Consumption Prof Mike Kennedy. Where we are going? Here we will be looking at two major components of aggregate demand: – Aggregate consumption or what.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
3. Goods market equilibrium: the IS curve.
Advertisements

Aggregate Expenditure CHAPTER 30 C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to 1 Distinguish.
Budget Today or Tomorrow
1 Interest Rate Determination Here we start with an example and end with a theory of changes in the interest rate.
Investment and Saving Decisions
Intertemporal Approach to the Current Account Part 2.
1 MACROECONOMICS AND THE GLOBAL BUSINESS ENVIRONMENT Consumption and Saving 2 nd edition.
© 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved Appendix 4.A A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving.
© The McGraw-Hill Companies, 2005 Advanced Macroeconomics Chapter 16 CONSUMPTION, INCOME AND WEALTH.
Chapter 4: Consumption, Saving , and Investment
Expectations and our IS-LM model In this lecture we will examine how expectations about the future will impact investment and consumption today. We will.
1 Aggregate Expenditure Components CHAPTER 9 © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 9 The IS Curve.
The Influence of Monetary and Fiscal Policy on Aggregate Demand
1 Basic Macroeconomic Relationships. 2 Overview Here we study some basic economic relationships that we think hold in a general way in the economy. Here.
Output and the Exchange Rate in the Short Run. Introduction Long run models are useful when all prices of inputs and outputs have time to adjust. In the.
Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education Canada
The Influence of Monetary and Fiscal Policy on Aggregate Demand Chapter 32 Copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. All rights reserved. Requests for permission.
8 CAPITAL, INVESTMENT, AND SAVING CHAPTER.
Consumption & Saving Chapter 13. East Asian Savings Rates  As a region, East Asia has high savings rates. These high savings rates have helped finance.
Consumption, Saving, and Investment
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 3 Spending, Income, and Interest Rates.
Slide Show #4 AGEC 430 Macroeconomics of Agriculture Spring 2010.
1 of 11 PART III The Core of Macroeconomic Theory © 2012 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Prepared by: Fernando Quijano & Shelly Tefft.
Source: Mankiw (2000) Macroeconomics, Chapter 3 p Determinants of Demand for Goods and Services Examine: how the output from production is used.
... are the markets in the economy that help to match one person’s saving with another person’s investment. ... move the economy’s scarce resources.
V PART The Core of Macroeconomic Theory.
Appendix 4.A A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving.
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 8 A Two-Period Model: The Consumption– Savings Decision and Credit Markets.
Assumptions for discussion on this topic In our class on National Income we saw that output Y = C + I + G + NX We shall ignore NX. This means we are assuming.
© 2008 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., All Rights Reserved.
Review of the previous lecture In the long run, the aggregate supply curve is vertical. The short-run, the aggregate supply curve is upward sloping. The.
Principles of Microeconomics
This chapter presents:

AGGREGATE EXPENDITURE AND EQUILIBRIUM OUTPUT
© 2007 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics 8e by Case and Fair Prepared by: Fernando & Yvonn Quijano 21 Chapter PART V THE GOODS.
1 Lecture 8 The Keynesian Theory of Consumption Other Determinants of Consumption Planned Investment (I) The Determination of Equilibrium Output (Income)
1 of 33 © 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. CHAPTER OUTLINE 8 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output The Keynesian Theory of Consumption Other Determinants.
The Economy in the Short-run
Income and Spending Chapter #10 (DFS)
Chapter 15. Consumption, income and wealth ECON320 Prof Mike Kennedy.
CHAPTER 12 Expenditure Multipliers
Economics 202 Principles Of Macroeconomics Lecture 10 Investment, Savings and the Real Interest Rate The role of the Government Savings and Investment.
Test Review Econ 322 Test Review Test 1 Chapters 1,2,8,3,4,7.
Macroeconomics Econ 2301 Dr. Frank Jacobson Coach Stuckey Chapter 11.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western. The Influence of Monetary and Fiscal Policy on Aggregate Demand Many factors influence aggregate demand besides monetary.
Copyright © 2004 South-Western 34 The Influence of Monetary and Fiscal Policy on Aggregate Demand.
1 Chapter 4 Prof. Dr. Mohamed I. Migdad Professor in Economics 2015.
© 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved 4-1 Chapter Outline Consumption and Saving Investment Goods Market Equilibrium Chapter 4 Consumption,
Lecture 3 Consumption. John M. Keynes: Absolute Income Hypothesis Consumption is a linear function of disposable personal income, C = C + cY C = consumption.
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 3 Income and Interest Rates: The Keynesian Cross Model and the IS Curve.
1 of 27 The level of GDP, the overall price level, and the level of employment—three chief concerns of macroeconomists—are influenced by events in three.
Chapter 21: The Simplest Short-Run Macro Model Copyright © 2014 Pearson Canada Inc.
Investment and Saving Prof Mike Kennedy. Investment There is a trade-off between the present and the future. A firm commits its resources to increasing.
1 Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization CHAPTER 6 Appendix © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
7 AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY CHAPTER.
Copyright © 2004 South-Western 34 The Influence of Monetary and Fiscal Policy on Aggregate Demand.
© 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved Consumption, Saving, and Investment Chapter 4.
The Short – Run Macro Model
Chapter 9 A Two-Period Model: The Consumption-Savings Decision and Credit Markets Macroeconomics 6th Edition Stephen D. Williamson Copyright © 2018, 2015,
Chapter 23: Output and Prices in the Short Run
CASE FAIR OSTER MACROECONOMICS P R I N C I P L E S O F
A Formal Model of Consumption and Saving
PowerPoint Lectures for Principles of Economics, 9e
PowerPoint Lectures for Principles of Economics, 9e
PowerPoint Lectures for Principles of Economics, 9e
Abel & Bernake: Macro Ch3 Varian: Micro Ch10
PowerPoint Lectures for Principles of Macroeconomics, 9e
Presentation transcript:

Consumption Prof Mike Kennedy

Where we are going? Here we will be looking at two major components of aggregate demand: – Aggregate consumption or what is the same thing aggregate saving; and – Investment by firms (in the next lecture). We want to develop a view as to how goods market equilibrium is determined. In Chapter 3 we saw how the supply of goods and services is determined we now turn to demand.

Consumption and its major components

Another look at the components of consumption

Consumption and Saving Changes in consumers’ willingness to spend have major implications for the behaviour of the economy. – Consumption accounts for about 55 to 60% of total spending. – The decisions to consume and to save are closely linked.

Consumption and Saving (continued) Desired consumption (C d ) is the aggregate quantity of goods and services that households want to consume, given income and other factors. Desired national saving (S d ) is the level of national saving that occurs when aggregate consumption is at its desired level. When NFP=0, national saving is: S = Y – C – G Then, desired national saving is: S d = Y – C d – G Remember this is the total of private and government saving.

The Consumption and Saving Decision – some preliminaries A lender can earn, and a borrower will have to pay, a real interest rate of r per year. 1 dollar’s worth of consumption today is equivalent to 1 + r dollar’s worth of consumption in the next time period. If I consume $1 today, my saving is lower by that amount and I will have $1(1 + r) less to consume in the future. Therefore 1 + r is the price of a dollar of current consumption in terms of future consumption – it is what you give up tomorrow when you consume today.

The Consumption and Saving Decision (continued) The consumption-smoothing motive is the desire to have a relatively even pattern of consumption over time. This seems to be consistent with observed behaviour. A good part of a one-time income bonus is likely to be saved and the income earned on that saving spread over time.

Changes in Current Income Marginal propensity to consume (MPC) is the fraction of additional current income that is consumed in the current period. When Y rises by 1: – C d typically rises by less than 1; – S d rises by the fraction of 1 not spent on consumption.

A Formal Treatment of Desired Consumption This part of the lecture follows closely Appendix 4.A (in the 4 th edition) and which is on the website. We will treat a simple economy with two periods, the present and future, and a representative agent who seeks to maximize utility by choosing between present and future consumption.

The Budget Constraint Suppose that I have the following – y = real income today – y f = real income in the future – w = assets or wealth at the beginning of the period – c = current consumption – c f = future consumption – r = the real interest rate (for both borrowing and lending) I can use this information to figure out my possible consumption combinations of c f and c by examining extremes and points in between: eq (1) c f = (y + w – c)(1 + r) + y f The line is the budget constraint and slope of the line is – (1+r).

The Concept of Present Value Suppose that I have future income (Y f ) of $ (one year from now) but I want to spend it all now. I can get a bank loan but how much can I borrow given my Y f ? The loan (L) at 10% has to satisfy: L( ) = $ (my ability to pay in the future) L = $13 200/1.1 = $ If I was a saver and wanted to have $ in the future, I would need to invest $ today to achieve that goal. The bank loan has effectively converted my future income into present income or given my Y f a value that I can get my hands on today; i.e., a present value (PV). In the same way, the financial markets have valued my target saving as worth $ in today’s dollars.

The Concept of Present Value (continued) Some points to make: – Implicitly we are assuming no constraints on borrowing or lending. – If the interest rate rises and assuming that I wanted to borrow for current consumption, I would only be able to borrow something less than the $ – If I were a saver, worried more about future consumption, then I would be able to achieve my future spending goal with less saving.

What am I worth today? Based on the simplified two period model, today I am worth my current income (y) and the discounted value of my future income (y f ), plus my existing wealth (w): eq (2) PVLR = y + w + y f /(1+r) Where PVLR represents the PV of my lifetime resources.

Look again at eg (1) and divide both sides by (1+r) and add c to both sides as well: eq (1) c f = (y + w – c)(1 + r) + y f eq (3) c + c f /(1+r) = y + w + y f /(1+r) PVLC = PVLR The budget constraint has been rearranged to show that the PV of lifetime consumption equals the PV of lifetime resources. In this form, it is called the “inter-temporal budget constraint” and it is an important and useful concept. Going a Step Further

Going a Step Further (continued) We have simply re-arranged the budget constraint (eq 1). If we choose to consume all the resources today (set c f = 0 ), then we would get: c = y + w + y f /(1+r) This is the length of the horizontal axis on the budget constraint graph. Once again, it is also PVLR, which is how much I am worth today.

Going a Step Further (continued) To get the length of the vertical axis, I simply set c = 0 and ask the question: how much c f I could have if I consumed nothing today. The answer is: c f =(1+ r)(y + w) + y f That is, I would have available the amount I saved (in this case, all of y plus w ), with interest, plus my future income. This is how to get the budget constraint shown next.

Figuring Out What the Consumer Wants So far so good but we don’t know where on the budget line the consumer will end up. To find that point, we need to know the consumers utility curve, which shows preferences for various combination of c and c f. These curves have three important properties: 1.Slope downward from left to right. 2.Farther away from origin represents more utility. 3.Utility curves are bowed towards the origin because we assume consumption smoothing – a preference for smooth and small changes to consumption.

A Formal Treatment of the Optimal Level of Consumption This and the following four slides are to show students how c and c f are determined using the model. The optimum level of total consumption (c) is the point where the budget constraint (eq 1) just touches the highest indifference curve it can reach. Recall that the budget constraint shows all the combinations of c and c f that are possible given the income available and the level of wealth (w). Utility is described by U(c, c f ) = constant.

A Formal Treatment of the Optimal Level of Consumption (continued) At the point of tangency, the lost marginal utility from giving up a unit of c equals the marginal utility of c f times (1+r). In symbols, noting that U ’(  ) is the first partial derivative of U wrt to either c or c f (represented by the symbol “  ” ): which can be re-written as: The ratio of the two marginal utilities, known as the marginal rate of substitution (MRS), is the slope of the indifference curve. That ratio equals ( 1 + r ) in equilibrium.

Taking the total derivative of a utility curve and setting it equal to zero Suppose that the utility curve was Cobb-Douglas

A Formal Treatment of the Optimal Level of Consumption (continued) We now have another relationship between present and future consumption Given the relationship between c and c f, we can use the inter-temporal budget constraint to figure out consumption.

A Formal Treatment of the Optimal Level of Consumption (continued) While we had to plough through some algebra, the final result is simple and intuitive: – Consumption today depends on my income and wealth today as well as the PV of my future income (the amount I can borrow against future income). – Together these two items represent the PVLR. – The whole thing is multiplied by α the utility weight that the individual puts on present consumption. – This is the foundation of the permanent income and life- cycle hypothesis of consumption and is behind most views on how consumption is determined.

A special case One special case is perfect consumption smoothing, where households want c = c f. In this case:

What Happens When There Are Temporary Changes to Income and Wealth? In this model, the effect will depend on how the PVLR is changed when either y, y f or w is changed. All three changes move the PVLR line without changing its slope (1+r). It is referred to as an income and/or wealth effect and it is shown as a parallel shift in the budget constraint. – The change in y raises both c and current saving (y-c). – The changes in y f and wealth (w) raises c but lowers current saving since current income (y) is not affected. The consumer moves to point B from either D or E because of consumption smoothing.

Consumption is largely driven by disposable income

The relation of consumption to wealth (net worth) is complicated

Consumption and housing wealth

The Permanent Income Theory In terms of the model, a temporary change in income is represented by a change in y with y f held constant. A permanent change would assume both components (y and y f ) change. This would have a larger effect on PVLR and so on both c and c f. The theory that emphasizes this relationship (the permanent income hypothesis) is attributable to Milton Friedman. Its formal expression is the final equation on Slide 22 above and reproduced here.

The Life-Cycle Hypothesis The two period model can be generalised to many periods which can capture more real world phenomena. – Income tends to follow a pattern over the life of the economic agent, rising from early years and then peaking between ages 50 to 60. – After retirement, income falls sharply. – Consumption patterns tend to be smoother (which is consistent with consumption smoothing). Saving as a result is at first negative, then positive and then negative. The Life-Cycle theory is attributable to Franco Modigliani (he won a Nobel Prize in part for this) and Richard Brumberg.

How Well Does the Model Fit the Data – The Role of Borrowing Constraints Studies confirm that y, y f and w all affect consumption and that permanent income changes are more important than transitory ones. Other studies point out that the volatility of consumption is greater than the theory suggests. Possible reasons : – People are short sighted. – Borrowing constraints are important when they are binding.

The Real Interest Rate and the Budget Line First what happens to the budget line when the real rate increases. It rotates around a point (E in the figure) where there is neither borrowing or lending. That is c=y + w and c f = y f. Since such a point involves neither borrowing nor lending, it remains on the budget line no matter what the interest rate (remember we are not changing y, y f or w so this point, where c = y + w and c f = y f, stays the same after we change r). Since an increase in r causes the line to become steeper, it must rotate around E. It is the only point where agents are not affected by changes in the interest rate since they are neither borrowing nor lending.

The Substitution Effect Recall that an increase in r raises the price of c in terms of c f. Starting from a no-borrowing/lending point, the increase in r will cause consumers to lower c (and increase s). They do this because they get more utility. The increase in saving is measured along the horizontal axis as a drop in c (remember y and y f are unchanged). Because we started from a no-borrowing/no-lending position, the rotation of the curve reflects a “pure substitution effect”.

Income and Substitution Effects Together We can use the graphical model to separate the two effects (see next slide): – Let the budget constraint pivot around the initial position (D). The drop in c (equivalent to a rise in s) from going from D to P is the substitution effect. – The income effect is measured by the movement from P back to Q. Note that if the initial position was one of dissaving (on the figure, you would be located to the right and below point E), saving would unambiguously rise.

Changes in the Real Interest Rate For a lender an increase in r has two opposite effects: – increase in current saving (substitution effect); – decrease in current saving (income effect). From our simple model, saving seems to rise nonetheless – this means that the substitution effect dominates.

Changes in the Real Interest Rate (continued) For borrowers when r increases the substitution and income effects both result in increased S – remember that borrowers now pay more on their outstanding loans. The empirical evidence is that an increase in r reduces C and increases S, but the effect is not very strong.

Consumption is negatively (but weakly) responsive to real interest rates

Low interest rates have driven increases in household debt-to-PDI in Canada, which has been on an upward trend since the early 2000s. Recently there has been some slowing in the rise of indebtedness but it remains high.

Net worth fluctuated widely during the great recession but has since regained its pre-recession heights

Taxes and the Real Return to Saving The expected after-tax real interest rate – r (after tax) – is the after-tax nominal interest rate minus the expected inflation rate. r (after tax) = i(1 – τ) – π e By reducing the tax rate on interest the government can increase the real rate of return for savers and (possibly) increase the rate of saving in the economy.

Fiscal Policy Let’s make an assumption that the economy’s aggregate output (supply) is given, it is not affected by the changes in fiscal policy. Furthermore, we are interested in the effect of fiscal policy on national saving (S d ). The government fiscal policy has two major components: government purchases and taxes.

Government Purchases When government purchases increase temporarily: Indirect effects: C d falls, because of lower after-tax income, but by less than the rise in taxes. S d increases, because of the fall in C d. Direct effect: S d (national of national saving). From the equation in slide 6 (reproduced) the total effect on national saving (S d ) is a fall as the direct effect of the rise in G outweighs the indirect effect. S d = Y – C d – G

Taxes A government tax cut without a reduction of current spending should: – Increase income and, therefore, C d by a fraction of the tax cut. – But expectations of higher taxes and lower after-tax income in the future are raised. According to the Ricardian equivalence proposition the positive and the negative effects of the tax cut without reduction of the current spending should exactly cancel. In reality it may not be so, since many consumers are likely to be not forward-looking.

Ricardian Equivalence in it’s Strict Form The model of consumer behaviour emphasises the importance that changes in PVLR have on c and c f. How do changes in taxes affect c? – If the government cuts taxes today then y rises, which should raise c, other things being equal. – Assuming unchanged spending, the government must borrow the difference. – But taxpayers are on the hook for that borrowing so y f will be lower. – Under certain conditions one offsets the other.

Ricardian Equivalence in it’s Strict Form (continued) For a more formal demonstration, start with PVLR, which is: – In the first period, the government raises household income by giving them a lump sum tax rebate, which they use to buy government bonds (b). – The government, however, has to raise taxes in the future ( t f ) by b(1+r) to retire its debt with interest and in the model, these taxes are levied against households.

Ricardian Equivalence in it’s Strict Form (continued) From the information on the previous slide the PVLR becomes: Since t f = b(1 + r), we get: = Since this is the original value of PVLR, consumption doesn’t change. In this case, as households are forward looking, they simply save the tax cut to pay off their future tax liabilities.