Utility Maximization and Choice

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE
Advertisements

UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE
UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE
Choice.
AAEC 2305 Fundamentals of Ag Economics Chapter 2 Economics of Demand.
Indifference Curves and
Consumer Behavior Esa Unggul University Budget Constraints Preferences do not explain all of consumer behavior. Budget constraints also limit an.
Chapter 3 A Consumer’s Constrained Choice If this is coffee, please bring me some tea; but if this is tea, please bring me some coffee. Abraham Lincoln.
©2005, Southwestern Slides by Pamela L. Hall Western Washington University Utility Maximization Chapter 3.
A Consumer Constrained Choice
PREFERENCES AND UTILITY
Quick Reminder of the Theory of Consumer Choice Professor Roberto Chang Rutgers University January 2007.
Theory of Consumer Behavior
DEMAND RELATIONSHIPS AMONG GOODS
Part 2 Demand © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western.
INCOME AND SUBSTITUTION EFFECTS
Theory of Consumer Behavior Basics of micro theory: how individuals choose what to consume when faced with limited income? Components of consumer demand.
Changes in Income An increase in income will cause the budget constraint out in a parallel manner An increase in income will cause the budget constraint.
Chapter 20: Consumer Choice
Chapter 5: Theory of Consumer Behavior
1 Chapter 3 PREFERENCES AND UTILITY Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
INCOME AND SUBSTITUTION EFFECTS
Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization
Chapter 3 A Consumer’s Constrained Choice
Theory of Consumer Behavior
Lecture # 2 Review Go over Homework Sets #1 & #2 Consumer Behavior APPLIED ECONOMICS FOR BUSINESS MANAGEMENT.
Module 12: Indifference Curves and Budget Constraints
INCOME AND SUBSTITUTION EFFECTS
DEMAND RELATIONSHIPS AMONG GOODS
BACHELOR OF ARTS IN ECONOMICS Econ 111 – ECONOMIC ANALYSIS Pangasinan State University Social Science Department – PSU Lingayen CHAPTER 7 CONSUMER BEHAVIOR.
Chapter Five Choice 选择. Structure 5.1 The optimal choice of consumers 5.2 Consumer demand  Interior solution (内解)  Corner solution (角解)  “Kinky” solution.
Chapter 5 Choice.
Lecture 3: Consumer BehaviorSlide 1 Topics to be Discussed Consumer Preferences Budget Constraints Consumer Choice.
Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior. Chapter 32©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Introduction How are consumer preferences used to determine demand? How do consumers.
Microeconomics Pre-sessional September 2015 Sotiris Georganas Economics Department City University London.
Chapter 3 A Consumer’s Constrained Choice
Copyright (c) 2000 by Harcourt, Inc. All rights reserved. Utility The pleasure people get from their economic activity. To identify all of the factors.
Objectives:  Use the utility-maximizing model to explain how consumers choose goods and services.  Use the concept of utility to explain how the law.
Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior. Chapter 3: Consumer BehaviorSlide 2 Topics to be Discussed Consumer Preferences Budget Constraints Consumer Choice Marginal.
Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior. Chapter 3: Consumer BehaviorSlide 2 Topics to be Discussed Consumer Preferences Budget Constraints Consumer Choice Revealed.
Lecture 7 Consumer Behavior Required Text: Frank and Bernanke – Chapter 5.
1 Consumer Choice and Demand CHAPTER 6 © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
Consumer Behavior & Utility Maximization ECO 2023 Chapter 7 Fall 2007 Created by: M. Mari.
1 Chapter 4 UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
1 Chapter 3 PREFERENCES AND UTILITY Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
Consumer Behavior and Utility Maximization 21 C H A P T E R.
Copyright 2011The McGraw-Hill Companies 5-1 Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility Theory of Consumer Behavior Deriving the Demand Curve Applications and.
CHAPTER 2 UTILITY AND CHOICE. Objective Build a model to understand how a consumer makes decisions under scarcity. To understand his choice we need to.
Consumer Choice Preferences, Budgets, and Optimization.
Lecture 4 Consumer Behavior Recommended Text: Franks and Bernanke - Chapter 5.
Chapter 5 Choice Budget set + preference → choice Optimal choice: choose the best one can afford. Suppose the consumer chooses bundle A. A is optimal (A.
Chapter 5 CHOICE.
Chapter 5 CHOICE.
Recall: Consumer behavior Why are we interested? –New good in the market. What price should be charged? How much more for a premium brand? –Subsidy program:
Chapter Four Consumer Choice Chapter Four. Chapter Four Consumer Choice Chapter Four.
 This will explain how consumers allocate their income over many goods.  This looks at individual’s decision making when faced with limited income and.
1 Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization CHAPTER 6 Appendix © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2013 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Chapter 5 Theory of Consumer Behavior.
Course: Microeconomics Text: Varian’s Intermediate Microeconomics
Utility Maximization and Choice
Chapter 5 Theory of Consumer Behavior
Theory of Consumer Behavior
Theory of Consumer Behavior
Chapter 5.
Theory of Consumer Behavior
Chapter 5: Theory of Consumer Behavior
Chapter 5: Theory of Consumer Behavior
Presentation transcript:

Utility Maximization and Choice Chapter 4 Utility Maximization and Choice

Complaints about the Economic Approach Do individuals make the “lightning calculations” required for utility maximization? the utility-maximization model predicts many aspects of behavior economists assume that people behave as if they made such calculations

Complaints about the Economic Approach The economic model of choice is extremely selfish nothing in the model prevents individuals from getting satisfaction from “doing good”

Optimization Principle To maximize utility, given a fixed amount of income, an individual will buy the goods and services: that exhaust total income for which the MRS is equal to the rate at which goods can be traded for one another in the marketplace

A Numerical Illustration Assume that the individual’s MRS = 1 willing to trade one unit of x for one unit of y Suppose the price of x = $2 and the price of y = $1 The individual can be made better off trade 1 unit of x for 2 units of y in the marketplace

The Budget Constraint Assume that an individual has I dollars to allocate between good x and good y pxx + pyy  I Quantity of y The individual can afford to choose only combinations of x and y in the shaded triangle If all income is spent on y, this is the amount of y that can be purchased If all income is spent on x, this is the amount of x that can be purchased Quantity of x

FOCs for a Maximum We can add the individual’s utility map to show the utility-maximization process Quantity of y U1 A The individual can do better than point A by reallocating his budget U3 C The individual cannot have point C because income is not large enough U2 B Point B is the point of utility maximization Quantity of x

FOCs for a Maximum Utility is maximized where the indifference curve is tangent to the budget constraint Quantity of y B U2 Quantity of x

SOCs for a Maximum The tangency rule is necessary but not sufficient unless we assume that MRS is diminishing if MRS is diminishing, then indifference curves are strictly convex if MRS is not diminishing, we must check second-order conditions to ensure that we are at a maximum

SOCs for a Maximum The tangency rule is only a necessary condition we need MRS to be diminishing Quantity of y U1 B U2 A There is a tangency at point A, but the individual can reach a higher level of utility at point B Quantity of x

Corner Solutions Individuals may maximize utility by choosing to consume only one of the goods At point A, the indifference curve is not tangent to the budget constraint Quantity of y U2 U1 U3 A Utility is maximized at point A Quantity of x

ℒ = U(x1,x2,…,xn) + (I - p1x1 - p2x2 -…- pnxn) The n-Good Case The individual’s objective is to maximize utility = U(x1,x2,…,xn) subject to the budget constraint I = p1x1 + p2x2 +…+ pnxn Set up the Lagrangian: ℒ = U(x1,x2,…,xn) + (I - p1x1 - p2x2 -…- pnxn)

ℒ / = I - p1x1 - p2x2 - … - pnxn = 0 The n-Good Case FOCs for an interior maximum: ℒ/x1 = U/x1 - p1 = 0 ℒ /x2 = U/x2 - p2 = 0 • ℒ /xn = U/xn - pn = 0 ℒ / = I - p1x1 - p2x2 - … - pnxn = 0

Implications of FOCs For any two goods, This implies that at the optimal allocation of income

Interpreting the Lagrangian Multiplier  is the marginal utility of an extra dollar of consumption expenditure the marginal utility of income

Interpreting the Lagrangian Multiplier At the margin, the price of a good represents the consumer’s evaluation of the utility of the last unit consumed how much the consumer is willing to pay for the last unit

ℒ/xi = U/xi - pi  0 (i = 1,…,n) Corner Solutions A corner solution means that the first-order conditions must be modified: ℒ/xi = U/xi - pi  0 (i = 1,…,n) If ℒ/xi = U/xi - pi < 0, then xi = 0 This means that any good whose price exceeds its marginal value to the consumer will not be purchased

Cobb-Douglas Demand Functions Cobb-Douglas utility function: U(x,y) = xy Setting up the Lagrangian: ℒ = xy + (I - pxx - pyy) FOCs: ℒ/x = x-1y - px = 0 ℒ/y = xy-1 - py = 0 ℒ/ = I - pxx - pyy = 0

Cobb-Douglas Demand Functions First-order conditions imply: y/x = px/py Since  +  = 1: pyy = (/)pxx = [(1- )/]pxx Substituting into the budget constraint: I = pxx + [(1- )/]pxx = (1/)pxx

Cobb-Douglas Demand Functions Solving for x yields Solving for y yields The individual will allocate  percent of his income to good x and  percent of his income to good y

Cobb-Douglas Demand Functions Cobb-Douglas utility function is limited in its ability to explain actual consumption behavior the share of income devoted to a good often changes in response to changing economic conditions A more general functional form might be more useful

CES Demand Assume that  = 0.5 Setting up the Lagrangian: FOCs: U(x,y) = x0.5 + y0.5 Setting up the Lagrangian: ℒ = x0.5 + y0.5 + (I - pxx - pyy) FOCs: ℒ/x = 0.5x -0.5 - px = 0 ℒ/y = 0.5y -0.5 - py = 0 ℒ/ = I - pxx - pyy = 0

CES Demand This means that (y/x)0.5 = px/py Substituting into the budget constraint, we can solve for the demand functions

CES Demand In these demand functions, the share of income spent on either x or y is not a constant depends on the ratio of the two prices The higher is the relative price of x, the smaller will be the share of income spent on x

CES Demand If  = -1, The demand functions are U(x,y) = -x -1 - y -1 First-order conditions imply that y/x = (px/py)0.5 The demand functions are

I = pxx + pyy = pxx + py(x/4) CES Demand If  = -, U(x,y) = Min(x,4y) The person will choose only combinations for which x = 4y This means that I = pxx + pyy = pxx + py(x/4) I = (px + 0.25py)x

CES Demand Hence, the demand functions are

Indirect Utility Function It is often possible to manipulate first-order conditions to solve for optimal values of x1,x2,…,xn These optimal values will be • x*n = xn(p1,p2,…,pn,I) x*1 = x1(p1,p2,…,pn,I) x*2 = x2(p1,p2,…,pn,I)

Indirect Utility Function We can use the optimal values of the x’s to find the indirect utility function maximum utility = U(x*1,x*2,…,x*n) maximum utility = V(p1,p2,…,pn,I) The optimal level of utility will depend indirectly on prices and income

The Lump Sum Principle Taxes on an individual’s general purchasing power are superior to taxes on a specific good an income tax allows the individual to decide freely how to allocate remaining income a tax on a specific good will reduce an individual’s purchasing power and distort his choices

The Lump Sum Principle A tax on good x would shift the utility-maximizing choice from point A to point B B U2 Quantity of y A U1 Quantity of x

The Lump Sum Principle An income tax that collected the same amount would shift the budget constraint to I’ I’ Quantity of y Utility is maximized now at point C on U3 U3 C A B U1 U2 Quantity of x

The Lump Sum Principle If the utility function is Cobb-Douglas with  =  = 0.5, we know that The indirect utility function is

The Lump Sum Principle If a tax of $1 was imposed on good x the individual will purchase x* = 2 indirect utility will fall from 2 to 1.41 An equal-revenue tax will reduce income to $6 indirect utility will fall from 2 to 1.5

The Lump Sum Principle If the utility function is fixed proportions with U = Min(x,4y), we know that The indirect utility function is

The Lump Sum Principle If a tax of $1 was imposed on good x indirect utility will fall from 4 to 8/3 An equal-revenue tax will reduce income to $16/3 Since preferences are rigid, the tax on x does not distort choices

Expenditure Minimization Dual minimization problem for utility maximization allocate income to achieve a given level of utility with the minimal expenditure the goal and the constraint have been reversed

Expenditure Minimization Point A is the solution to the dual problem Expenditure level E2 provides just enough to reach U1 Quantity of y Expenditure level E3 will allow the individual to reach U1 but is not the minimal expenditure required to do so Expenditure level E1 is too small to achieve U1 U1 Quantity of x

Expenditure Minimization The individual’s problem is to choose x1,x2,…,xn to minimize total expenditures = E = p1x1 + p2x2 +…+ pnxn subject to the constraint utility = Ū = U(x1,x2,…,xn) The optimal amounts of x1,x2,…,xn will depend on the prices of the goods and the required utility level

minimal expenditures = E(p1,p2,…,pn,U) Expenditure Function The expenditure function shows the minimal expenditures necessary to achieve a given utility level for a particular set of prices minimal expenditures = E(p1,p2,…,pn,U) The expenditure function and the indirect utility function are inversely related both depend on market prices but involve different constraints

Two Expenditure Functions The indirect utility function in the two-good, Cobb-Douglas case is If we interchange the role of utility and income (expenditure), we will have the expenditure function E(px,py,U) = 2px0.5py0.5U

Two Expenditure Functions For the fixed-proportions case, the indirect utility function is If we again switch the role of utility and expenditures, we will have the expenditure function E(px,py,U) = (px + 0.25py)U

Properties of Expenditure Functions Homogeneity a doubling of all prices will precisely double the value of required expenditures homogeneous of degree one Nondecreasing in prices E/pi  0 for every good, i Concave in prices

Concavity of Expenditure Function At p*1, the person spends E(p*1,…) E(p*1,…) p*1 Epseudo If he continues to buy the same set of goods as p*1 changes, his expenditure function would be Epseudo E(p1,…) E(p1,…) Since his consumption pattern will likely change, actual expenditures will be less than Epseudo such as E(p1,…) p1

Important Points to Note: To reach a constrained maximum, an individual should: spend all available income choose a commodity bundle such that the MRS between any two goods is equal to the ratio of the goods’ prices the individual will equate the ratios of the marginal utility to price for every good that is actually consumed

Important Points to Note: Tangency conditions are only first-order conditions the individual’s indifference map must exhibit diminishing MRS the utility function must be strictly quasi-concave

Important Points to Note: Tangency conditions must also be modified to allow for corner solutions the ratio of marginal utility to price will be below the common marginal benefit-marginal cost ratio for goods actually bought

Important Points to Note: The individual’s optimal choices implicitly depend on the parameters of his budget constraint observed choices and utility will be implicit functions of prices and income

Important Points to Note: The dual problem to the constrained utility-maximization problem is to minimize the expenditure required to reach a given utility target yields the same optimal solution leads to expenditure functions spending is a function of the utility target and prices