It Ain’t What You Do It’s The Way That You Do I.T.: Investigating the US Productivity Miracle using Multinationals John Van Reenen, Department of Economics,

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
1 InnovaTion, InvesTment and ImiTation: How Information and Communication Technology Affected European Productivity Performance Bart Los and Marcel Timmer,
Advertisements

Ex post versus ex ante measures of the user cost of capital Nicholas Oulton LSE and NIESR June 2005.
The Productivity Gap between Europe and the US: Trends and Causes Marcel P. Timmer Groningen Growth and Development Centre The EU KLEMS project is funded.
INTRODUCTION TO THE WORLD KLEMS CONFERENCE By Dale W. Jorgenson, Mun S. Ho, and Jon D. Samuels Harvard.
International Comparisons of Industry Output, Inputs and Productivity Levels: Methodology and New Results Presentation prepared for Discussion session.
Firm-Level Productivity in Bangladesh Manufacturing Industries Ana M. Fernandes The World Bank (DECRG) Bangladesh: A Strategy for Growth and Employment.
Introduction Describe what panel data is and the reasons for using it in this format Assess the importance of fixed and random effects Examine the Hausman.
Yvonne Wolfmayr with Martin Falk Services and materials outsourcing to low-wage countries and employment: Empirical evidence from EU countries WORKS Expert.
Productivity or Employment: Is it a choice? Andrea De Michelis Federal Reserve Board Marcello Estevão International Monetary Fund Beth Anne Wilson Federal.
Searching for the Robust Method to Estimate Total Factor Productivity at Firm Level Yin Heng Li Shigang Liu Di SEBA Beijing Normal University
The Israeli Economy Stanley Fischer Bank of Israel November 2007.
1 Reviewing the nomenclature for high- technology trade – the sectoral approach by Alexander Loschky.
Nick Bloom, Applied Econometrics, Winter 2010 APPLIED ECONOMETRICS Lecture 2 – Research Projects.
Nick Bloom, Stanford University, Labor Topics, LABOR TOPICS Nick Bloom Technology and Labor Markets.
Services productivity growth in Australia, Europe and US Robert Inklaar Groningen Growth and Development Centre, University of Groningen and The Conference.
Productivity Growth in the New Millennium and its Industry Origins By Dale W. Jorgenson, Mun Ho, Jon Samuels, and Kevin Stiroh Harvard University, Resources.
The Changing Shape of UK Manufacturing Joe Grice, Director and Chief Economist.
R&D as a Value Creating Asset Emma Edworthy Gavin Wallis.
Industrial policy, Structural Change, and Pattern of Industrial Productivity Growth in Taiwan 1 Tsu-tan Fu Department of Economics & Center for Efficiency.
Overview of CSO Business Demography release Workshop on Business Demography and Job Churn statistics Dublin Castle, May 12 th 2011 Jillian Delaney.
1 The Industry Origins of the Second Surge of U.S. Productivity Growth Kevin J. Stiroh* Federal Reserve Bank of New York May 2006 *These comments are the.
The impact of intangible assets on regional productivity disparities in Great Britain Konstantinos Melachroinos & Nigel Spence School of Geography Queen.
ECON 6012 Cost Benefit Analysis Memorial University of Newfoundland
[ 1 ] MIGRATION AND PRODUCTIVITY. LESSONS FROM THE UK-SPAIN EXPERIENCES This project is funded by the European Commission, Research Directorate General.
Metal Industries 2012 * Structure and current developments Crisis and transformation Situation of the MET industries Labour Market: main developments Major.
Labour Market Flexibility and Sectoral Productivity: A Comparative Study John Grahl London Metropolitan University Labour Market.
1 ITFD Growth and Development LECTURE SLIDES SET 5 Professor Antonio Ciccone.
Ifo Institute for Economic Research ICT, SKILLS AND GERMAN INDUSTRY PRODUCTIVITY – The Interdependency of High-Skilled Labor and ICT Investments Thomas.
Copyright 2010, The World Bank Group. All Rights Reserved. Introduction to the System of National Accounts (SNA) Lesson 9 Data Sources for Estimating GDP.
ICT adoption in developing countries: firm-level evidence from Brazil and India Simon Commander (LBS) Rupert Harrison (IFS) 1 st June 2006.
Jukka Pekkarinen Technology frontier: A comment ”Quality of tertiary education and the economic policy agenda”, Ljubljana, April 2, 2008.
Trade Dynamics in the Euro Area: A Disaggregated Approach DNB/IMF Workshop Preventing and Correcting Macroeconomic Imbalances in the Euro Area 14 October.
Trade with China and skill upgrading: Evidence from Belgium Firm-Level Data G. Mion, H. Vandenbussche, L. Zhu.
Impact of Regulatory and Institutional Changes on Plant-level Productivity and Technical Efficiency: Evidence from the Indian Manufacturing Sector Sumon.
Patterns of Industrialization and effects of country-specific conditions IPD/JICA Task Force on Industrial Policy and Transformation Jordan, June 5-6,
Chapter 6 The Theory and Estimation of Production
Infrastructure and Long Run Economic Growth David Canning Infrastructure and Growth: Theory, Empirical Evidence and policy Lessons Cape Town May.
It Ain’t What You Do It’s The Way That You Do I.T.: Investigating the Productivity Miracle using Multinationals* Bank of England, February 2006 Nick Bloom,
ICT, Corporate Restructuring and Productivity Laura Abramovsky Rachel Griffith IFS and UCL ZEW – November 2007 Workshop on Innovative Capabilities and.
AMERICANS DO I.T. BETTER: US Multinationals and the Productivity Miracle John Van Reenen, Department of Economics, LSE; Director of the Centre for Economic.
Inflation Report May Output and supply Chart 3.1 Whole-economy output (a) (a) Chained-volume measure of gross value added at basic prices
The Industry Life-Cycle and Acquisitions and Investment: Does Firm Organization Matter? Vojislav Maksimovic Gordon Phillips University of Maryland.
The Effect of Privatization and Competitive Pressure on Firms’ Price-Cost Margins Micro Evidence from Emerging Economies Jozef Konings, Patrick Van Cayseele.
WORKSHOP ON TEACHING AND RESEARCH OF TRADE AND POVERTY: Conceptual and Methodological approaches and Policy Implications Peacock, Hotel, Dar-es-Salaam,
Nick Bloom, Macro Topics, Spring 2007 Nick Bloom The US Productivity Miracle Associated class reading: Atkenson & Kehoe (2007)
C e ntre for Research into Business Activity Information Technology, Organisational Change and Productivity Growth: Evidence from UK.
Brixen, September 09 Heterogeneous Responses of Firms to Import Protection Journal of International Economics by Jozef Konings (*) and Hylke Vandenbussche.
The Industry Life-Cycle and Financial Dependence: Does Firm Organization Matter? Vojislav Maksimovic Gordon Phillips University of Maryland.
Lecture 1: Trade and Labour H. Vandenbussche. Research questions Link between imports from low-wage countries and firm-level employment growth? Link between.
THE IMPACT OF INTERNATIONAL OUTSOURCING ON EMPLOYMENT: EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE FROM EU COUNTRIES Martin Falk and Yvonne Wolfmayr Austrian Institute of Economic.
Export Spillovers from FDI: Evidence from Polish firm-level data Andrzej Cieślik (University of Warsaw) Jan Hagemejer (National Bank of Poland)
China’s Competitive Threat A Sector Perspective Presented by Mark Killion, CFA Managing Director Global Insight’s World Industry Services.
Page 1 Digital Transformations A Research Programme at London Business School Funded by the Leverhulme Trust “Why is there no New Economy in Old Europe?”
Outsourcing and U.S. Economic Growth: The Role of Imported Intermediate Inputs Christopher Kurz, Paul Lengermann Federal Reserve Board of Governors* World.
FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENTS AND INDUSTRIAL POLICY A COMPARISON OF RESULTS BETWEEN SLOVENIA AND HUNGARY Albert Puig GATE (Analysis Group in Economic Transition)
A good measure of productivity Eric Bartelsman Vrije Universiteit Amsterdam and Tinbergen Institute Washington, World Bank, October 31, 2005.
Estimating the Causal Effect of Access to Public Credit on Productivity: the case of Brazil Eduardo P. Ribeiro (IE – UFRJ, Brazil) João A. De Negri (IPEA,
MALAYSIA KLEMS: PRODUCTIVITY PERFORMANCE THE 2 ND ASIA KLEMS DATABASE MANAGEMENT WORKSHOP 17 OCTOBER 2014 Mazlina Shafi’i Wan Fazlin Nadia Wan Osman Malaysia.
Estimating productivity when labor is a dynamic input Xulia González Daniel Miles Universidad de Vigo (Spain) Very preliminar.
China KLEMS Database —— The 2 nd Asia KLEMS Database Management workshop Ren Ruoen Sun Linlin Fan Maoqing Zheng Haitao Li xiaoqin.
Comparison of Estimation Methods for Agricultural Productivity Yu Sheng ABARES the Superlative vs. the Quantity- based Index Approach August 2015.
The economic implications of Brexit for Scotland
Impacts of Oil Price Changes Korea Development Institute
EU-KLEMS project: Progress in Economic Underpinnings and Measurement
Productivity Growth and Resource Reallocation Effects in Taiwan: Tsu-tan Fu, Soochow University Yih-ming Lin, National Chiayi University.
© The Author(s) Published by Science and Education Publishing.
Hosein Joshaghani PhD in economics at the University of Chicago
For the World Economy Availability of business services and outward investment: Evidence from French firms Holger Görg Kiel Institute for the World Economy,
PROXIMITY AND INVESTMENT: EVIDENCE FROM PLANT-LEVEL DATA
Sven Blank (University of Tübingen)
Presentation transcript:

It Ain’t What You Do It’s The Way That You Do I.T.: Investigating the US Productivity Miracle using Multinationals John Van Reenen, Department of Economics, LSE; Director of the Centre for Economic Performance, NBER & CEPR Nick Bloom, Stanford, CEP & NBER Raffaella Sadun, LSE & CEP

European productivity had been catching up with the US for 50 years…

…but since 1995 US productivity accelerated away again from Europe.

The US resurgence is known as the “productivity miracle”.

The “productivity miracle” started as quality adjusted computer price falls started to accelerate.

Source: Oliner and Sichel (2000, 2005) See also Jorgenson (2001, AER) and Stiroh (2002, AER) Interestingly, in the US the “miracle” appears linked in particular to the “IT using” sectors…

- 3 Change in annual growth in output per hour from 1990–95 to 1995–2001 % ICT - using sectors ICT - producing sectors Non - ICT sectors U.S EU Increase in annual growth rate–from 1.2% in 1990–95 to 4.7% from 1995 Static growth–at around 2% a year– during the early and late 1990s … but no acceleration of productivity growth in Europe in the same IT using sectors. Source: O’Mahony and Van Ark (2003, Gronnigen Data and European Commission)

And Europe also did not have the same IT investment boom as the US

Question Why did the US achieve a productivity miracle and not Europe? Two types of arguments proposed (not mutually exclusive): 1) Standard: US advantage lies in geographic/business environment (e.g. less planning regulation, faster demand growth, larger market size, better skills, younger labor force, etc.) 2) Alternative: US advantage lies in their firm organization/management practices (e.g. Martin Bailey) Paper will present micro evidence from UK data that supports (2) -Key idea is to look within one country (holds environment constant) but look across US multinationals vs. non-US MNEs

Summary of Results New micro data - unbalanced panel of c.11,000 establishments located in UK –US multinationals (MNE) more productive than non-US multinationals –US establishments have more IT capital, but higher US productivity mainly due to higher returns to IT Also true for US takeovers of UK establishments Result driven by “IT using” sectors Rationalize the results with a simple model –Common production function (IT-org complementarity) –But lower adjustment costs of changing organization in US relative to Europe

Macro facts and motivation New micro results Our intuition and a possible model Conclusion

Why use UK micro data? The UK has a lot of multinational activity –In our sample, 40% plants are multinational (10% US, 30% non-US) –Frequent M&A generates lots of ownership change No productivity acceleration in UK UK census data is excellent for this purpose –Data on IT and productivity for manufacturing and services (where much of the “US miracle” occurred) –Combined 4 unused surveys of IT expenditure with ABI (like US LRD) –About 23,000 observations from 1995 to 2003

Stiroh/Van Ark “IT Intensive / Non-Intensive” and Services / Manufacturing split IT Intensive# obsIT non-intensive# obs Wholesale trade2620Food, drink and tobacco1116 Retail trade1399Hotels & catering1012 Machinery and equipment 736Construction993 Printing and publishing 639Supporting transport services (travel agencies) 740 Professional business services 489Real estate700 Industries (SIC-2) in blue are services and in black are manufacturing

Preliminary figures already show US multinationals are particularly different in terms of IT use Observations: 576 US; 2228 other MNE; 4770 Domestic UK % difference from 4 digit industry mean in 2001

Estimate a standard production function (in logs) for establishment i at time t: Where q = ln(Gross Output) a = ln(TFP) m = ln(Materials) l = ln(Labor) k = ln(Non-IT capital) c = ln(IT capital) Also include age, multi-plant dummy, region controls (z) Econometric Methodology (1)

TFP can depend on ownership (UK domestic is omitted base) Coefficient on factor J depends on ownership (and sector, h) Empirically, only IT coefficient varies significantly (table 2) US MNE Non-US MNE US MNE Non-US MNE Econometric Methodology (2)

Include full set of four-digit industry dummies interacted with year dummies to control for industry level shocks (e.g. output price differences) Main specifications also include establishment fixed effects Standard errors clustered by establishment Try to address endogeneity using GMM-SYS (Blundell and Bond, 1998, 2000) and Olley Pakes (1996) Also consider takeover sample (discuss below) Econometric Methodology (3): Other Issues

Dep Variableln(GO) SectorsAll IT UsingOthersIT UsingOthers Fixed effectsNo Yes Ln(C) 0.043***0.041***0.036***0.044***0.021***0.027*** US MNE *ln(C) **0.019** ***0.000 Non- US MNE*ln(C) * Ln(Materials) 0.538*** 0.614***0.501***0.559***0.411*** Ln(Non-IT K) 0.118*** 0.102***0.134***0.139***0.211*** Ln(Labour) 0.287***0.286***0.233***0.303***0.253***0.339*** US MNE 0.074*** ***0.014 Non-US MNE 0.041*** * Obs 22,736 7,87614,8607,87614,860 Table 1: IT Coefficient (C) by ownership status Note: All regression SE are clustered by establishment

All inputs interacted Another IT measure 1 TranslogWages (Skills) Value added Fixed effectsYesNoYes Dependent :ln(GO) ln(VA) Ln(C)0.0184***0.0385***0.0181*** *** USA*ln(C)0.0441***0.0311*0.0292***0.0163*0.0681*** MNE*ln(C) Ln(Wages)* Ln(C) Ln(Wages) ***- Obs7,8762,8597,8767,8727,876 Table 2: Robustness Checks (IT Intensive sectors) 1 log(No. of employees using a computer) from a matched computer use survey. Note: All columns estimated on IT intensive sample. All variables of Table 1 included (labour, non-IT, capital, materials,…). All regression SE clustered by establishment

Dep Variable ln(GO) Sectors All IT- intensive WholesaleRetail Rest of IT intensive Fixed effects Yes Ln(C)0.021***0.018***0.013***0.024*** US MNE *ln(C)0.029*** **0.025* Non- US MNE*ln(C) Ln(Materials)0.559***0.679***0.638***0.445*** Ln(Non-IT K)0.139***0.100***0.106***0.216*** Ln(Labour)0.253***0.177***0.219***0.311*** US MNE *** ***-0.163* Non-US MNE * Obs 7,8762,6201,3993,857 IT Intensive industries in more detail Note: All regression SE are clustered by establishment

Other Issues US firms have to “cross the Ocean” so have to be more efficient? Divide into EU and non-EU MNEs – no different US firms select into high IT sectors – use % of US establishments in 4 digit industry (col 7 table 2) Revenue productivity? But in standard Klette-Griliches this implies different coefficients on all factor inputs if US mark-ups different (col 2 of table 2) Unobserved US HQ inputs (e.g. software)? –But why larger than non-US MNE inputs –Software results –No significant interaction of IT with global firm size in UK sample –US firms global size same at median compared to non-US MNE global size Endogeneity of IT: GMM-SYS and Olley-Pakes

Worried about unobserved heterogeneity? Maybe US firms “cherry pick” plants with high IT productivity? Or maybe some kind of other unobserved difference So test by looking at production functions before and after establishment is take-over by US firms (compared to other takeovers) No difference before takeover. After takeover results look very similar to table 1 (and interesting dynamics)

Table 3: US Takeovers and IT Coefficients Note: All variables of Table 1 included, SE clustered by establishment Sample Before takeover Before takeover After takeover After takeover After takeover US MNE, all years *** NON- US MNE, all years ** US MNE*ln(C), all years * NON-US MNE*ln(C), all yrs US*ln(C), 1 year after TO US*ln(C), 2+ yrs after TO 0.038** NON-US*ln(C),1 yr after TO NON-US*ln(C), 2+ yrs after US MNE, 1 year after TO US MNE, 2+ yrs after TO NON-US, 1 year after TO NON-US, 2+ yrs after TO Obs2,365 3,353

Dep. Variable Ln(I IT ) Timing versus TOBeforeAfter US MNE, (all years) *** US MNE, (1 year after TO) 0.519*** US MNE, (2+ years after TO) 0.359** Non-US MNE ***0.223 Ln(Labour) 1.110***1.011***1.010*** Obs 2,3653,353 Table 4: US Takeovers and IT Investment US dummy significant higher than Non-US MNE dummy at 5% level Note: All variables of Table 1 included, firm clustered SE

Macro facts and motivation New micro results Our intuition and a possible model Conclusion

The US advantage is better organizational and managerial structures? Macro and micro estimates consistent with the idea of an unobserved factor which is: Complementary with IT Abundant in US firms relative to others We think the unobserved factor is the different organizational and managerial structure of US firms (see next slide)

European Firms US Firms Domestic Firms in Europe Non-US MNEs in Europe US MNEs in Europe Organizational devolvement European Firms US Firms Management practices Source: Bloom and Van Reenen (2006) survey of 732 firms in the US, UK, France and Germany. Differences between “US-multinational” and “Domestic” firms significant at 1% level in all panels except bottom left which is significant at the 10% level. Domestic Firms in Europe Non-US MNEs in Europe US MNEs in Europe Organizational devolvement (firms located in Europe) Management practices (firms located in Europe) US firms are organized and managed differently

Effective IT use appears associated with these different organizational (and managerial) practices 1.Econometric firm level evidence, i.e. Complementarity of IT and organizational practices in production functions (Bresnahan, Brynjolfsson & Hitt (QJE, 2002), Caroli and Van Reenen (QJE, 2002)) 2.Case study evidence, i.e. Introduction of ATMs & PCs in banking (Hunter, 2002) –Teller positions reduced due to ATM’s –“Personal banker” role expanded using CRM software and customer databases to cross-sell –Remaining staff have more responsibility, skills and decision making –Not all banks did this smoothly or successfully (e.g. much slower in EU)

Domestic Firms Non-US MNEs US MNEs Source: WIRS data (1984 and 1990) plots the proportion of establishments experiencing organizational change in previous 3 years (all establishments in the UK). US MNEs (N=190), Non-US MNEs (N=147), Domestic (N=2848). Senior manager is asked “whether there has been any change in work organization not involving new plant/equipment in the past three years” CIS data: we plot the proportion of establishments experiencing organizational or managerial change in previous 3 years. The firm is asked “Did your enterprize make major changes in the following areas of business structure and practices during the three year period ?” with answers to either “Advanced Management techniques” or “Major changes in organizational structure” recorded as an organizational change. Domestic Firms Non-US MNEs US MNEs Organizational change in the UK during (WIRS data) US multinationals also change their organizational structures more frequently Organizational change in the UK during (CIS data)

One simple way to model the all this macro, micro and survey data is based on three simple elements 1.IT is complementary with newer organizational/managerial structures 2.IT prices are falling rapidly, especially since 1995, increasing IT inputs 3.US “re-organizes” more quickly because more flexible Maybe because less labor market regulation and union restrictions

organizational structure (O) as an optimal choice (1) Firms optimally choose their organization between: –Old-style “Fordism”, complementary with physical capital –New style organizational structures complementary with IT (“decentralized”) Q = A C α+σO K β-σO L 1-α- β π = PQ- G(ΔO)- p c I C – p K I K – p L L Where: Q=Output, A=TFP, π=profits C = IT capital (I C = investment in IT), K = non-IT capital (I K =investment), L=Labor O=organizational structure (between 0 and 1) σ=Complementarity between IT and organizational structure G(ΔO)= Organizational adjustment costs

IT price and organizational adjustment (2) IT prices fall fast so firms want to re-organize quickly (3) But rapid re-organization is costly, with adjustment costs higher in EU than US, G(ΔO) = ω k (O t -O t-1 ) 2 + ηPQ| ΔO≠0| Quadratic cost with ω EU > ω US Fixed “Disruption” cost

Other details The model is: –“De-trended” so no baseline TFP growth –Deterministic so IT price path known –Allows for imperfect (monopolistic) competition –EU and US identical except organization adjustment costs In the long run US and EU the same, but transition dynamics different Solving the model –Almost everywhere unique continuous solution and policy correspondences: O*(O -1,P c ),K*(O -1,P c ),C*(O -1,P c ), L*(O -1,P c ) –But need numerical methods for precise parameterisation 1 1 Full Matlab code on

US re-organizes first due to lower adjustment costs US re-organizes, particularly as IT prices start falling rapidly Initially “centralized” best EU re-organizes later and more slowly

IT intensity (C/K) rises everywhere, but faster in US US decentralization increases optimal IT investment US EU

Decentralized US obtains higher labor productivity Note: Assumed baseline TFP equal in US and EU, with no TFP growth Higher IT inputs lead to higher productivity (Q/L), particularly in more decentralized US US EU

Extension: Multinationals What happens when a firm expands abroad? Assumption: Costly for multinationals to have different management and organizational structures (easier to integrate managers, HR, training, software etc. if org is similar across borders) Implication: Then US multinationals and EU multinationals abroad will adjust to their parent’s organizational structure Consistent with range of case-study evidence (e.g. Bartlett & Ghoshal, 1999, Muller-Camen et al. 2004) and true for well- known firms (P&G, Unilever, McKinsey, Starbucks etc..)

Plants rapidly reorganize after a US takeover US firm EU firmUS firm takes- over an EU firm Note: Assumes cost of non-alignment = sales x (O PARENT - O SUBSIDIARY ) 2

The model provides: 1.A rationale for differences in organizational structures between US and European firms 1.A simple way to interpret the macro stylized facts on productivity dynamics and IT investment in the US and Europe 1.A useful framework to link the micro findings on US multinationals active in the UK to the macro picture

Other extensions we consider to the model 1.Industry heterogeneity –If the degree of complementarity is higher in some sectors (e.g. “IT intensive using” industries) and zero in others, then these patterns will be sector specific –EU does just as well as US when no complementarity (σ = 0) 2.Adjustment costs for IT capital –Qualitative findings the same –TFP also will appear to grow faster in the transition 3.Permanent differences in management quality –Possible alternative story: US firms able to transfer management practices across international boundaries Q = A O ζ C α+σO K β - σO L 1-α- β- ζ -But implies a permanently higher US labor productivity even after controlling for IT level and higher coefficient -Can test using new management data we are collecting

Macro facts and motivation New micro results A possible model Conclusion

New micro evidence (cross section, panel and takeovers) –US establishments have higher TFP than non-US multinationals –This is almost all due to higher coefficient on IT (“the way that you do I.T.”) –Driven by same sectors responsible for US “productivity miracle” Micro, macro and survey findings consistent with a simple re- organization model –IT changes the optimal structure of the firm –So as IT prices fall firms want to restructure –Occurred in the US but much less in the EU (regulations) –When will the EU resume the catching up process?

Next Steps Bringing management and organizational data together with firm IT, organization and productivity data. New survey data following up Bloom and Van Reenen, 2006, forthcoming QJE. 12 countries (including China, Japan), 3,000+ firms Understanding determination of organizational decentralization (Acemoglu and Van Reenen et al, 2006) Structural estimation of the adjustment cost model (e.g. Simulated Method of Moments). See examples in Bloom, Bond and Van Reenen (forthcoming ReStud) More on IT endogeneity (e.g. broadband natural experiment)

Back Up

European Firms US Firms “Operations” management“Monitoring” management Source: Bloom and Van Reenen (2006) survey of 732 firms in the US, UK, France and Germany. “Targets” and “incentives” management differences significant at the 1% level. US firm also have different management “styles” “Targets” management“Incentives” management European Firms US Firms European Firms US Firms European Firms US Firms

Europe also did not have the same IT investment boom as the US

Non IT capital per hour worked

organization matters for the productivity of IT Source: Bresnahan, Brynjolfsson & Hitt (2002) “Information Technology, Workplace Organization and the Demand for skilled labor” Quarterly Journal of Economics

IT Capital Stocks Estimates Methodology Perpetual inventory method (PIM) to generate establishment level estimates of IT stocks Robustness test assumptions on: –Initial Conditions –Depreciation and deflation rates

IssueChoiceNotes Initial Conditions We do not observe all firms in their first year of activity. How do we approximate the existing capital stock? Use industry data (SIC2) and impute:  Similar to Martin (2002)  Industry IT capital stocks from NIESR  Robust to alternative methods Depreciation Rates How to choose δ ?Follow Oliner et al (2004) and set δ = 0.36 (obsolescence)  Basu and Oulton suggest Results not affected by alternative δ Deflators Need real investment to generate real capital Use NIESR hedonic deflators (based on US estimates)  Re-evaluation effects included in deflators Methodological Choices

Basic Production functions (Table A4) (at least 3 continuous time series observations)

Dep Variableln(GO) SectorsAll IT UsingOthersIT UsingOthers Fixed effectsNo Yes Ln (C) 0.043***0.041***0.036***0.044***0.021***0.027*** US MNE *ln(C) **0.019** ***0.000 Non- US MNE*ln(C) * Ln(Materials) 0.547***0.538*** 0.614***0.501***0.559***0.411*** Ln(Non-IT K) 0.130***0.118*** 0.102***0.134***0.139***0.211*** Ln(Labour) 0.315***0.287***0.286***0.233***0.303***0.253***0.339*** US MNE 0.085***0.074*** ***0.014 Non-US MNE 0.048***0.041*** * Obs 22,736 7,87614,8607,87614,860 Table 1: IT Coefficient by ownership status Note: All regression SE are clustered by establishment

BASIC PRODUCTION FUNCTION ESTIMATES, CONT. (TABLE A4) (1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7) Estimation MethodOLS, No FE OLS, FE OLS, FE GMM, Static GMM, Dynamic (Unrestricted) GMM COMFAC (Restricted) Olley-Pakes Dependent variable: ln(GO) = ln(Gross Output) Ln(C t ) ***0.0299***0.0265***0.0391***0.0656*0.0430**0.0204*** IT capital (0.0023)(0.0040)(0.0063)(0.0171)(0.0373)(0.0211)(0.0030) Ln(C t-1 ) IT capital, lagged (0.0242) Ln(M t ) ***0.4665***0.4702***0.3998***0.3293***0.3595***0.5562*** Materials (0.0080)(0.0193)(0.0283)(0.0402)(0.0750)(0.0494)(0.0102) Ln(M t-1 ) Materials, lagged (0.0534) Ln(K t ) ***0.1650***0.1953***0.1584***0.3618***0.2937***0.1511*** Non-IT Capital (0.0063)(0.0153)(0.0234)(0.0410)(0.0869)(0.0526)(0.0115) Ln(K t-1 ) ***- Non-IT Capital, lagged (0.0592) Ln(L t ) ***0.3177***0.2979***0.4158***0.2981***0.3524***0.2611*** Labour (0.0062)(0.0198)(0.0209)(0.0479)(0.0829)(0.0560) (0.0080) Ln(L t-1 ) Labour, lagged (0.0624) Ln(Y t-1 ) ***-- Gross Output, lagged (0.0581)

Other Notes on Results Higher coefficient on IT than expected from share in gross output, but not as large as Brynjolfsson and Hitt (2003) on US firm-level data (example of TFP specification over) Methodological and data differences from BH (e.g. firms vs. establishments; BH pre 1995 we are post 1995; we use standard investment method BH use stock survey; we have more observations) But may be because we are looking at different countries

TFP BASED SPECIFICATIONS (1)(2)(3)(4) Dependent variableΔln(TFP) Length of differencingfirstsecondthirdfourth (e.g. first differencing vs. longer differencing) SectorsAll ΔLn(C)0.0137***0.0150***0.0154***0.0155* IT capital (0.0022)(0.0030)(0.0057)(0.0082) Observations10,1224,

What do we expect in TFP regressions? MTFP, measured TFP is In our model “true” TFP is So we measure TFP correctly even in presence of O

Using micro data In the data the higher O firms will have higher C so on average coefficient on C is positive in TFP regressions unless we use exact factor share of C by firm. On average, US firms will have no higher coefficient on C in TFP equation if we use the US revenue share Extensions –Allow adjustment costs on C. Implies that IT share “too low” when calculating TFP, so measured TFP higher for high O firms

What do we expect in TFP regressions?

Precise parameterization variableMnemonicValueReference C coefficient (IT capital) α0.025Share of IT in value added K coefficientβ0.3Share of capital costs in value added Complementarityσ0.017α (1-e -1 ) Mark-up (p-mc)/mc1/(e-1)0.5Hall (1988) Relative quadratic adjustment cost of O ω EU /ω US 4Nicoletti and Scarpetta (2003) Disruption cost of O (as a % of sales) η0.2%Bloom (2006), Cooper & Haltiwanger (2003) IT pricespcpc -15% p.a. until 1995 then -30% BLS

Table A1 BREAKDOWN OF INDUSTRIES (1 of 3) IT Intensive (Using Sectors) IT-using manufacturing 18 Wearing apparel, dressing and dying of fur 22 Printing and publishing 29 Machinery and equipment 31, excl. 313 Electrical machinery and apparatus, excluding insulated wire 33, excl. 331 Precision and optical instruments, excluding IT instruments 351 Building and repairing of ships and boats 353 Aircraft and spacecraft Railroad equipment and transport equipment miscellaneous manufacturing and recycling IT-using services 51 Wholesale trades 52 Retail trade 71 Renting of machinery and equipment 73 Research and development Professional business services

BREAKDOWN OF INDUSTRIES (2 of 3) Non- IT Intensive (Using Sectors) Non-IT intensive manufacturing Food drink and tobacco 17 Textiles 19 Leather and footwear 20 wood 21pulp and paper 23 mineral oil refining, coke and nuclear 24 chemicals 25 rubber and plastics 26 non-metallic mineral products 27 basic metals 28 fabricated metal products 34 motor vehicles Non-IT Services 50 sale, maintenance and repair of motor vehicles 55 hotels and catering 60 Inland transport 61 Water transport 62 Air transport 63 Supporting transport services, and travel agencies 70 Real estate 749 Other business activities n.e.c Other community, social and personal services 95 Private Household 99 Extra-territorial organizations Non-IT intensive other sectors 01 Agriculture 02 Forestry 05 Fishing Mining and quarrying Utilities 45 Construction

BREAKDOWN OF INDUSTRIES (3 of 3) IT Producing Sectors IT Producing manufacturing 30 Office Machinery 313 Insulated wire 321 Electronic valves and tubes 322 Telecom equipment 323 radio and TV receivers 331 scientific instruments IT producing services 64 Communications 72 Computer services and related activity