quickly.

BMI Health analysts usually measure obesity in terms of Body Mass Index, or BMI, with the formula. CategoryBMI range Severely underweightless than 16 Underweight16 to 18.5 Normal18.5 to 25 Overweight25 to 30 Obese Class I30 to 35 Obese Class II35 to 40 Obese Class III40 and above BMI BMI Calculator

2000 Obesity Trends* Among U.S. Adults BRFSS, 1990, 2000, 2010 (*BMI 30, or about 30 lbs. overweight for 5’4” person) No Data <10% 10%–14% 15%–19% 20%–24% 25%–29% ≥30%

Yaniv, Rosin, and Tobol Calories are expended in both in physical activity and when the body is at rest. The rest component, known as Basal Metabolic Rate (BMR), is the largest source of energy expenditure, reflecting blood circulation, respiration and daily maintenance of body temperature. Differing BMRs among individuals indicate why one person can “eat like a horse” and gain little weight, while another may gain weight with far less intake of food.

Obesity – Economic Theory Weight gain as the outcome of rational choice that reflects a willingness to trade off some future health for the present pleasures of less restrained eating and lower physical activity. “Diets” reverse this.

Model Overweight individuals can determine consumption of junk-food meals, F, and healthy meals, H. They may also choose their level of exercise, x. The model defines the weight gain during a period, or obesity, S, as: S = δF + εH − μx − BMR YRT develop the model showing that taxes on junk food (reducing consumption), or subsidies to healthy food (increasing its consumption) could have important impacts on formation of health capital.

Why has obesity increased. Cutler, Glaeser, and Shapiro (2003)

Changes in the time costs of food production Vacuum packing, improved preservatives. Mass preparation –French fries are a pain to make at home –Quick and easy at the restaurants –Food professionals and economies of scale

Time Costs by Group Cutler, Glaeser, and Shapiro (2003) 104.4

References Cutler, David M., Edward L. Glaeser and Jesse M. Shapiro, “Why Have Americans Become More Obese?” Journal of Economic Perspectives 17 (3): 93–118 Yaniv, Gideon, Odelia Rosin, and Yossef Tobel, “Junk-food, Home Cooking, Physical Activity and Obesity: The Effect of the Fat Tax and the Thin Subsidy,” Journal of Public Economics 93 (2009): 823–830