SIMULTANEOUS EQUATION MODELS

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Chapter 6 Matrix Algebra.
Advertisements

5.4 Basis And Dimension.
Rules of Matrix Arithmetic
Economics 20 - Prof. Anderson1 Simultaneous Equations y 1 =  1 y 2 +  1 z 1 + u 1 y 2 =  2 y 1 +  2 z 2 + u 2.
Simple Regression. Major Questions Given an economic model involving a relationship between two economic variables, how do we go about specifying the.
Lecture 12 (Ch16) Simultaneous Equations Models (SEMs)
LINEAR REGRESSION MODEL
AE Model and the Multiplier
© Based on 2006 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Macroeconomics, 4/e Olivier Blanchard The Short Term I: The Goods Market.
Bagian 1. 2 Contents The log-linear model Semilog models.
Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western.
The Demand for Goods Total Demand. The Demand for Goods –C = C 0 + C 1 Y D –C 1 = propensity to consume Change in C from a dollar change in income –0.
Simultaneous Equations Models
1Prof. Dr. Rainer Stachuletz Simultaneous Equations y 1 =  1 y 2 +  1 z 1 + u 1 y 2 =  2 y 1 +  2 z 2 + u 2.
Appendix to Chapter 1 Mathematics Used in Microeconomics © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western.
Chapter 4 Multiple Regression.
Chapter 9 Simultaneous Equations Models. What is in this Chapter? In Chapter 4 we mentioned that one of the assumptions in the basic regression model.
Economics 310 Lecture 18 Simultaneous Equations There is a two-way, or simultaneous, relationship between Y and (some of) the X’s, which makes the distinction.
Economics 214 Lecture 13 Systems of Equations. Examples of System of Equations Demand and Supply IS-LM Aggregate Demand and Supply.
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 3 Spending, Income, and Interest Rates.
§ 10.5 Systems of Nonlinear Equations in Two Variables.

Chapter 4 Systems of Linear Equations; Matrices
Demand Estimation & Forecasting
V PART The Core of Macroeconomic Theory.
1 In a second variation, we shall consider the model shown above. x is the rate of growth of productivity, assumed to be exogenous. w is now hypothesized.
5  Systems of Linear Equations: ✦ An Introduction ✦ Unique Solutions ✦ Underdetermined and Overdetermined Systems  Matrices  Multiplication of Matrices.
1 1.1 © 2012 Pearson Education, Inc. Linear Equations in Linear Algebra SYSTEMS OF LINEAR EQUATIONS.
Copyright (c) 2000 by Harcourt, Inc. All rights reserved. Functions of One Variable Variables: The basic elements of algebra, usually called X, Y, and.
ECON 6012 Cost Benefit Analysis Memorial University of Newfoundland
Regression Method.
Systems of Linear Equation and Matrices
ME 1202: Linear Algebra & Ordinary Differential Equations (ODEs)
CJT 765: Structural Equation Modeling Class 7: fitting a model, fit indices, comparingmodels, statistical power.
Simultaneous Equations Models (聯立方程式模型)
Section 2.2 Echelon Forms Goal: Develop systematic methods for the method of elimination that uses matrices for the solution of linear systems. The methods.
TWO-VARIABLEREGRESSION ANALYSIS: SOME BASIC IDEAS In this chapter:
WEEK 8 SYSTEMS OF EQUATIONS DETERMINANTS AND CRAMER’S RULE.
Chapter 4.1 Solving Systems of Linear Equations in two variables.
1 Lecture 8 The Keynesian Theory of Consumption Other Determinants of Consumption Planned Investment (I) The Determination of Equilibrium Output (Income)
National Income Determination For more, see any Macroeconomics text book.
The Goods Market Lecture 11 – academic year 2013/14 Introduction to Economics Fabio Landini.
CJT 765: Structural Equation Modeling Class 10: Non-recursive Models.
Y X 0 X and Y are not perfectly correlated. However, there is on average a positive relationship between Y and X X1X1 X2X2.
Section 2.3 Properties of Solution Sets
Chapter Three TWO-VARIABLEREGRESSION MODEL: THE PROBLEM OF ESTIMATION
Copyright © Cengage Learning. All rights reserved. 1 STRAIGHT LINES AND LINEAR FUNCTIONS Warm Up: p. 45 Self-Check Exercises #1.
Simultaneous Equations Models A simultaneous equations model is one in which there are endogenous variables which are determined jointly. e.g. the demand-supply.
Copyright ©2015 Pearson Education, Inc. All rights reserved.
10-1 MGMG 522 : Session #10 Simultaneous Equations (Ch. 14 & the Appendix 14.6)
Financial Econometrics – 2014 – Dr. Kashif Saleem 1 Financial Econometrics Dr. Kashif Saleem Associate Professor (Finance) Lappeenranta School of Business.
1 Mathematics for Economics and Business Jean Soper chapter three Macroeconomic Models.
Slide 0 CHAPTER 10 Aggregate Demand I In Chapter 10, you will learn…  the IS curve, and its relation to  the Keynesian cross  the loanable funds model.
1/25 Introduction to Econometrics. 2/25 Econometrics Econometrics – „economic measurement“ „May be defined as the quantitative analysis of actual economic.
Lecturer: Ing. Martina Hanová, PhD. Business Modeling.
Instructor: R. Makoto 1richard makoto UZ Econ313 Lecture notes.
Endogeneity in Econometrics: Simultaneous Equations Models Ming LU.
Regression Analysis Chapters 1-2
Solving Systems of Equations in Two Variables; Applications
Simultaneous equation system
STOCHASTIC REGRESSORS AND THE METHOD OF INSTRUMENTAL VARIABLES
Linear Systems.
Lial/Hungerford/Holcomb/Mullins: Mathematics with Applications 11e Finite Mathematics with Applications 11e Copyright ©2015 Pearson Education, Inc. All.
Simultaneous equation models Prepared by Nir Kamal Dahal(Statistics)
Further Equations and Techniques
Chapter 1 Linear Equations and Graphs
Linear Regression Summer School IFPRI
Simultaneous Equations Models
Matrices and Determinants
Presentation transcript:

SIMULTANEOUS EQUATION MODELS ECONOMETRICS DARMANTO STATISTICS UNIVERSITY OF BRAWIJAYA

PREFACE… In contrast to single-equation models, in simultaneous-equation models more than one dependent, or endogenous, variable is involved, necessitating as many equations as the number of endogenous variables. A unique feature of simultaneous-equation models is that the endogenous variable (i.e., regressand) in one equation may appear as an explanatory variable (i.e., regressor) in another equation of the system. As a consequence, such an endogenous explanatory variable becomes stochastic and is usually correlated with the disturbance term of the equation in which it appears as an explanatory variable. In this situation the classical OLS method may not be applied because the estimators thus obtained are not consistent, that is, they do not converge to their true population values no matter how large the sample size.

EXAMPLES : 1.1 DEMAND-AND-SUPPLY MODEL As is well known, the price P of a commodity and the quantity Q sold are determined by the intersection of the demand-and-supply curves for that commodity. Thus, assuming for simplicity that the demand-and- supply curves are linear and adding the stochastic disturbance terms u1 and u2, … (1) … (2)

EXAMPLES : 1.2

EXAMPLES : 2.1 KEYNESIAN MODEL OF INCOME DETERMINATION Consider the simple Keynesian model of income determination: Consumption function: Ct = β0 + β1Yt + ut ; 0 <β1 < 1 …(3) Income identity: Yt = Ct + It ( = St ) …(4) where C = consumption expenditure Y = income I = investment (assumed exogenous) S = savings t = time u = stochastic disturbance term β0 and β1 = parameters

EXAMPLES : 2.2

EXAMPLES: 3 …(5) …(6)

EXAMPLES: 4 THE IS MODEL OF MACROECONOMICS The celebrated IS, or goods market equilibrium, model of macroeconomics in its nonstochastic form can be expressed as

EXAMPLES: 5 ECONOMETRIC MODEL: Klein’s model I (Professor Lawrence Klein of the Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania). His initial model`is as follows:

THE IDENTIFICATION PROBLEM SIMULTANEOUS EQUATION MODELS

PREFACE… The problem of identification precedes the problem of estimation. The identification problem asks whether one can obtain unique numerical estimates of the structural coefficients from the estimated reduced form coefficients. If this can be done, an equation in a system of simultaneous equations is identified. If this cannot be done, that equation is un- or under-identified. An identified equation can be just identified or over- identified. In the former case, unique values of structural coefficients can be obtained; in the latter, there may be more than one value for one or more structural parameters.

NOTATION AND DEFINITION: 1 The general M equations model in M endogenous, or jointly dependent, variables may be written as Eq. (7):

NOTATION AND DEFINITION: 2 Where Y1, Y2, ... , YM = M endogenous, or jointly dependent, variables X1, X2, ... , XK = K predetermined variables (one of these X variables may take a value of unity to allow for the intercept term in each equation) u1, u2, ... , uM = M stochastic disturbances t = 1, 2, ... , T = total number of observations β’s = coefficients of the endogenous variables γ’s = coefficients of the predetermined variables

NOTATION AND DEFINITION: 3 The variables entering a simultaneous-equation model are of two types: Endogenous, that is, those (whose values are) determined within the model; and Predetermined, that is, those (whose values are) determined outside the model. The predetermined variables are divided into two categories: Exogenous, current as well as lagged, and Thus, X1t is a current (present-time) exogenous variable, whereas X1(t−1) is a lagged exogenous variable, with a lag of one time period. Lagged endogenous. Y(t−1) is a lagged endogenous variable with a lag of one time period, but since the value of Y1(t−1) is known at the current time t, it is regarded as non-stochastic, hence, a predetermined variable.

NOTATION AND DEFINITION: 4 The equations appearing in (7) are known as the structural, or behavioral, equations because they may portray the structure (of an economic model) of an economy or the behavior of an economic agent (e.g., consumer or producer). The β’s and γ’s are known as the structural parameters or coefficients. From the structural equations one can solve for the M endogenous variables and derive the reduced-form equations and the associated reduced form coefficients. A reduced-form equation is one that expresses an endogenous variable solely in terms of the predetermined variables and the stochastic disturbances.

NOTATION AND DEFINITION: 5 Consider the simple Keynesian model of income determination: Consumption function: Ct = β0 + β1Yt + ut ; 0 <β1 < 1 …(3) Income identity: Yt = Ct + It ( = St ) …(4) If (3) is substituted into (4), we obtain, after simple algebraic manipulation, …(8) where …(9) reduced-form equation reduced-form coefficient

NOTATION AND DEFINITION: 6 Substituting the value of Y from (8) into C of (3), we obtain another reduced-form equation: The reduced-form coefficients, such as ∏1 and ∏3, are also known as impact, or short-run, multipliers, because they measure the immediate impact on the endogenous variable of a unit change in the value of the exogenous variable. where …(10) …(11)

NOTATION AND DEFINITION: 7 If in the preceding Keynesian model the investment expenditure is increased by, say, $1 and if the MPC is assumed to be 0.8, then from (9) we obtain ∏1 = 5. This result means that increasing the investment by $1 will immediately (i.e., in the current time period) lead to an increase in income of $5, that is, a fivefold increase. Similarly, under the assumed conditions, (11) shows that ∏3 = 4, meaning that $1 increase in investment expenditure will lead immediately to $4 increase in consumption expenditure.

THE IDENTIFICATION PROBLEM By the identification problem we mean whether numerical estimates of the parameters of a structural equation can be obtained from the estimated reduced-form coefficients. If this can be done, we say that the particular equation is identified. If this cannot be done, then we say that the equation under consideration is unidentified, or under-identified. An identified equation may be either: Exactly (or fully or just) identified. if unique numerical values of the structural parameters can be obtained Over-identified. If more than one numerical value can be obtained for some of the parameters of the structural equations.

UNDER-IDENTIFICATION: 1 Consider once again the demand-and-supply model (1) and (2), together with the market-clearing, or equilibrium, condition that demand is equal to supply. By the equilibrium condition, we obtain …(12) where …(13) …(14) …(12.a)

UNDER-IDENTIFICATION: 2 Substituting Pt from (12.1) into (1) or (2), we obtain the following equilibrium quantity: …(15) …(16) …(17) where

UNDER-IDENTIFICATION: 3 Equations (12.a) and (15) are reduced-form equations. Now our demand-and-supply model contains four structural coefficients α0, α1, β0, and β1, but there is no unique way of estimating them. WHY…? The answer lies in the two reduced-form coefficients given in (13) and (16). These reduced-form coefficients contain all four structural parameters, but there is no way in which the four structural unknowns can be estimated from only two reduced- form coefficients.

JUST OR EXACT IDENTIFICATION: 1 Consider the following demand-and-supply model By the market-clearing mechanism we have …(18) …(19) …(20)

JUST OR EXACT IDENTIFICATION: 2 Solving this equation, we obtain the following equilibrium price: …(21) …(22) where

JUST OR EXACT IDENTIFICATION: 3 Substituting the equilibrium price into the demand or supply equation, we obtain the corresponding equilibrium quantity: …(23) …(24) where

OVER-IDENTIFICATION Let modify the demand function (18) as follows, keeping the supply function as before (R represents wealth): …(25) …(26) (29)… …(27) …(28)

RULES OF IDENTIFICATION Fulfill the order and rank conditions, Notations: M = number of endogenous variables in the model m = number of endogenous variables in a given equation K = number of predetermined variables in the model including the intercept k = number of predetermined variables in a given equation

THE ORDER CONDITION OF IDENTIFIABILITY: 1 DEFINITION 1: In a model of M simultaneous equations in order for an equation to be identified, it must exclude at least M − 1 variables (endogenous as well as pre-determined) appearing in the model. If it excludes exactly M − 1 variables, the equation is just identified. If it excludes more than M − 1 variables, it is over-identified. DEFINITION 2: In a model of M simultaneous equations, in order for an equation to be identified, the number of pre-determined variables excluded from the equation must not be less than the number of endogenous variables included in that equation less 1, that is, K − k ≥ m− 1 (...30) If K − k = m − 1, the equation is just identified, but if K − k > m − 1, it is over-identified.

THE ORDER CONDITION OF IDENTIFIABILITY: 2

THE ORDER CONDITION OF IDENTIFIABILITY: 3

THE RANK CONDITION OF IDENTIFIABILITY: 1 RANK CONDITION OF IDENTIFICATION In a model containing M equations in M endogenous variables, an equation is identified if and only if at least one nonzero determinant of order (M − 1)(M − 1) can be constructed from the coefficients of the variables (both endogenous and predetermined) excluded from that particular equation but included in the other equations of the model.

THE RANK CONDITION OF IDENTIFIABILITY: 2 Consider the following hypothetical system of simultaneous equations in which the Y variables are endogenous and the X variables are predetermined Consider the first equation, which excludes variables Y4, X2, and X3

THE RANK CONDITION OF IDENTIFIABILITY: 3

THE RANK CONDITION OF IDENTIFIABILITY: 3 The first equation: Since the determinant is zero, the rank of the matrix, denoted by ρ(A), is less than 3. Therefore, Eq. (19.3.2) does not satisfy the rank condition and hence is not identified. As noted, the rank condition is both a necessary and sufficient condition for identification. Therefore, although the order condition shows that Eq. (19.3.2) is identified, the rank condition shows that it is not. Apparently,

THE RANK CONDITION OF IDENTIFIABILITY: 4 To apply the rank condition one may proceed as follows: Write down the system in a tabular form Strike out the coefficients of the row in which the equation under consideration appears. Also strike out the columns corresponding to those coefficients in 2 which are nonzero. The entries left in the table will then give only the coefficients of the variables included in the system but not in the equation under consideration.

THE RANK CONDITION OF IDENTIFIABILITY: 5